Processing math: 100%
Research article

Bifurcation analysis and optimal control of a delayed single-species fishery economic model


  • Received: 02 March 2022 Revised: 10 May 2022 Accepted: 17 May 2022 Published: 06 June 2022
  • In this paper, a single-species fishery economic model with two time delays is investigated. The system is shown to be locally stable around the interior equilibrium when the parameters are in a specific range, and the Hopf bifurcation is shown occur as the time delays cross the critical values. Then the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions are discussed. In addition, the optimal cost strategy is obtained to maximize the net profit and minimize the waste by hoarding for speculation. We also design controls to minimize the waste by hoarding for the speculation of the system with time delays. The existence of the optimal controls and derivation from the optimality conditions are discussed. The validity of the theoretical results are shown via numerical simulation.

    Citation: Xin Gao, Yue Zhang. Bifurcation analysis and optimal control of a delayed single-species fishery economic model[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(8): 8081-8106. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022378

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xin-You Meng, Yu-Qian Wu . Bifurcation analysis in a singular Beddington-DeAngelis predator-prey model with two delays and nonlinear predator harvesting. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(4): 2668-2696. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019133
    [2] Xinyou Meng, Jie Li . Stability and Hopf bifurcation analysis of a delayed phytoplankton-zooplankton model with Allee effect and linear harvesting. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(3): 1973-2002. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020105
    [3] Xiaomeng Ma, Zhanbing Bai, Sujing Sun . Stability and bifurcation control for a fractional-order chemostat model with time delays and incommensurate orders. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(1): 437-455. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023020
    [4] Yuan Ma, Yunxian Dai . Stability and Hopf bifurcation analysis of a fractional-order ring-hub structure neural network with delays under parameters delay feedback control. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(11): 20093-20115. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023890
    [5] Yuting Ding, Gaoyang Liu, Yong An . Stability and bifurcation analysis of a tumor-immune system with two delays and diffusion. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(2): 1154-1173. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022053
    [6] Ting Yu, Qinglong Wang, Shuqi Zhai . Exploration on dynamics in a ratio-dependent predator-prey bioeconomic model with time delay and additional food supply. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(8): 15094-15119. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023676
    [7] Zhenzhen Liao, Shujing Gao, Shuixian Yan, Genjiao Zhou . Transmission dynamics and optimal control of a Huanglongbing model with time delay. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(4): 4162-4192. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021209
    [8] Hongying Shu, Wanxiao Xu, Zenghui Hao . Global dynamics of an immunosuppressive infection model with stage structure. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(3): 2082-2102. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020111
    [9] A. K. Misra, Jyoti Maurya, Mohammad Sajid . Modeling the effect of time delay in the increment of number of hospital beds to control an infectious disease. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(11): 11628-11656. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022541
    [10] Sarita Bugalia, Jai Prakash Tripathi, Hao Wang . Mathematical modeling of intervention and low medical resource availability with delays: Applications to COVID-19 outbreaks in Spain and Italy. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(5): 5865-5920. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021295
  • In this paper, a single-species fishery economic model with two time delays is investigated. The system is shown to be locally stable around the interior equilibrium when the parameters are in a specific range, and the Hopf bifurcation is shown occur as the time delays cross the critical values. Then the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions are discussed. In addition, the optimal cost strategy is obtained to maximize the net profit and minimize the waste by hoarding for speculation. We also design controls to minimize the waste by hoarding for the speculation of the system with time delays. The existence of the optimal controls and derivation from the optimality conditions are discussed. The validity of the theoretical results are shown via numerical simulation.



    The fishery economic model is a kind of model based on biological population- and economic-related equations. It investigates the development of regulations of the biological population and economic income under the influence of the economic value of fishing behavior. By using reasonable parameters to build a model, the properties of the model are studied by using mathematical theory and methods. Therefore, we can reasonably explain the phenomenon in the actual fishing, predict the future trend and put forward guiding opinions on the reasonable maximization of fishing benefits. Some authors [1,2] established basic harvesting models to solve optimal harvesting problems. Jerry et al. [3] established a harvesting economic model and chose the fishing effort variation rate as the controllor to solve a nonlinear problem of optimal control. Conrad et al. [4] proposed and analyzed a mathematical model to study the dynamics of a fishery resource system in an aquatic environment that consists of two zones. Ami et al. [5] considered the optimal management problem by defining the stock density of the resource and the sum of discounted benefits as the biological indicator and economic indicator, respectively Bairagi et al. [6] performed a qualitative study of the bioeconomic management of a fishery in the presence of some infection.

    In [7], the author established a single-species fishery economic model based on a logistic model with a constant harvest. They found that the stock change of fish is related to its own growth and the catch rate. Additionally, they found that the price change is affected by the market positive linear demand function and the catch rate. It has a positive correlation with the market positive linear demand function and a negative correlation with the catch rate. So, the fishery economic model is as follows;

    {˙x(t)=rx(t)(1x(t)k)Y,x(0)=x0>0,˙p(t)=s(D(p)Y),p(0)=p0>0, (1.1)

    where the variables x(t) and p(t) denote the fish stock and the unit price of the stock at time t, respectively. D(p) is the positive linear demand function such that D(p)=ap(t)0 [8]. The parameter r is the intrinsic growth rate of the biomass. k is the carrying capacity of the environment. Y is the catch rate. a is the market capacity. s is the price speed adjustment. r, k, Y, a and s are positive constants.

    Indeed, the catch rate is affected by the total revenue and the total cost. Assume that the catch rate is positively correlated with the total revenue and negative correlated with the total cost. If the cost is high, the economic benefits of engaging in fishery production will be reduced accordingly, the attraction of engaging in relevant industries will be reduced, the human capital will flow to other fields, and the catch rate will be reduced accordingly. So, only considering the catch rate as a constant simply is not very reasonable. Therefore the catch rate should be a variable at time t, and it is represented by y(t). So the following fishery economic model is obtained:

    {˙x(t)=rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t),˙y(t)=βy(t)(p(t)c),˙p(t)=s(ap(t)y(t)), (1.2)

    where β is the response coefficient, c is the cost of catching. β and c are positive constants.

    Considering that the development of the system depends on both the current state and the past state, it is necessary to consider time delays in the model. Chakraborty et al. [9] introduced a single discrete gestation delay in a differential-algebraic bioeconomic system and investigated Hopf bifurcation in the neighborhood of the coexisting equilibrium point. Song et al. [10] determined the direction of the Hopf bifurcation and the stability of the bifurcating periodic solutions of a predator-prey system with two delays. Liu et al. [11] proposed a delayed Gause predator-prey model with Michaelis-Menten type harvesting and derived the conditions of local stability and Hopf bifurcation. Zhang et al. [12] determined the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions of a bioeconomic predator-prey model.

    In real life, there is a period of time from fishermen's capture to sale. That means that the fishermen's capture rate is also affected by the price at a certain time in the past, which is recorded as τ1 in the following model. Considering that there is a certain time delay between the actual market information and the market information acquired by buyers, a time delay in the process of the price affecting market demand exists, which is recorded as τ2. So we get the following delayed single-species fishery economic model:

    {˙x(t)=rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t),˙y(t)=βy(t)(p(tτ1)c),˙p(t)=s(ap(tτ2)y(t)), (1.3)

    where τ10 and τ20 are the time delays, and the other parameters are similar to ones of System (1.2).

    The initial conditions of the delayed single-species fishery economic system given by System (1.3) are

    x(0)R+,y(0)R+,p[τ,0]C+([τ,0];R+),

    with τ=max{τ1,τ2}.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, the conditions of local stability and Hopf bifurcation are discussed as functions of the time delays in different intervals. In Section 3, we investigate the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions. In Section 4, using cost control, the optimal harvesting of fish stocks is considered to maximize the net profit and minimize the waste caused by hoarding for speculation, while ensuring the sustainable survival of fish stocks. Besides, a control system with time delays is established, which is about guiding interventions and aims to reduce the waste. A realistic Penaeus vannamei's cultivation model simulation is demonstrated to prove the validity of the theoretical analysis in Section 5. Finally, the conclusions are presented in Section 6.

    In this section, one concentrates on the local stability and Hopf bifurcation phenomenon around the equilibria of System (1.3), as the time delays take different values.

    System (1.3) has non-negative equilibria S0=(0,0,a), ˆS0=(k,0,a) and S=(x,y,p), where p=c and y=ac, and x satisfies the following equation:

    rkx2+rx(ac)=0.

    After a simple calculation, it can be obtained that x1=k2+k2rr24rk(ac), x2=k2k2rr24rk(ac). There are two positive interior equilibria S1,2=(x1,2,ac,c) when ark4<c<a. The two internal equilibria of the system are merged into one, which is called the degenerate equilibrium (x0,ac,c) when c=ark4. And there is no interior equilibrium when c<ark4.

    The characteristic equation of System (1.3) at the equilibrium S0 can be expressed as follows:

    (rλ)(β(ac)λ)(seλτ2+λ)=0,

    and it always has two characteristic values λ1=r>0 and λ2=β(ac)>0. So S0 is always unstable. The characteristic equation of System (1.3) at the equilibrium ˆS0 can be expressed as follows:

    (r+λ)(β(ac)λ)(seλτ2+λ)=0,

    and it always has two characteristic values λ1=r<0 and λ2=β(ac)>0. So ˆS0 is always unstable.

    And the characteristic equation of System (1.3) at the equilibria S1,2 can be expressed as follows:

    J(λ,τ)=det(r(12xk)λ100λβ(ac)eλτ10sseλτ2λ)=(r(12xk)λ)(λ2+sβ(ac)eλτ1+sλeλτ2)=0. (2.1)

    The characteristic Eq (2.1) always has a characteristic value λ=r(12xk), and λS1<0, λS2>0. So S2 is always unstable. In order to study the stability of the equilibrium S1, we need to further study other characteristic values.

    The other characteristic values are satisfied:

    λ2+sβ(ac)eλτ1+sλeλτ2=0. (2.2)

    In the following section, we will investigate the dynamic behavior of System (1.3) around S1 (we denote S) according to the time delays τ1 and τ2 with different values, respectively.

    Case 1. τ1=τ2=0.

    Equation (2.2) becomes

    λ2+sβ(ac)+sλ=0,

    The two eigenvalues have negative real parts, so we can get the following theorem:

    Theorem 1. System (1.3)is asymptotically stablearound the interior equilibrium S.

    Remark 1. It means that in the absence of a time delay, the system will remain stable, that is, the fish stock will remain at a stable quantity without extinction; the capture rate and the unit price of the stock will also remain stable, and they are all stable at the value of the internal equilibrium.

    Case 2. τ1=τ2=τ>0.

    Equation (2.2) becomes

    λ2+s(β(ac)+λ)eλτ=0. (2.3)

    It is assumed that for some values of τ>0, there exists a real number ω>0 such that λ=±iω are two purely imaginary roots of Eq (2.3). Substituting λ=iω into Eq (2.3) and separating out the real and imaginary parts, it follows that

    ω2=sβ(ac)cosωτ+sωsinωτ,0=ωcosωτβ(ac)sinωτ. (2.4)

    From Eq (2.4), one obtains that

    ω4s2ω2s2β2(ac)2=0.

    There is a unique real and positive solution ω2 of the above equation.

    So the characteristic Eq (2.3) has a pair of purely imaginary roots ±iω for τk. The values of τk are calculated as follows:

    τk=1ω[arccosβ(ac)ω2sω2+sβ2(ac)2+2kπ],k=0,1,2,... (2.5)

    From [13], by using a method of analyzing the exponential polynomial zero distribution, we get System (1.3) is locally asymptotically stable around S for τ(0,τ0).

    From Eq (2.3), we can verify the following transversality conditions [14]

    sign{d(Reλ)dτ}λ=iω=sign{Re{(dλdτ)1}}λ=iω=sign{2ω2+s2ω4}>0

    Theorem 2. System (1.3) is asymptotically stable around the equilibrium Sfor τ(0,τ0) and unstable for τ>τ0.The system undergoes a bifurcation at τ=τ0.

    Case 3. τ1=0 and τ2>0.

    Equation (2.2) becomes

    λ2+sβ(ac)+sλeλτ2=0. (2.6)

    Substituting λ=iω into Eq (2.6) and separating out the real and imaginary parts, it follows that

    ω2+sβ(ac)+sωsinωτ2=0,sωcosωτ2=0. (2.7)

    Similar to Case 2, we get

    ω4(s2+2sβ(ac))ω2+s2β2(ac)2=0.

    The above equation has two real and positive roots

    ω2±=s2+2sβ(ac)±ss2+4sβ(ac)2.

    So, the characteristic equation only has two pairs of imaginary roots ±iω±. The values of τ2k± are given by Eq (2.8), which is calculated from Eq (2.7).

    τ2k±=1ω±(π2+kπ),k=0,1,2,... (2.8)

    By calculating from Eq (2.6), it is obtained that

    Re{(dλdτ2)1}λ=iω±=ω2±+sβ(ac)ω2±(ω2±sβ(ac)).

    Subsequently, we can verify the following transversality conditions

    sign{d(Reλ)dτ2}τ2=τ20+,λ=iω+=sign{ω2+(ω2+sβ(ac))}>0,sign{d(Reλ)dτ2}τ2=τ20,λ=iω=sign{ω2(ω2sβ(ac))}<0,

    By using the Butlers lemma [15], we can obtain the following theorem:

    Theorem 3. System (1.3) is asymptotically stable around the equilibrium Sfor τ2(0,τ20+)(j1k=0(τ2k,τ2k+1+)), andunstable for τ2(j1k=0(τ2k+,τ2k))(τ2j+,+),j>0.The system undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at τ2=τ20±.

    Case 4. τ1>0 and τ2=0.

    The calculations are similar to that for Case 1, so we will only list the theorem.

    τ1k=1ω(arcsinωβ(ac)+2kπ),k=0,1,2... (2.9)

    where ω is satisfied with

    ω4+s2ω2s2β2(ac)2=0.

    Theorem 4. System (1.3) is asymptotically stable around the equilibrium Sfor τ1(0,τ10) andunstable for τ1>τ10.The system undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at τ1=τ10.

    Case 5. τ1>0, τ2(0,τ20+), τ1τ2.

    In this subsection, τ1 is considered to be a bifurcation parameter and τ2 is confined to a range of (0,τ20+), where τ20+ is determined by Eq (2.8). Substituting λ=iω into Eq (2.2) and separating out the real and imaginary parts, it follows that

    ω2+sβ(ac)cosωτ1+sωsinωτ2=0,sβ(ac)sinωτ1+sωcosωτ2=0. (2.10)

    From Eq (2.10), ithe following is obtained:

    ω4+A1ω3+A2ω2+A3=0, (2.11)

    where

    A1=2ssinωτ2<0,A2=s2>0,A3=s2β2(ac)2<0.

    Denote F(ω)=4ω3+3A1ω2+2A2ω. Equation (2.11) has a unique real and positive root ω if Inequality (2.12) is satisfied. Otherwise, Eq (2.11) has one positive and real root at least.

    F(ω)0, (2.12)

    where ω=3A1+9A2124A212. So, Eq (2.2) has imaginary roots if Inequality (2.12) is satisfied, and the roots of Eq (2.2) have a negative real part when τ1(0,˜τ0). ˜τ0 is given by the following equation:

    ˜τk=1ω(arccosω4s2ω2+s2β2(ac)22sβ(ac)ω2+2kπ),k=0,1,2,3... (2.13)

    Then, differentiating Eq (2.2) at τ1=˜τ0 and separating out the real and imaginary parts, it follows that

    U(dReλdτ1)|τ1=˜τ0+V(dωdτ1)|τ1=˜τ0=W,V(dReλdτ1)|τ1=˜τ0+U(dωdτ1)|τ1=˜τ0=R,

    where

    U=˜τ0sβ(ac)cosω˜τ0+scosωτ2sτ2ωsinωτ2,V=2ω˜τ0sβ(ac)sinω˜τ0+ssinωτ2+sτ2ωcosωτ2,W=sβ(ac)ωsinω˜τ0,R=sβ(ac)ωcosω˜τ0.

    Thus, we get

    (dReλdτ1)|τ1=˜τ0=UWVRU2+V2>0,

    if

    UWVR>0. (2.14)

    If Inequality (2.12) is not satisfied, it can only hold that System (1.3) is locally asymptotically stable for τ1(0,ˆ˜τ0), where ˆ˜τ0 stands for the smallest ˜τ0 corresponding to all positive roots of Eq (2.11).

    Theorem 5. If Eqs (2.12) and (2.14) are satisfied, System (1.3) is asymptotically stable forτ1(0,˜τ0) andunstable for τ1>˜τ0, (˜τ0 is defined in Eq (2.13)).The system undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at τ1=˜τ0.

    Case 6. τ2>0, τ1(0,τ10), τ1τ2.

    τ10 is determined by Eq (2.9). The calculations are similar to those for Case 5, so we will only state the theorem.

    Theorem 6. If Eqs (2.15) and (2.17) are satisfied, the system isasymptotically stable around the equilibrium S for τ2(0,˜τ20)(˜τ20 is defined in Eq (2.16))and undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at τ2=˜τ20.

    s>4β(ac). (2.15)
    ˜τ2k=1ω(arcsinω4+s2ω2s2β2(ac)22sω3+2kπ),k=0,1,2... (2.16)

    and ω is satisfied with

    ω4(s2+2sβ(ac)cosωτ1)ω2+s2β2(ac)2=0.
    UWVR>0, (2.17)

    where

    U=τ1sβ(ac)cosωτ1+scosω˜τ20s˜τ20ωsinω˜τ20,V=2ωτ1sβ(ac)sinωτ1+ssinω˜τ20+s˜τ20ωcosω˜τ20,W=sω2cosω˜τ20,R=sω2sinω˜τ20.

    Remark 2. If the time delays are nonzero, corresponding to each case, when the time delays are small, the system will remain stable; when they are slightly greater than the bifurcation values, the system will undergo Hopf bifurcation. At this time, the fish stock, the capture rate and the unit price of the stock will fluctuate within a certain range and cannot reach stability. Because of these fluctuations, the fish stock cannot be stably supplied to the market, and the price fluctuation of fishery resources will also be relatively large, which is not conducive to the stability of the fishery economy. When the time delays are particularly large, the system will be unstable. At this time, the fluctuation ranges of the fish stock, the capture rate and the unit price will be larger and larger, which is not conducive to the stability of the fishery economy.

    In this part, we investigate the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions. For the delay differential equations, when the conditions of the Hopf bifurcation theorem are satisfied, the calculation formulas for determining the direction of Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcated periodic solutions can be given by applying the central manifold theory and gauge type method.

    We choose τ1=˜τ0+μ as the bifurcation parameter, μ=0 is the Hopf bifurcation value of System (1.3) and ˜τ0 is defined in Eq (2.13). Without the loss of generality, we assume that τ2<˜τ0, such that 1<τ2˜τ0<0. Let

    u1=xx,u2=yy,u3=pp,

    and t=t˜τ0, where (x,y,p) is the interior equilibrium S1. System (1.3) is expressed in the phase space C:=C([1,0],R3) which has the following vector form:

    ˙u(t)=Lμ(ut)+F(μ,ut), (3.1)

    where ut=(u1(t),u2(t),u3(t))TR3, Lμ:CR3 and F:R×CR3 are the linear part and nonlinear part respectively,

    where Φ=(Φ1,Φ2,Φ3)TC. By the Riesz representation theorem, there exists a 3×3 matrix η(θ,μ):[1,0]R3×3 of bounded variation functions, such that

    LμΦ=01Φ(θ)dθη(θ,μ),

    and η(θ,μ) in our system can be selected as follows:

    η(θ,μ)={(˜τ0+μ)(r(12xk)1000β(ac)0ss),θ=0,(˜τ0+μ)(00000β(ac)00s),θ[τ2˜τ0,0),(˜τ0+μ)(00000β(ac)000),θ(1,τ2˜τ0),03×3,θ=1.
    F(μ,ut)=(˜τ0+μ)(F1F2F3),

    where F1=rkΦ21(0), F2=β2Φ2(0)Φ3(1) and F3=0. The infinitely small generator A(μ) corresponding to the linearization part of System (1.3) is

    A(μ)Φ(θ)={dΦ(θ)dθ,θ=[1,0),01dϵη(μ,ϵ)Φ(ϵ),θ=0. (3.2)

    Define RΦ(θ) as

    RΦ(θ)={0,θ=[1,0),F(μ,Φ),θ=0. (3.3)

    Then, Eq (3.1) is equivalent to the abstract ordinary differential equation

    ˙ut=A(μ)ut+Rut. (3.4)

    Defining the formal adjoint matrix of A(μ0) as A

    AΨ(ϵ)={dΨ(ϵ)dϵ,ϵ=(0,1],01dηTt(t,0)Ψ(t),ϵ=0.

    For ΨC([0,1],R3) and ΦC([1,0],R3), we define a bilinear form suitable for the complex vector

    Ψ,Φ=ˉΨ(0)Φ(0)01θζ=0ˉΨ(ζθ)dη(0,θ)Φ(ζ)dζ. (3.5)

    Since A is the formal adjoint matrix of A(μ0), we can obtain that

    Ψ,AΦ=AΨ,Φ.

    Since ±iω˜τ0 are eigenvalues of A(0), they are also eigenvalues of A. We suppose that q(θ)=(q1,q2,1)Teiω˜τ0θ is the eigenvector of A(0) corresponding to iω˜τ0, and q(s)=D(q1,q2,1)eiω˜τ0s is the eigenvector of A(0) corresponding to iω˜τ0, where D is a nonzero coefficient. And they satisfy q,q=1. It can be obtained that

    q,ˉq=0,

    from the formal adjoint matrix A. Through a simple calculation, we get

    A(0)=˜τ0(r(12xk)1000β(ac)eiω˜τ00sseiωτ2),A(0)q(θ)=iω˜τ0q(θ).

    q1=iωseiω˜τ0r(12xk)iω, q2=iωseiω˜τ0. Similarly, we can obtain q1=sωieiωτ2+ω2β(ac)eiω˜τ0s, q2=seiωτ2iωβ(ac)eiω˜τ0. Because q,q=1, we get

    ˉD=(¯q1q1+¯q2q2+1sτ2eiωτ2+β(ac)¯q2˜τ0eiω˜τ0)1.

    Next, we will realize spectral decomposition. By the center manifold reduction [16], we define

    z(t)=q,ut, (3.6)

    where ut is the solution of Eq (3.1) for μ=0. We denote

    W(t,θ)=ut(θ)z(t)q(θ)ˉz(t)ˉq(θ); (3.7)

    so, W(t,θ)Q±iω˜τ0. z, ˉz are local coordinates of the center manifold C0 in the direction of q and ¯q, where z and ˉz are conjugate complex numbers. On the central manifold C0, W(t,θ)=W(z,ˉz,θ), and we only consider the real solutions here, where W(z,ˉz,θ) can be written in the form of a power series for z and ˉz:

    W(z,ˉz,θ)W20(θ)z22+W11(θ)zˉz+W02(θ)ˉz22+... (3.8)

    The solution utC0 of Eq (3.1) can be calculated from

    ˙z(t)=q(s),˙ut=iω˜τ0z(t)+¯q(0)F(0,zq(θ)+ˉzˉq(θ)+W(z,ˉz,θ)),

    where

    F(0,zq(θ)+ˉzˉq(θ)+W(z,ˉz,θ))=Fz2z22+Fzˉzzˉz+Fˉz2ˉz22+Fz2ˉzz2ˉz2+...

    The above equation can be rewritten as

    ˙z(t)=iω˜τ0z(t)+g(z,ˉz)(t), (3.9)

    where g(z,ˉz) is denoted by

    g(z,ˉz)(t)=g20z22+g11zˉz+g02ˉz22+g21z2ˉz2+...

    So, we can obtain that

    g20=¯q(0)Fz2,g11=¯q(0)Fzˉz,g02=¯q(0)Fˉz2,g21=¯q(0)Fz2ˉz. (3.10)

    From Eq (3.7), we can obtain that

    ut(θ)=W(t,θ)+z(t)q(θ)+ˉz(t)ˉq(θ),

    where ut(θ)=(u1t(θ),u2t(θ),u3t(θ))T, and W(t,θ)=(W(1)(t,θ),W(2)(t,θ),W(3)(t,θ))T. We can calculate the parameter expression from Eq (3.10), which can determine the direction of Hopf bifurcation, the stability of periodic solutions and the increase or decrease of the period of bifurcating periodic solutions. It can be further obtained that

    g20=ˉD˜τ0(2rkq21¯q1+βq2¯q2eiω˜τ0),g11=ˉD˜τ0(2rkq1¯q1¯q1+β2¯q2(q2eiω˜τ0+¯q2eiω˜τ0)),g02=ˉD˜τ0(2rk¯q12¯q1+β¯q2¯q2eiω˜τ0),g21=ˉD˜τ0(2rk(2q1W(1)11(0)+¯q1W(1)20(0))¯q1+β2(2q2W(3)11(1)+ˉq2W(3)20(1)+2eiω˜τ0W(2)11(0)+eiω˜τ0W(2)20(0))¯q2).

    From above, it can be found that g21 depends on the coefficients W20(θ) and W11(θ) of W(z,ˉz,θ), while g20, g11, g02 do not depend on W(z,ˉz,θ). Next, we calculate W20(θ) and W11(θ).

    For Eq (3.7), we get ˙W=˙ut˙zq˙ˉzˉq. Combining with the definitions of the infinitely small generator A(μ), RΦ(θ) and that given by (3.9), we can get

    ˙W={AWgq(θ)ˉgˉq(θ),θ[1,0),AWgq(θ)ˉgˉq(θ)+F0,θ=0. (3.11)

    In addition, on the central manifold Cμ0, we can obtain that

    ˙W=Wz˙z+Wˉz˙ˉz,=(W20(θ)z+W11(θ)ˉz)(iω˜τ0z(t)+g(z,ˉz))+(W11(θ)z+W02(θ)ˉz)(iω˜τ0ˉz(t)+ˉg(z,ˉz))+... (3.12)

    Through comparing the coefficients of the items z22 and zˉz between Eq (3.12) and Eq (3.11), we can obtain that

    (2iω˜τ0IA)W20(θ)={g20q(θ)ˉg02ˉq(θ),θ[1,0),g20q(0)ˉg02ˉq(0)+Fz2,θ=0, (3.13)

    and

    AW11(θ)={g11q(θ)ˉg11ˉq(θ),θ[1,0),g11q(0)ˉg11ˉq(0)+Fzˉz,θ=0, (3.14)

    where

    Fz2=˜τ0(2rkq21βq2eiω˜τ00)Fzˉz=˜τ0(2rkq1ˉq1β2(ˉq2eiω˜τ0+q2eiω˜τ0)0).

    For θ[1,0), from Eq (3.13), we can obtain that

    ˙W20(θ)=2iω˜τ0W20(θ)+g20q(θ)+ˉg02ˉq(θ). (3.15)

    Substituting q(θ)=q(0)eiω˜τ0θ into Eq (3.15), we can obtain that

    W20(θ)=ig20ω˜τ0q(0)eiω˜τ0θ+iˉg023ω˜τ0ˉq(0)eiω˜τ0θ+C1e2iω˜τ0θ. (3.16)

    For θ=0, from Eq (3.13), we can obtain that

    01dθη(0,θ)W20(θ)=2iω˜τ0W20(0)+ˉg02ˉq(0)+g02q(0)Fz2.

    Substitute Eq (3.16) into the above equation to obtain

    (iω˜τ0I01eiω˜τ0θdθη(0,θ))q(0)=0,

    which gives

    C1=(2iω˜τ0I01e2iω˜τ0θdθη(0,θ))1Fz2,=(2iωr(12xk)1002iωβ(ac)e2ω˜τ00s2iω+se2iω˜τ0)1(2rkq21βq2eiω˜τ00)

    For θ[1,0), from Eq (3.14), we can obtain that

    ˙W11(θ)=g11q(θ)+ˉg11ˉq(θ). (3.17)

    From further calculation, we can obtain that

    W11(θ)=ig11ω˜τ0q(0)eiω˜τ0θ+iˉg11ω˜τ0ˉq(0)eiω˜τ0θ+C2. (3.18)

    Similarly, we can obtain that

    C2=(01dη(0,θ))1Fzˉz,=(r(12xk)1000β(ac)0ss)1(2rkq1ˉq1β2(ˉq2eiω˜τ0+q2eiω˜τ0)0).

    Then, we can judge the properties of Hopf bifurcation by the parameters μ2, β2 and T2. We denote

    c1(0)=i2ω˜τ0(g11g202|g11|2|g02|23)+g212;

    then,

    μ2=Re(c1(0))Re(λ(˜τ0)),β2=2Re(c1(0)),T2=Im(c1(0))+μ2Im(λ(˜τ0))ω˜τ0. (3.19)

    So we can obtain the conclusion as follows.

    Theorem 7. The parameters μ2, β2 and T2 determine theproperties of Hopf bifurcation. μ2 determines the direction of the Hopfbifurcation: if μ2>0 (μ2<0), the Hopf bifurcation is supercritical(subcritical); β2 determines the stability of the bifurcating periodicsolution: the bifurcating periodic solution is stable (unstable) if β2<0(β2>0); T2 determines the period of the bifurcating periodicsolution: the period will increase (decrease) if T2>0 (T2<0).

    In this section, we investigate the optimal control strategy based on System (1.3). The optimal control problem is to seek the basic principle of control and the limitation of the available principle [17,18]. It is widely used in aerospace, electronic information-related fields, bioengineering, economic management and other fields [19,20,21]. In this section, two optimal control problems with different control variables are considered.

    We first consider System (1.3) with time delays τ1=τ2=0. To control the cost, we consider the optimal harvesting of fish stocks to maximize the net economic income and minimize the waste caused by the stored amount of fishery resources. Assume that the probability that the harvesting is greater than the market demand is p1(0p11). When the market demand is greater than the harvesting, then the sales is equal to harvesting and the total economic income is y(t)(1p1)p(t); otherwise, the sales is equal to market demand and the total economic income is (ap(t))p1p(t). And the total cost is y(t)c(t). Then the net economic income can be expressed as follows:

    π(x(t),y(t),p(t),c(t))=(ap(t))p1p(t)+y(t)(1p1)p(t)y(t)c(t).

    In the process of marine fish breeding, the management of the fishing ground is bound to produce corresponding resource management costs. When the monthly fish stock is greater than the catch rate, the excess fish stock is hoarded for speculation. The larger the value of this part, the more management costs will be incurred in theory. We do not want the waste caused by the stock of fish resources. The waste caused by monthly hoarding for speculation is represented byx(t)y(t), and A is the corresponding positive weight parameter. For the fishing process, the fishery administration department can adjust the costs incurred during the fishing process to a certain extent by adjusting the relevant tariff preferences, ocean fishing vessel construction subsidies, fuel subsidies and other support policies. The optimal control problem involves determining the control variable c to maximize the objective function

    0eδt((ap(t))p1p(t)+y(t)(1p1)p(t)y(t)c(t)+A(y(t)x(t)))dt,

    where δ is the instantaneous annual discount rate and p(x), x(t) and y(t) are state variables of System (1.3). Using the Pontryagin maximization principle, we construct the Hamiltonian function as follows

    H(x(t),p(t),y(t),c(t))=eδt((ap(t))p1p(t)+y(t)(1p1)p(t)y(t)c(t)+A(y(t)x(t)))+λ1(rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t))+λ2(βy(t)(p(t)c(t)))+λ3s(ap(t)y(t)),

    where λ1, λ2 and λ3 are adjoint variables and c is the control variable, which can be varied within the range ark4<c(t)<a. The condition for a singular control to be optimal is

    Hc=0.

    From the above equation, we can obtain that λ2(t)=1βeδt. For the adjoint variables λ1, λ2 and λ3, the following equations can be satisfied:

    dλ1dt=Hx=Aeδtλ1r(12xk), (4.1)
    dλ2dt=Hy=eδt((1p1)pc+A)+λ1λ2β(pc)+λ3s, (4.2)
    dλ3dt=Hp=eδt((a2p)p1+y(1p1))λ2βy+λ3s. (4.3)

    By substituting λ2(t)=1βeδt into Eq (4.3), it can be obtained that

    dλ3dtλ3s=eδt(a2py)p1.

    Then adding the integrating factor est [22], we can obtain that

    λ3=(a2py)p1δ+seδt. (4.4)

    By substituting λ2 and λ3 into Eq (4.2), we can obtain that

    λ1=eδt(δβp1p+Asp1(a2py)δ+s). (4.5)

    By substituting Eq (4.5) into Eq (4.1), we can obtain that

    (r(12xk)δ)(δβp1p+Asp1(a2py)δ+s)=A. (4.6)

    Equation (4.6) is the optimal control path Sδ(xδ,yδ,pδ) of System (1.2) under the control of cost. And the optimal cost and the optimal harvesting are as follows:

    cδ=arxδ(12xδk),yδ=rxδ(12xδk).

    Equation (4.6) provides an equation for the singular path and gives the optimal equilibrium levels of x=xδ,y=yδ and p=pδ. λieδt,i=1,2,3 represents the shadow prices along the singular path. From Eqs (4.4) and (4.5) and λ2(t)=1βeδt, it may be concluded that these shadow prices may remain constant over the time interval in an optimal equilibrium when they satisfy the strict transversality condition at . Further, they remain bounded when t. There exist an optimal control cδ and corresponding solutions xδ,yδ and pδ that maximize the objective function. The optimal control path can involve any combination of the three variables xδ,yδ and pδ that satisfy the constraints.

    The fisheries and fishery administrations play a crucial role in the process of cultivation, harvesting and the market circulation of aquatic products. They put forward guiding interventions to assist cultivation enterprises and individual farmers in finding a reasonable scale for farming scientifically, and they publicize marketing strategies for aquatic products reasonably and moderately. By doing so, companies and individuals will reduce the waste caused by hoarding for speculation or income loss caused by too few products, and maximize their interests, boosting the economic growth of the country.

    According to the above idea, System (1.3) is generalized by incorporating two controls. The controls u1(t) and u2(t) stand for the influence of guiding interventions on finding reasonable scale for farming and marketing strategies, respectively. Regarding finding a reasonable scale for farming, the government adjusts the breeding scale by increasing subsidies to fish fry suppliers and feed suppliers, thereby reducing the loan interest of enterprises of this product, and opening directional loans. Regarding marketing strategies, the regulatory authorities adjust the market price of the commodity by increasing import tariffs, limiting the import quantities of similar agricultural products, implementing the export tax rebate policy and refunding the domestic tax when the commodity is declared for export. At the same time, it also affects the capture rate for fishermen and farms. C1 and C2 are positive weight parameters. So, we obtain the following system:

    {˙x(t)=rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t)u1(t)x(t),˙y(t)=βy(t)(p(tτ1)c)+C1u2(t)y(t),˙p(t)=s(ap(tτ2)y(t))C2u2(t)p(t). (4.7)

    The state vector of System (4.7) is given by

    X=(x(t),y(t),p(t))R3+.

    Considering the biological significance, we assume that the initial conditions of System (4.7) are given as follows:

    (φ1(θ),φ2(θ),φ3(θ))C+=C([τ,0],R3+),φi(0)>0,i=1,2,3,

    where τ=max(τ1,τ2). The optimal control problem involves determining the control variables u1(t) and u2(t) to minimize the objective function

    J(u1(t),u2(t))=tf0(A(x(t)y(t))+12B1u1(t)2+12B2u2(t)2)dt,

    where x(t)y(t) is the waste caused by hoarding for speculation and A is positive weight parameter. The squares of the control variables reflect the severity of the side effects of guiding interventions on finding a reasonable scale for farming and marketing strategies; B1 and B2 are positive weight parameters that are associated with them. The variables u1(t),u2(t)U and U represent the control set defined by

    U={u=(u1,u2)L([0,tf],R2)0ui(t)umaxi=1,t[0,tf],i=1,2},

    where umaxi represents the maximum attainable values of ui. To solve the optimal control problem, we must prove the existence of the optimal control first. It will be proved if the following conditions are satisfied:

    (1) The set of controls and state variables is nonempty.

    (2) The control space is closed and convex.

    (3) The right side of System (4.7) is bounded by a linear function with the state and control.

    (4) The integrand in the objective function is convex with respect to the input controls u1 and u2.

    (5) There exists a constant D1>1 and positive numbers D2 and D3 such that the integrand of the objective functional satisfies

    A(xy)+12B1u21+12B2u22D2(u12+u22)D1/2D3.

    By neglecting the negative terms in System (4.7), we obtain

    {dx(t)dt<rx(t),dy(t)dt<βy(t)p(tτ1)+C1u2y(t),dp(t)dt<sa. (4.8)

    From the third equation of the above system, the solution of p(t) in finite time is bounded and exists according to the comparison theorem [22]. System (4.8) can be rewritten in the vector form as follows:

    (˙x˙y˙p)<(r000C1u2+βpmax0000)(xyp)+(00sa),

    where pmax is the maximum of p. This system is linear in finite time with bounded coefficients. Then the solutions of this linear system are uniformly bounded. Therefore, the solutions of the nonlinear system given by System (4.8) are bounded and exist. Hence, Condition 1 is satisfied. Condition 2 is satisfied by the definition of U. System (4.7) can be rewritten as

    G(X,Xτ1,Xτ2)=(rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t)u1(t)x(t)βy(t)(p(tτ1)c)+C1u2(t)y(t)s(ap(tτ2)y(t))C2u2(t)p(t)),

    where X(t)=(x(t),y(t),p(t))T,Xτ1(t)=(x(tτ1),y(tτ1),p(tτ1))T, Xτ2=(x(tτ2),y(tτ2),p(tτ2))T are the vectors of the state variables. According to the Hölder inequality [23], X1,Xτ11,Xτ21,X2,Xτ12 and Xτ22 exist and satisfy

    G(X1,Xτ11,Xτ21)G(X2,Xτ21,Xτ22)∣≤(C+Q)X1X2+βymaxXτ11Xτ12+Cτ∣∣Xτ21Xτ22,

    where

    C=(ru1100βc+C1u200sC2u2),Cτ=(00000000s),

    Q=max{2rkxmax,βpmax}<. This means that G(X) is uniformly Lipschitz continuous, Condition 3 is satisfied. Condition 4 is verified by the definition. Finally,

    A(xy)+12B1u21+12B2u22D2(u12+u22)D1/2D3,

    where D2=max{B12,B22}, D1=2, D3>0. Condition 5 is satisfied. So the following theorem is obtained.

    Theorem 8. There exist optimal control functions u1δ, u2δ and a setof corresponding solutions xδ(t), yδ(t), pδ(t) sothat J(u1δ,u2δ)=minJ(u1,u2), u1,u2U.

    Then, using Pontryagin's maximization principle, we construct the Hamiltonian function as follows

    H=A(x(t)y(t))+12B1u21(t)+12B2u22(t)+λ1(rx(t)(1x(t)k)y(t)u1(t)x(t))+λ2(βy(t)(p(tτ1)c)+C1u2(t)y(t))+λ3(s(ap(tτ2)y(t))C2u2(t)p(t)),

    Let χ[0,tfτ](t) be the indicator function of the interval [0,tfτ]

    χ[0,tfτ](t)={1ift[0,tfτ],0otherwise.

    By using optimality, we can obtain that

    Hu1=B1u1(t)λ1xδ(t)=0,Hu2=B2u2(t)+C1λ2yδ(t)C2λ3pδ(t)=0.

    So, we can find that

    u1δ=max{min{λ1xδ(t)B1,umax1},0},u2δ=max{min{C2λ3pδ(t)C1λ2yδ(t)B2,umax2},0},

    with x(0)=x0, y(0)=y0, p(0)=p0. The adjoint equations and transversality conditions are obtained using

    dλdt=HX(t)χ[0,tfτ1](t)HXτ1(t+τ1)χ[0,tfτ2](t)HXτ2(t+τ2),λ(tf)=0.

    It is obtained that

    dλ1dt=Aλ1(r(12xδ(t)k)u1δ(t)),dλ2dt=A+λ1λ2(β(pδ(t)c)+C1u2δ(t))+λ3s,dλ3dt=χ[0,tfτ1](t)λ2(t+τ1)βyδ(t+τ1)+χ[0,tfτ2](t)λ3(t+τ2)s+λ3C2u2δ(t),λ1(tf)=λ2(tf)=λ3(tf)=0,

    where (xδ,yδ,pδ) is the optimal solution for the optimal controls u1δ(t), u2δ(t), and they satisfy System (4.7).

    Penaeus vannamei is an important commercial shrimp and there are many experiments and studies on its cultivation [24,25]. There are also some reports on the breeding, fishing and marketing of Penaeus vannamei [26]. In this section, the above theoretical results will be applied to the culture of Penaeus vannamei.

    For System (1.3), we take r=0.86, k=700, β=0.4, c=50.07, a=88.92, s=0.05 and the set initial value X0(x0,y0,p0)=(650,38,50). We take the month as the time unit. The value of c is the unit cost (ten thousand yuan) and the value of a is the monthly market demand (tons); their values are derived from the preliminary treatment of the fishing situation investigation results of Penaeus vannamei in [26], where c and a, respectively, are the average cost and total sales of Penaeus vannamei in China. The value r is converted and averaged according to the survival rate of the seedlings in several environments in a culture experiment report [24] to obtain an estimated value. The above-mentioned parameter values are in line with the definition of the parameters in our model. By calculation, it can be obtained that S1=(651.4596,38.8500,50.0700) and S2=(48.5404,38.8500,50.0700). When τ1=τ2=0, there is only one equilibrium S1, according to Theorem 1, the internal equilibrium point S1 is globally asymptotically stable, which can be seen in Figure 1. The points near S2 always reach a steady-state S1, which can be seen in Figure 2. From Case 1 and Eq (2.5), it can be obtained that ω=2.8100 and τ00.0637. So, the interior equilibrium S1 remains stable for τ<τ0, which can be seen in Figure 3. As τ increases through τ0, Hopf bifurcation occurs. The bifurcating periodic solution exists for τ slightly larger than τ0 which can be seen in Figure 4. The phase space trajectory shows a limit cycle corresponding to the periodic solution in the solution curves, which forms around the fixed point. For τ>τ0, the interior equilibrium becomes unstable, which can be seen in Figure 5. The solution of System (1.3) varies as the bifurcation parameter τ for τ1=τ2, which is shown in Figure 6. And from this figure, we can observe that the solution changes from stable to unstable as the bifurcation parameter τ increases through the bifurcation value τ0. From Eq (2.8), it can be obtained that τ20+0.1767,τ200.2276. From Eq (2.9), it can be obtained τ100.2054. The graphs that show dynamical variation of System (1.3) when τ1τ20 are similar to τ1=τ2.

    Figure 1.  Solution curves and phase space trajectories for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock without any time delay, beginning with x0=650, y0=38 and p0=50, finally stabilizing at S1.
    Figure 2.  Solution curves and phase space trajectories for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock without any time delay, beginning with x0=48, y0=38 and p0=50 around S2, finally stabilizing at S1.
    Figure 3.  Solution curves and phase space trajectories for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock with time delay τ1=τ2=0.01<τ0, beginning with x0=650, y0=38 and p0=50, finally stabilizing at S1.
    Figure 4.  Solution curves and phase space trajectory for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock with time delay τ1=τ2=0.067>τ0, beginning with x0=650, y0=38 and p0=50, producing a stable periodic solution.
    Figure 5.  Solution curves and phase space trajectory for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock with time delay τ1=τ2=0.08>τ0, beginning with x0=650, y0=38 and p0=50.
    Figure 6.  Solution of System (1.3), shown to vary with the bifurcation parameter τ, when τ1=τ2=τ.

    For case 5, we fix τ2=0.0670<τ20+; by calculation, it can be obtained that ω2.8640,˜τ00.0598. Based on our analysis in Section 3, we can compute the crucial values with the help of Matlab to get μ2=2.7672×104, β2=7.4396×104, T2=2.5146105. Therefore, according to Theorem 7, when τ1=τ0=0.0598, it can be concluded that the direction of the local Hopf bifurcation is subcritical additionally, the nontrivial periodic solutions bifurcating from the interior equilibrium S1=(651.4596,38.8500,50.0700) are unstable and increase on the center manifold, which can be seen in Figure 7. The solution of System (1.3) varies according to the bifurcation parameter τ1, for τ2=0.0670, which is shown in Figure 8.

    Figure 7.  Solution curves and phase space trajectory for the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock with time delay τ1=0.0598,τ2=0.067, beginning with x0=650, y0=38 and p0=50.
    Figure 8.  Solution of System (1.3), shown to vary with the bifurcation parameter τ1, when τ2=0.0670.

    The optimal control problem of System (4.7) cannot be solved analytically; ,consequently, reliable numerical methods are essentially required. It is transformed into a nonlinear programming problem. The rough steps are as follows. Let A=0.001, B1=1000, B2=10, C1=C2=10. Under the assumption that there exist a step size h>0 and integers (n,g1,g2)N3 with tf=nh, τ1=g1h and τ2=g2h, let τ1=0.05, τ2=0.5, h=0.01, tf=300, so that n=3000,g1=1,g2=10 and other parameters are the same as above. We set X(θ)=(xθ/h,yθ/h,pθ/h)=X0,θ[τ,0] and λj(θ)=λθ/hj=0, where, θ[tf,tf+τ],j=1,2,3, where τ=max{τ1,τ2}. By using backward difference approximation, adjoint functions with transversality conditions can be obtained as

    λni11=λni1h(Aλni1(r(12xik)ui1)),λni12=λni2h(A+λni1λni2(β(pic)+C1ui2)+λni3s),λni13=λni3h(χ[0,tfτ1](tni)λni+g13βyi+g1+χ[0,tfτ2](tni)λni+g23s+λni3C2ui2).

    By utilizing combinations of the forward and backward difference approximations, it can be derived that

    xi+1=xi+h(rxi(1xik)yiui1xi),yi+1=yi+h(βyi(pig1c)+C1ui2yi),pi+1=pi+h(s(apig2yi)C2ui2pi).

    The optimal harvest controls are updated by values of the state and adjoint variables

    ui+11=max{min{λni1xi+1B1,umax1},0},ui+12=max{min{C2λni3pi+1C1λni2yi+1B2,umax2},0},

    where umax1=umax2=1. Repeat the above steps for i=0,...,n1. From these steps, we obtain Figure 9. From this figure we can get that under the reasonable controls, the waste caused by hoarding for speculation is reduced. We also get that the interior equilibrium of System (1.3) is stable when the cost is c=56.8426 and the time delay τ1=τ2<τ0, which is shown in Figure 9.

    Figure 9.  Stable dynamical variations of the fish stock, catch rate and unit price of the stock with controls or without controls.

    In this paper, a delayed single-species fishery economic model was established. It is considered that the catch rate was affected by the total revenue and the total cost. Two time delays were added to the system; they were found to be related to the effects of price on the catch rate and the market requirements respectively. For the delayed system, the local stability behaviors around the interior equilibrium point were discussed. It could be seen that the time delays had a great influence on the stability of the system. When the time delays are too large, the system will change from stable to unstable. This is reflected in the sharp fluctuations of fishery resources and prices in fisheries, which we do not want to see. If we can reduce these two time delays as much as possible, we can increase the stability of the fishery industry. For example, we would be able to feedback market information to fishermen and farms in real time, improve price transparency and reduce the time delay of price in the fishing process. For another example, the pricing of the current year is affected by the previous pricing experience, resulting in a time delay of the price. The supervision department can lead the scientific research institutes to make scientific predictions on the market trend of that year, guide the market price and reduce the time delay. Using the central manifold theory, we obtained the direction of Hopf bifurcation, stability and existence of the bifurcated periodic orbit.

    Using Pontryagin's maximum principle, we obtained the optimal cost strategy. According to the optimal cost strategy, guidances could be given to regulatory agencies' subsidies and tax adjustments to fisheries. This will only ensure the maximization of economic benefits and minimize the waste, but also realize the sustainable development of the population. We also got the stable dynamical variation of the delayed system under the control of guiding interventions. This showed that there would be less waste caused by hoarding for speculation if fisheries and fishery administrations could assist cultivation enterprises and individual farmers in finding a reasonable scale for farming scientifically, and publicize marketing strategies for aquatic products reasonably and moderately. And, from the simulation results, compared with that before adding the optimal control with guiding interventions, the waste caused by hoarding is indeed reduced on the premise of ensuring the stability of the system.

    There are some topics remaining to refine our modeling and further the analysis. These include the influences of other species on the target species in polycultural mode and the influences of environmental complexity caused by algae, fungi and other microorganisms in water on population growth, as well as the global stability analysis and other bifurcation in the sense of mathematical theory.

    This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (61703083 and 61673100). The authors gratefully acknowledge the reviewers for their comments and suggestions, which have greatly improved the presentation of this work.

    All authors declare that there is no conflicts of interest for this study.



    [1] C. Clark, Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1990. https://doi.org/10.1137/1020117
    [2] M. Liu, C. Bai, Optimal harvesting of a stochastic Logistic model with time delay, J. Nonlinear Sci., 25 (2015), 277–289. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00332-014-9229-2 doi: 10.1007/s00332-014-9229-2
    [3] M. Jerry, N. Raïssi, The optimal strategy for a bioeconomical model of a harvesting renewable resource problem, Math. Comput. Model., 36 (2002), 1293–1306. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0895-7177(02)00277-7 doi: 10.1016/S0895-7177(02)00277-7
    [4] J. M. Conrad, The bioeconomics of marine sanctuaries, J. Bioeconomics, 1 (1999), 205–217. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010039031324 doi: 10.1023/A:1010039031324
    [5] D. Ami, P. Cartigny, A. Rapaport, Can marine protected areas enhance both economic and biological situations?, C. R. Biol., 328 (2005), 357–366. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.crvi.2004.10.018 doi: 10.1016/j.crvi.2004.10.018
    [6] N. Bairagi, S. Bhattacharya, P. Auger, Bioeconomics fishery model in presence of infection: Sustainability and demand-price perspectives, Appl. Math. Comput., 405 (2021), 126225. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2021.126225 doi: 10.1016/j.amc.2021.126225
    [7] C. Jerry, N. Raïssi, Can management measures ensure the biological and economical stabilizability of a fishing model?, Appl. Math. Comput., 51 (2010), 516–526. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mcm.2009.11.017 doi: 10.1016/j.mcm.2009.11.017
    [8] J. T. Lafrance, Linear demand functions in theory and practice, J. Econ. Theory, 37 (1985), 147–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(85)90034-1 doi: 10.1016/0022-0531(85)90034-1
    [9] K. Chakraborty, M. Chakraborty, T. K. Kar, Bifurcation and control of a bioeconomic model of a prey Cpredator system with a time delay, Nonlinear Anal. Hybrid Syst., 5 (2011), 613–625. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.nahs.2011.05.004 doi: 10.1016/j.nahs.2011.05.004
    [10] Y. Song, Y. Peng, J. Wei, Bifurcations for a predator-prey system with two delays, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 337 (2008), 466–479. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmaa.2007.04.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2007.04.001
    [11] W. Liu, Y. Jiang, Bifurcation of a delayed Gause predator-prey model with Michaelis-Menten type harvesting, J. Theor. Biol., 438 (2018), 116–132. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2017.11.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2017.11.007
    [12] X. Zhang, S. Song, J. Wu, Oscillations, fluctuation intensity and optimal harvesting of a bio-economic model in a complex habitat, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 436 (2016), 692–717. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmaa.2015.11.068 doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2015.11.068
    [13] S. Ruan, J. Wei, On the zeros of transcendental functions with applications to stability of delay differential equations with two delays, Dyn. Contin. Discrete Impuls. Syst., 10 (2003), 863–874. https://doi.org/10.1093/imammb/18.1.41 doi: 10.1093/imammb/18.1.41
    [14] K. Yang, Delay Differential Equations: With Applications in Population Dynamics, American Academic Press, New York, 1993.
    [15] H. I. Freedman, V. Sree Hari Rao, The trade-off between mutual interference and time lags in predator-prey systems, B. Math. Biol., 45 (1983), 991–1004. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0092-8240(83)80073-1 doi: 10.1016/S0092-8240(83)80073-1
    [16] B. Hassard, N. Kazarinoff, Y. Wan, Theory and Applications of Hopf Bifurcation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1981. https://doi.org/10.1137/1024123
    [17] L. D. Berkovitz, Optimal Control Theory, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1974. https://doi.org/10.1002/9783527639700.ch5
    [18] A. E. Bryson, Y. C. Ho, G. M. Siouris, Applied optimal control: optimization, estimation, and control, IEEE T. Syst. Man Cybernetics. B, 9 (1979), 366–367. https://doi.org/10.1109/TSMC.1979.4310229 doi: 10.1109/TSMC.1979.4310229
    [19] K. A. Gepreel, M. Higazy, A. M. S. Mahdy, Optimal control, signal flow graph, and system electronic circuit realization for nonlinear Anopheles mosquito model, Int. J. Mod. Phys. C, 31 (2020), 2050130. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0129183120501302 doi: 10.1142/S0129183120501302
    [20] J. Borek, B. Groelke, C. Earnhardt, C. Vermillion, Economic optimal control for minimizing fuel consumption of Heavy-Duty trucks in a highway environment, IEEE Trans. Control Syst. Technol., 99 (2019), 1–13. https://ieeexplore.ieee.org/document/8737780
    [21] F. A. Rihan, S. Lakshmanan, H. Maurer, Optimal control of tumour-immune model with time-delay and immuno-chemotherapy, Appl. Math. Comput., 353 (2019), 147–165. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2019.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.amc.2019.02.002
    [22] W. Kaplan, Ordinary Differential Equations, Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1958.
    [23] O. Hölder, Ueber einen Mittelwerthabsatz, Digi Zeitschriften, (1889).
    [24] Z. Peng, M. Huang, J. Qiao, Effects of breeding density and salinity on growth traits of penaeus vannamei during sizing, Fish. Sci. Technol. Inf., 46 (2019), 154–159.
    [25] J. Li, J. Shi, X. Hu, Statistical analysis of Penaeus vannamei strains, density, seedling release time and breeding benefit, J. Aquacult., 40 (2019), 19–24.
    [26] Y. Fu, L. Mai, X. Zhong, 2016 national report on breeding and fishing of penaeus vannamei, Ocean Fish., 8 (2016), 68–71. https://doi.org/10.3969/j.issn.1672-4046.2016.08.038 doi: 10.3969/j.issn.1672-4046.2016.08.038
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Yanhua Zhu, Xiangyi Ma, Tonghua Zhang, Jinliang Wang, Regulating spatiotemporal dynamics of tussock-sedge coupled map lattices model via PD control, 2025, 194, 09600779, 116168, 10.1016/j.chaos.2025.116168
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1808) PDF downloads(89) Cited by(1)

Figures and Tables

Figures(9)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog