Research article Special Issues

Key generic technology research and development decision-making in Stackelberg competition

  • Research and development (R&D) of key generic technology (KGT) is conducive to improving the innovation capacity of countries and regions and has a significant impact on economic development and social progress. Compared to other technologies, the factors affecting the R&D decisions of KGT are more complex and need to be explored in depth. This study constructs a Stackelberg model considering R&D effort level, R&D efficiency and product differentiation to investigate the leader's and follower's decisions on R&D of KGT under three types of R&D modes. The results reveal that firms' strategic decisions are affected by product differentiation, R&D efficiency and different R&D modes. Product differentiation and R&D efficiency have impacts on equilibrium results and government subsidies for KGT R&D are optimal for social welfare.

    Citation: Xiao Liang, Xinran Xie. Key generic technology research and development decision-making in Stackelberg competition[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28833-28857. doi: 10.3934/math.20231478

    Related Papers:

    [1] Jun Wang, Dan Wang, Yuan Yuan . Research on low-carbon closed-loop supply chain strategy based on differential games-dynamic optimization analysis of new and remanufactured products. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 32076-32101. doi: 10.3934/math.20241540
    [2] Chengli Hu, Ping Liu, Hongtao Yang, Shi Yin, Kifayat Ullah . A novel evolution model to investigate the collaborative innovation mechanism of green intelligent building materials enterprises for construction 5.0. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(4): 8117-8143. doi: 10.3934/math.2023410
    [3] Zifu Fan, Youpeng Tao, Wei Zhang, Kexin Fan, Jiaojiao Cheng . Research on open and shared data from government-enterprise cooperation based on a stochastic differential game. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(2): 4726-4752. doi: 10.3934/math.2023234
    [4] Dilshad Alghazzawi, Sajida Abbas, Hanan Alolaiyan, Hamiden Abd El-Wahed Khalifa, Alhanouf Alburaikan, Qin Xin, Abdul Razaq . Dynamic bipolar fuzzy aggregation operators: A novel approach for emerging technology selection in enterprise integration. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 5407-5430. doi: 10.3934/math.2024261
    [5] Ahmad Bin Azim, Ahmad ALoqaily, Asad Ali, Sumbal Ali, Nabil Mlaiki . Industry 4.0 project prioritization by using q-spherical fuzzy rough analytic hierarchy process. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(8): 18809-18832. doi: 10.3934/math.2023957
    [6] Nawras H. Sabbry, Alla Levina . Nonce generation techniques in Schnorr multi-signatures: Exploring EdDSA-inspired approaches. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20304-20325. doi: 10.3934/math.2024988
    [7] Christopher Withers, Saralees Nadarajah . Some linear differential equations generated by matrices. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(6): 9588-9602. doi: 10.3934/math.2022533
    [8] Yue Liu, Yixian Wen, Yulan Xiao, Lichang Zhang, Shan Huang . Identification of the enterprise financialization motivation on crowding out R&D innovation: evidence from listed companies in China. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 5951-5970. doi: 10.3934/math.2024291
    [9] Erdal Bayram, Gülşah Çelik, Mustafa Gezek . An advanced encryption system based on soft sets. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 32232-32256. doi: 10.3934/math.20241547
    [10] Mustafa M. Hasaballah, Yusra A. Tashkandy, Oluwafemi Samson Balogun, M. E. Bakr . Reliability analysis for two populations Nadarajah-Haghighi distribution under Joint progressive type-II censoring. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(4): 10333-10352. doi: 10.3934/math.2024505
  • Research and development (R&D) of key generic technology (KGT) is conducive to improving the innovation capacity of countries and regions and has a significant impact on economic development and social progress. Compared to other technologies, the factors affecting the R&D decisions of KGT are more complex and need to be explored in depth. This study constructs a Stackelberg model considering R&D effort level, R&D efficiency and product differentiation to investigate the leader's and follower's decisions on R&D of KGT under three types of R&D modes. The results reveal that firms' strategic decisions are affected by product differentiation, R&D efficiency and different R&D modes. Product differentiation and R&D efficiency have impacts on equilibrium results and government subsidies for KGT R&D are optimal for social welfare.



    Globally, key generic technology (KGT) is of great strategic significance and practical value for social progress and sustainable economic development. KGT has attracted increasing attention from academia, government and business in recent decades [1,2,3,4]. KGT refers to the dominant and foundational technology that can be widely applied in multiple technological fields and spread and shared among various manufacturing industries, which has a strong spillover effect. KGT is often considered as a significant innovation that facilitates plentiful incremental innovations, considerably improving social benefits and driving economic growth [5,6,7,8]. In particular, in the range of emerging technologies, the breakthrough of KGT is the key to promoting technological advancement from imitative to independent innovation, from single to integrated innovation and from product to industrial competition [9]. Therefore, numerous economies have implemented policies to encourage the research and development (R&D) of KGT. For instance, in 2021, the Chinese government updated the "Industrial Critical Generic Technology Development Guide, " which provides priority and support to the R&D of 174 KGT(s), including the raw material, equipment manufacturing, electronic information, communication industries and so on. Similarly, the Unites States Congress raised the "American Technology Preeminence Act, " which proposes that KGT can promote industrial development and enhance national welfare. The European Union has formulated the "Cooperation of Science and Technology" to unite the technological forces of European countries and enhance the international competitiveness of European firms.

    As forward-looking technologies in a fundamental and core position, KGT in the emerging technology fields are pivotal links between basic and applied research. Previous studies demonstrate that KGT plays a crucial supporting role in the technological innovation chain and maintains the core competitiveness of strategic emerging industries [10,11]. However, in the emerging technological fields, the valuable KGT often falls into the R&D dilemma. Specifically, the R&D of KGT is generally recognized as high threshold and cost, long cycle, high risk and obvious spillover [12]. Therefore, firms have a strong incentive of free-riding and aim to enjoy the "spillover effect" bonus of KGT, which would trigger the market failure of the R&D of KGT [13]. Joint R&D is an effective form of cooperation to promote the R&D of KGT. Joint R&D refers to two or more entities working together to conduct R&D activities [14]. Joint R&D projects can be divided into three types (invention, innovation and diffusion projects) [15]. Joint R&D is an important approach to technological innovation by sharing the development costs and risks, which can effectively promote the R&D of KGT in the context of the contradiction between rapidly growing technological demand and the R&D dilemma. Furthermore, it plays a predominant role in improving and maintaining the competitiveness of firms and is the most significant element of diffusion processes [16]. Meanwhile, with the accelerating development of technology, a shorter response time is required to capture changing market demands, driving a growing need for interfacing people and disciplines and integrating critical skills, and joint R&D is the key means. Hagedoorn [17] indicated that the benefits of developing joint R&D activities for firms in technology include accelerating the development of innovation and improving market transactions. In reality, the government and firms usually take measures such as intellectual property protection mechanisms, risk and responsibility sharing, benefits and intellectual property sharing to promote joint R&D activities [18].

    Furthermore, along with these characteristics of R&D, governments and their policymakers, also conscious of this reality, are advocating the development of joint R&D in the technological innovation field by providing government subsidies. Therefore, since the 1980s, several economies, such as Europe, the US and Japan, have launched various favorable science and technology policies to encourage cooperation in R&D activities among firms, research institutes and universities. Governments should use a flexible policy mix to achieve their goals [19]. Government subsidies help firms reduce R&D investment and risk, and official policies can strengthen firms' confidence in technological innovation. Because KGT has a strong spillover effect and is beneficial to society as a whole, cooperation between the government, firms, research institutes and universities is reasonable and necessary. Interactions among these different types of participants through the development of joint R&D projects allow industry to obtain mutual benefits from the results of government-funded behavior [20]. Joint R&D is a common market approach, and government subsidies are part of the government solution. How does the R&D mode (independent R&D, joint R&D and government subsidies) affect technological innovation, firm profits, consumer surplus and social welfare? What are the effects of product differentiation and R&D efficiency on firms and government behavior under different R&D models? Which R&D model is more effective? These issues are important for firms' decisions on R&D of KGT aimed at improving competitiveness. Therefore, we construct a multiple oligopoly model that includes the R&D effort level, technology spillover, government subsidies and product differentiation. Further, we analyze firms' decision-making regarding the mode selection of KGT R&D and the government's science and technology subsidy policy.

    The abundant literature on the R&D of KGT is embodied in two aspects: definition/measurement and diffusion/supply, neither of which pay sufficient attention to the R&D dilemma and market failure of KGT. In the former aspect, theorists have employed diversified methods to recognize and measure KGT, such as system integration, text analysis, co-classification index, process parameter, technology-specific performance indicator and so on [21,22,23,24,25,26]. In the latter, scholars have analyzed the diffusion and supply of KGT from the perspective of resource recombination (knowledge, capital), government funds, industry-university-research consociation, patent cooperation networks, innovation competition, intellectual property rights and so on [27,28,29,30,31].

    Moreover, some studies have analyzed the factors and outcomes of R&D behavior on firms and industrial peers. Cohen and Levinthal [32] documented that a firm's R&D contributes to realizing spillovers from other firms' R&D efforts and improving its innovative ability. Konstantinos et al. [33] and Del Carmen Haro-Domínguez et al. [34] demonstrated that absorptive capacity is directly related to the R&D process and affects firm innovation. Grunfeld [35] probed the effects of investment and spillover on a firm's R&D decisions. Caputo et al. [36] highlighted the critical issue of how the transfer of technology from R&D to manufacturing affects technology-driven firms' innovative strategies. Pourkarimi and Kam [37] quantitatively demonstrated that R&D activities, such as increasing the R&D share and number of patents granted in advanced technology, have a significant positive effect on firm performance. Yan and Yang [38] analyzed the optimal licensing schemes for a mixed-ownership firm when facing uncertain R&D outcomes and technology spillover and established that the probability of R&D success plays a critical role in the process of determining the licensing strategy for the mixed firm. Blanco et al. [39] highlighted the necessity of revising government R&D policies toward greater coordination and resources and the implementation of new instruments, considering the impact of R&D expenditure on economic growth, development and integration. Kučera and Fiľa [40] took European Union countries as samples to identify the possible impact of R&D expenditure on innovation performance and influence of the innovation performance on economic development, and established a significant interdependence between R&D expenditure, innovation performance and level of economic development.

    Other studies have focused on government policies promoting firms' R&D innovation. For example, Kim and Park [41] revealed that government investment in joint R&D contributes to the improvement of the short-term business performance of firms engaging in joint R&D projects supported by the government. Tong et al. [42] empirically documented that government subsidies can realize the purpose of stimulating the innovation of high-tech enterprises and highlighted the subsidy mechanism includes resource and signal transmission effects. Furthermore, Wu and Zhao [43] examined the impact of government R&D subsidies on enterprise R&D activities from both theoretical and empirical perspectives and proposed that R&D subsidies play a critical positive role in motivating the R&D projects of firms, and the incentive effect of subsidies will be enhanced with the improvement of R&D investment and efficiency.

    However, concerning the R&D dilemma and market failure of KGT, the core role of leading firms with certain advantages and government policy remains to be further examined during joint R&D of KGT, especially the choice of R&D mode. Currently, the effects of different R&D modes on a firm's technology strategy and government behavior, and the multiple characteristics of the R&D mode, such as R&D effort level, R&D efficiency, technology spillover and government subsidies remain under consideration. In other words, we do not have a satisfactory answer to the question of "how to promote the R&D of KGT in building emerging technology knowledge mansions." Moreover, considering the key features of the spillover effect and "quasi-public goods" of KGT, the R&D of KGT requires a greater range of technological resource gathering and the participation of multiple parties, including government, firms, universities and research institutions. Therefore, technological innovation cooperation is a significant enabler for KGT R&D. The main contents of the literature review and the innovation points of this study are listed in Table 1.

    Table 1.  Summary of the literature.
    Research orientation Research contents References Innovation points
    Definition and measurement of KGT Using methods such as system integration, text analysis, co-classification index, process parameter, technology-specific performance indicators, etc. Leydesdorff, 2008; Bekar et al., 2018; Heikkilä et al., 2023; da Ponte et al., 2023; Shafique and Hagedoorn, 2022; Vu et al., 2020
    Diffusion and supply of KGT Analyzing from the perspective of resource recombination (knowledge, capital), government funds, industry-university-research consociation, patent cooperation network, innovation competition, intellectual property rights, etc. Appio et al., 2017; Kokshagina et al., 2017; Zheng et al., 2023; Franzò et al., 2023; Cen et al., 2022 Construct a Stackelberg model considering more realistic factors using sequential game theory.
    Factors affecting KGT R&D Impacts of other firms' behavior, absorptive capacity, investment and spillover effects on R&D decisions of KGT. Cohen and Levinthal, 1989; Konstantinos et al., 2011; del Carmen et al., 2007; Grunfeld, 2003 Degree of product differentiation, R&D effort level, R&D efficiency, technology spillover and government subsidies are incorporated into the model.
    Government policy Impacts of government R&D investment and subsidies on KGT. Kim and Park, 2021; Tong et al., 2021; Wu and Zhao, 2021 Analyze the boundaries of joint R&D and government subsidies.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    This paper contributes to existing research as follows: First, we conduct a comparative analysis of one firm's independent R&D, two firm's joint R&D and one firm's independent R&D with government subsidies. This helps reveal the boundaries of joint R&D and government subsidies effectively, which provides the guiding value for understanding the role of joint R&D, and government and market mechanisms in a firm's technological innovation. Second, our duopoly model includes various factors that are more comprehensive and closer to reality. Parameters such as the degree of product differentiation, R&D effort level, R&D efficiency, technology spillover and government subsidies are introduced in the model, which enriches and expands existing research.

    The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes our model construction, which includes three models: one firm's independent R&D (Model IR), a model (Model JR) in which two firms conduct joint R&D and one (Model SR) in which one firm conducts technology R&D with government subsidies. Section 3 presents the equilibrium results for the three models and analyzes the effects of product differentiation and R&D efficiency on each equilibrium outcome. Section 4 compares and analyzes the equilibrium results to reveal the boundaries of different R&D modes. Finally, our conclusions are presented in Section 5. Related proofs are provided in the Appendix.

    Construct a Stackelberg oligopolistic market model with Firm 1 (leader) and Firm 2 (follower), which produce differentiated products. The linear inverse demand function is pi=aqirqj [44,45], where qi is the output of each firm, and r[0,1] is the degree of product differentiation (the higher the value, the weaker the heterogeneity), i,j=1,2 and ij. Firm 1 is faced with the R&D of KGT. The R&D cost is c1=tb22 [46,47], where b>0 is the R&D effort level and t>0 is the R&D efficiency (the higher the value, the lower the efficiency). For simplicity, no production cost is considered in this analysis. Thus, Firm 1's profit function is π1=(p1+b)q1c1. However, because of the spillover effect of KGT, Firm 2's profit function is defined as π2=(p2+λb)q2, where λ(0,1) is the degree of spillover (the higher the value, the stronger the spillover effect). The consumer surplus function is cs=q12+q22+2rq1q22, social welfare function is sw=2i=1πi+cs.

    Consider three types of firm R&D modes: (ⅰ) One firm conducts independent R&D and we define the case as Model IR (independent R&D), and the equilibrium results are denoted by the superscript IR, . (ⅱ) Two firms conduct joint R&D and share the R&D cost, and we define the case as Model JR (joint R&D). If 0<β<1 is the proportion of R&D cost undertaken by Firm 1, then the cost functions of the two firms are c1=tβb22 and c2=t(1β)b22 [48]. Regardless of the spillover effect, Firm 2's profit function changes as π2=(p2+b)q2c2, and the equilibrium results are denoted by superscript JR. (ⅲ) The government subsidizes Firm 1 and the subsidy rate is 0<s<1, and we define the case as Model SR (subsidizing R&D). Then, Firm 1's cost and profit functions are changed into c1s=(1s)tb22 and π1=(p1+b)q1c1s, and the social welfare function is sw=2i=1πi+csstb22. The equilibrium results are denoted by the superscript SU.

    In the above game, that under Model IR is divided into two stages. In the first stage, Firm 1 determines the optimal R&D effort level b to maximize its profits. In the second stage, Firm 1 and Firm 2 determine the optimal output qi according to profit maximization sequentially.

    When the two firms conduct the joint R&D project, Model JR has three stages. In the first stage, Firm 1 determines the optimal proportion of R&D cost β. In the second stage, Firm 1 determines the optimal R&D effort level b to maximize its profits. In the third stage, the firms choose their optimal outputs qi under Stackelberg competition.

    When the government subsidizes the firm's R&D activity, the game under Model SR contains three stages. In the first stage, the government determines the optimal subsidy rate s to maximize social welfare. In the second stage, Firm 1 determines the optimal R&D effort level b required to maximize its profits. In the third stage, each firm chooses the optimal output qi in the Stackelberg competition. The notations used in the models are listed in Table 2.

    Table 2.  Model notation.
    i,j Index for firms, i,j=1,2 and ij
    qi Deterministic production for Firm i
    pi Deterministic price for Firm i
    r Degree of product differentiation
    ci The R&D cost function of Firm i
    β The proportion of R&D cost undertaken by Firm 1
    b R&D effort level
    t R&D efficiency
    λ Degree of spillover
    s Government subsidy rate
    πi Profit function of Firm i
    cs Consumer surplus function
    sw Social welfare function
    IR One firm conducts independent R&D
    JR Two firms conduct joint R&D
    SR One firm conducts R&D with government subsidies
    Optimal values of different variables

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    When the leading firm conducts R&D of KGT, in the second stage, each firm pursues maximal profits by satisfying πiqi=0. The optimal quantity can then be deduced as

    q1=2(a+b)r(a+λb)2(2r2),q2=(4r2)(a+λb)2r(a+b)4(2r2). (1)

    In the first stage, Firm 1 determines the optimal R&D effort level according to π1b=0. Then, we can obtain

    bIR=a(2r)(λr2)(λ2+4t)r24(rλ+2t1). (2)

    Normal production requires t>tIR0=2λr2r2; then, equilibrium results can be obtained in the case of Model IR, as presented in Lemma 1.

    Lemma 1. The equilibrium results in the case of Model IR are:

    qIR1=2at(r2)(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),qIR2=a(r2t+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1))(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),
    pIR1=a(2r)(r2tλr+2(1t))(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),pIR2=a((λ2+t)r2(λ2+3λ2t)r2(2tλ1)(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),
    πIR1=a2t(2r)22((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1)),πIR2=a2(r2t+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2,
    csIR=a2(4(2r)2t2+4rt(r2)((r2+2r4)t+(λ1)(λr2))+((r2+2r4)t+(λ1)(λr2))2)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2,
    swIR=a2((7r420r316(r24r+2))t2((2λr)(λr32(λ+2)r2+4(52λ)r+8(λ2)))t(λ1)2(λr2)2)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2.

    The equilibrium results are obviously affected by the values of r and t. Proposition 1 can be obtained by analyzing these effects.

    Proposition 1. Under Model IR, the effects of r and t on the equilibrium results are:

    (i) The effects of r:

    If 0<λ<4rr222r2, 22<r<1 and tIR0<t<t1, then πIR1r>0; if 0<λ<4rr222r2, 22<r<1 and t>t1, then πIR1r<0; πIR2r<0; csIRr<0; swIRr>0; when 0<r<22, if tFR0<t<t2, then bIRr<0; if t>t2, then bIRr>0.

    (ii) the effects of t:

    πIR1t<0; πIR2t<0; when f3(t)<0, csIRt>0; otherwise, csIRt<0; when f4(t)<0, then swIRt>0; otherwise, SWIRt<0; bIRt<0.

    Proof. See Appendix A

    As demonstrated in Proposition 1, if the leading firm conducts an R&D project that competes with the no R&D firm in Stackelberg competition with a spillover effect when t>tIR0, the product differentiation strategy can boost the quantity of Firm 2 and consumer surplus. But the impact of r on π1 depends on the value ranges of λ and t. Specifically, when the degree of spillover is under the critical value and R&D efficiency is relatively low, increasing product differentiation can improve the R&D-conducting firm's profit. Furthermore, the positive influences of t on πi and b manifest such that increasing R&D efficiency enhances the two firms' profits and the R&D effort level of Firm 1. This means that the growth in R&D efficiency can motivate firms to conduct more R&D activities of technological innovation, and peer firms can enjoy the increasing spillover effect bonus. However, the relationships between R&D efficiency and consumer surplus and social welfare display an inverted U-shaped trend. This finding indicates that the influences of R&D efficiency on consumers and the whole society are complex and nonlinear. On the one hand, a high R&D efficiency level helps firms enhance the technological innovation adopted in their products and services, which benefits downstream firms and consumers. On the other hand, an R&D efficiency level that is too high will widen the technological gap between the firm and its stakeholders, leading to disadvantages such as a cooperation dilemma, which has a negative impact on consumers and society as a whole. Therefore, firms should improve their R&D efficiency within a certain range by integrating the resources and advantages of multiple actors to promote the continuous improvement of scientific and technological innovation abilities and further develop the R&D of KGT.

    When two firms conduct joint R&D of KGT, in the third stage, Firm i pursues maximal profits according to πiqi=0. Then, the quantity of each firm is

    q1=(a+b)(2r)2(2r2),q2=(4r22r)(a+b)4(2r2). (3)

    In the second stage, the leading Firm 1 determines the optimal R&D effort level for the maximal profits. Substituting q1 into π1(q1,b), the following can be derived when π1(b)b=0:

    b(β)=a(2r)24βt(2r2)(2r)2. (4)

    Substituting Formula (4) into π1(b) and Formula (3), we can obtain:

    q1(β)=2(r2)atβ4βt(r22)+(2r)2,q1(β)=2(r2)atβ4βt(r22)+(2r)2, (5)
    πJR1(β)=βt(2r)2a22(4βt(2r2)(2r)2),πJR2(β)=ta2((β2t+12β12)r4+4(β2tβ+1)r34(β2t3β+3)r216(β2t+β1)r+8(β2t+β1))(4βt(r22)+(2r)2)2. (6)

    In the first stage, Firm 1 (the leader) determines the optimal proportion of R&D costs. This must be profitable for both Firms 1 and 2, which satisfies

    πJR1πIR10, (7)
    πJR2πIR20. (8)

    After calculation, when β0=(2r)24t(2r2)<ββ1=(2r)2(2λr)2, πJR1πIR1 and πJR2πIR2 exists. Therefore, the optimal proportion of R&D cost is βJR=(2r)2(2λr)2.

    Normal production requires 0<r<0.914394 and t>tJR0=(2λr)2(2r)(2r2), then equilibrium results can be obtained in Model JR, as presented in Lemma 2.

    Lemma 2. The equilibrium results under Model JR are:

    βJR=(2r)2(2λr)2,bJR=(2λr)2a(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),qCJR1=2at(2r)(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),
    qJR2=at(r2+2r4)(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),pJR1=a(r3t(λ2+2t)r2+2(2λt)r+4(t1))(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),
    pJR2=a((λ2+t)r22(2λt)r4(t1))(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1),πJR1=a2(2r)2t2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1)),
    πJR2=a2t((λ4λ22t)r44(2λ3λ2λ+2t)r3+4(5λ24λ+2t1)r216(λ2t1)32t)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2,
    csJR=a2t2(5r4+4r332(r21))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2,
    swJR=ta2((λ43t)r44(2λ3+7t)r3+24(λ2+2t)r2+32(2tλ)r16(6t1))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2.

    Proposition 2. Under Model JR, the effects of r and t on the equilibrium results are:

    (i) The effects of r:

    πJR1r<0; πJR2r<0; if λ1<λ<1 and tJR0<t<t5, then csJRr<0; if λ1<λ<1 and t>t5, then csJRr>0; swJRr<0; if λ<r<0.914394, then bJRr>0; if 0<r<λ, then bJRr<0; βJRr<0.

    (ii) The effects of t:

    πJR1t<0; if tJR0<t<t6, then πJR2t>0; if t>t6, then πJR2t<0; csJRt<0; swJRt<0; bJRt<0; βJRt=0.

    Proof. See Appendix B

    As demonstrated in Proposition 2, when the two firms conduct joint R&D in Stackelberg competition with 0<r<0.914394 and t>tJR0, a high degree of product differentiation can boost the proportion of R&D costs undertaken by Firm 1, profits of the two firms and social welfare. However, a U-shaped relationship exists between r and cs, indicating the nonlinear effects of product differentiation on consumers. At a low level of product differentiation, Firm 1 undertakes higher competitive pressure and is more likely to increase its R&D effort level when implementing R&D activities. Furthermore, the growth in R&D efficiency increases the profit and R&D effort level of Firm 1, consumer surplus and social welfare, but has no impact on the proportion of R&D cost of the leading firm. The effect of R&D efficiency on Firm 2's profit depends on the value range of t. Specifically, when t>t6, improving R&D efficiency benefits the follower's profit. This suggests that the two firms conducting joint R&D should have narrow levels of technological innovation, otherwise, the joint R&D may be ineffective owing to the unsynchronous development between the collaborators. The firms should maintain coordination and cooperation in the R&D process, which helps to ensure that both firms can be more effective in the realization of technological innovation and the achievement of goals.

    Compared with Proposition 1, the relationship between r and sw changes from a positive to a negative correlation, and significant changes occur in how r and t affect cs. That is, r is no longer completely negatively correlated with cs, but t has a monotonic impact on cs. The inverted U-shaped relationship between r and π1 becomes negative, which is also reflected in the interaction between t and sw. These changes are attributable to the changes in firm's R&D modes. Furthermore, the effects of r on π2 are the same as that in Proposition 1.

    In the third stage, each firm maximizes its profits by satisfying πiqi=0, then the equilibrium quantities can be obtained as

    q1=2(a+b)r(a+λb)2(2r2),q2=(4r2)(a+λb)2r(a+b)4(2r2). (9)

    In the second stage, the optimal R&D effort level of Firm 1 when π1b=0 can be obtained as

    b(s)=a(r2)(λr2)(4t(s1)λ2)r2+4(λr1)+8(1s)t. (10)

    In the first stage, the optimal government subsidy for maximal social welfare can be determined as

    sSR=((7r4+6r336r2+16(3r))λ+2r2(3r2)+16(1r))t+(5r212)λ3r(5r3+8r212(r+2))λ2+4(2r2r6)λ+4r(3r4+14r34(7r2+8r12))λ+2r2(7r10)+16(32r))t. (11)

    Normal production of firms requires t>tSR0=(3r428r2+48)λ2+4r(7r216)λ+4(125r2)16(r44r2+4), then equilibrium results can be obtained in Model SR, as presented in Lemma 3.

    Lemma 3. The equilibrium results under Model SR are:

    bSR=(3λr4+14λr328λr2+14r332rλ20r2+48(λ+1)32r)a(16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1);
    qSR1=2(4r3t+(5λ25λ8t)r2+2(λ4t1)r12λ(λ1)+16t)a(16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1);
    qSR2=2(2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r3+6(1λ2t)r22(λ2λ+4t)r+4(3λ3+4t))a(16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1);
    pSR1=(a(4r5t+(5λ28t2λ)r4+4(4λ4t+3)r3+2(11λ2+18t3λ15)r2+4(4t9λ7)r+8(3λ24t+3λ+6)))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1));
    pSR2=a((4t3λ2)r44(3λ2+4λ2t)r3+4(7λ2+2λ6t+3)r2+(7λ2+9λ4t)r12λ2+8t6(λ+1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1));
    πSR1=a2(4r4t+(5λ25λ16t)r32(10λ26λ4t+1)r24(3λ22λ8t1)r+8(3λ23λ4t))2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1));
    πSR2=4a2(2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ2t1)r2+2rλ(1λ)8rt+12(λ1)+16t)2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2;
    csSR=2a2(20t2r8+16t(2λ22λ+t)r7+(11λ422λ3+32λ2t+11λ296λt208t2+64t)r6+(136λ268λ3192λ2t+256λt64(t+1)68λ)r5+(46λ323λ4224λ2t11λ2+576λt+720t224λ352t+12)r4+(324λ3+(384t648)λ2+64t(t10λt)324λ+256t)r3+(136λ368λ4+512λ2t160λ21152λt1024t2+184λ+640t92)r2+(768λ2384λ3256λ2t+512λt384λ256t)r+144(λ42λ(λ2λ+1))384t(λ2+1)+768λt+512t2)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2;
    swSR=a2(3r4t+28r3t+16(λ22λ3t+1)r264rt36λ2+72λ+96t36)2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1)).

    We can obtain Proposition 3 by analyzing how the values of r and t affect the equilibrium outcomes.

    Proposition 3. Under Model SR, the effects of r and t on the equilibrium results are:

    (i) The effects of r:

    πSR1r<0; if tSR0<t<t7, then πSR2r>0; if t>t7, then πSR2r<0; csSRr>0; swSRr<0; bSRr<0; sSRr>0.

    (ii) The effects of t:

    πSR1t<0; if tSR0<t<t7, then πSR2t>0; if t>t7, then πSR2t<0; csSRt<0; swSRt<0; bSRt<0; sSRt>0.

    Proof. See Appendix C

    As demonstrated in Proposition 3, when the government subsidizes the firm's R&D activity in Stackelberg competition with t>tSR0, r and t are negatively correlated with π1, which reveals that the improvements of product differentiation and R&D efficiency add to the leading firm's profit. The leading firm can adopt a product differentiation strategy to promote its profit, and social welfare will also be improved. Whether the strategy benefits the follower's profit depends on the value range of the R&D efficiency. r and t have the same nonlinear impact on the follower's profits. The follower can benefit from the R&D activities of the leader only when R&D efficiency is relatively low. Furthermore, the growth of product differentiation and R&D efficiency will motivate the leading firm to enhance R&D effort and improve social welfare, but the government thus reduces subsidies for firms' R&D activity. Consumer surplus can be improved by increasing the R&D efficiency of Firm 1.

    The impacts of r and t on π2, cs and sw in Proposition 3 are different from those in Proposition 1. The complete negative correlation between r (or t) and π2 becomes a non-monotonic interaction, the uncertain relationship between t and cs (or sw) is replaced with a negative correlation and the U-shaped trend between r and b changes into a negative correlation. These changes are the result of government subsidies. The effects of t on π1 and b are identical to those in Propositions 1 and 2. Therefore, the roles of product differentiation and R&D efficiency are dynamic and should be flexibly grasped in different contexts.

    To ensure firms' normal productions, we can obtain t>tJR0=(2λr)2(2r)(2r2) under the three types of R&D modes. The results are presented as follows.

    Corollary 1. πSR1>πIR1=πJR1.

    Proof. See Appendix D

    As shown in Corollary 1, the leading firm's profit is maximized when the government provides subsidies for R&D activity in the Stackelberg competition. If there are no government subsidies, the profit of the leading firm will decrease regardless of whether it is conducting independent or joint R&D. Note that the profit under independent R&D mode is the same as that under joint R&D mode, indicating that the value of πIR1 (πJR1) is the boundary of whether Firm 1 implements joint R&D, and Firm 1 has no reason to reject joint R&D. Additionally, the definite comparative relationship among the three types of profits shows that the government subsidy mode has the absolute advantage of improving the leading firm's profit, which can help relieve the R&D cost burden and boost confidence in the R&D process.

    Corollary 2. πSR2>πJR2>πIR2.

    Proof. See Appendix E

    As presented in Corollary 2, the follower obtains maximal profits when the government provides subsidies to Firm 1's R&D activity under Stackelberg competition. If the government subsidies are canceled, the follower's profit πJR2 will rank second among the three models. The follower's profits are minimized when the leading firm conducts R&D activity independently. The government's fund support has a direct, positive impact on the follower's profit. Therefore, by enjoying the technological and capital advantages of the leading firm, small and medium-sized firms should actively cooperate with industrial leaders in the R&D of KGT to solve R&D dilemmas and improve their technological innovation ability.

    Corollary 3. If tJR0<t<t8, then csSR>csIR>csJR; if t>t8, then csSR>csJR>csIR.

    Proof. See Appendix F

    As indicated in Corollary 3, consumer surplus is always maximized when the government subsidizes Firm 1's R&D activity in Stackelberg competition, regardless of the value range of t. However, a comparison of the consumer surplus under independent and joint R&D modes is uncertain. Specifically, the consumer surplus under joint R&D mode will be greater if the value of t is above the critical value and smaller than that under Model IR. That is, the government subsidies mode has the absolute advantage of improving consumer surplus. The R&D cooperation between two firms can improve the utility of consumers only when the R&D efficiency is relatively low. Too large an R&D efficiency gap will lead to cooperation difficulties, which are not conducive to the improvement of consumer surplus.

    Corollary 4. swSR>swJR>swIR.

    Proof. See Appendix G

    As presented in Corollary 4, the social welfare ranking is consistent with that of Firm 2's profit, revealing the strong, positive correlation between social welfare and the profit of the follower. From the perspective of social welfare, one firm conducting R&D with government subsidies is optimal, indicating that the government support promotes the maximization of social welfare. Under such support, the increase in the follower's profit will compensate for the lost consumer surplus when the leading firm conducts R&D activity, thus resulting in an overall increase in social welfare. By synthesizing Corollaries 1–4, we can determine that the function of government behavior in guiding firm R&D activities is far greater than that of firms. From the perspectives of firms, consumers and the whole of society, government behaviors always play a dominant role in motivating firm R&D and technological innovation.

    This study constructs a Stackelberg model considering R&D effort level, technology spillover, R&D efficiency and product differentiation to investigate the leader's and follower's decisions on R&D of KGT under independent, joint and government subsidy R&D modes. The results reveal the condition for joint R&D and the factors that affect R&D activities. The main conclusions are as follows.

    First, the firms' strategic decision on the R&D of KGT is affected by product differentiation, R&D efficiency, and different R&D modes. When the leading firm conducts independent R&D activities, increasing product differentiation can enhance the follower's profit, consumer surplus and social welfare, but may not improve the leading firm's profit, depending on the degree of spillover and R&D efficiency. In Model JR, the growth in R&D efficiency boosts the profits of the leading firm, consumer surplus and social welfare. However, improving R&D efficiency benefits follower's profits only when R&D efficiency is relatively low. This suggests that the two firms conducting joint R&D should have narrow levels of technological innovation to ensure effective cooperation. In Model SR, the leading firm can adopt the product differentiation strategy to promote its profit and social welfare will also be improved. However, whether the product differentiation strategy benefits the follower's profit depends on the value range of the R&D efficiency. Furthermore, when the government funds the firm's R&D project, the improvement in R&D efficiency helps increase consumer surplus and social welfare, which is the same as under the joint R&D mode. In other words, an improvement in R&D efficiency can produce more profits for the leading firm among the three types of R&D modes. Therefore, the leading firm should vigorously improve R&D efficiency by integrating the resources and advantages of multiple actors to promote the continuous improvement of scientific and technological innovation abilities, and further develop the R&D of KGT.

    Second, product differentiation and R&D efficiency exert varied impacts on the firm's R&D behaviors and the level of government subsidies under different R&D modes. In Model IR, when R&D efficiency is high, product differentiation motivates the leading firm to increase its R&D efforts and investments. However, the R&D efforts can be enhanced with the growth of product differentiation only when the products of the two firms are highly heterogeneous. Different from independent and joint R&D modes, product differentiation can always promote the leading firm's R&D efforts but reduces government subsidies, which are unaffected by any factors. The main reason is that product differentiation has a positive effect on the leading firm's R&D efforts, profit and social welfare, which conforms to the government's goal. Thus, the government subsidies are finally decreased. We also found that an increase in R&D efficiency will motivate the leading firm's R&D efforts under the three R&D modes. This means that enhancing R&D efficiency is a significant way to help technology-driven firms solve R&D difficulty and promote R&D innovation of KGT.

    Third, the comparative analyses reveal the various characteristics of independent R&D, joint R&D and government subsidies. The leading firm's profit is maximized when the government provides subsidies to the R&D activity in the Stackelberg competition. If the government provides no subsidies, the leading firm's profit will decrease regardless of whether independent or joint R&D is conducted. Note that the profit under the independent R&D mode is the same as that under the joint R&D mode, which reveals the boundary between the two modes. In terms of the follower, its profits will be maximized under government subsidy policy but minimized when the leading firm conducts R&D activity independently. Furthermore, consumer surplus is always maximized under government subsidies. The R&D cooperation between two firms can improve the utility of consumers only when the R&D efficiency is relatively low. Note that the social welfare ranking is consistent with that of the follower's profit, displaying a positive correlation between social welfare and the follower's profit. From the perspective of social welfare, one firm conducting R&D with government subsidies is optimal, owing to the government's goal of social welfare maximization. Moreover, the comparative analyses reveal the absolute advantage of the government in improving the profits of the leader and follower, consumer surplus and social welfare, indicating the considerable functions of government behaviors in guiding firms' R&D activities. Government behaviors play a dominant role in motivating firm R&D of KGT.

    Based on the above conclusions, the government should formulate effective favorable policies such as subsidy support and improve the management system for input into science and technology. Government financial investment in science and technological innovation reflects the regional and industrial levels of science and technology. Providing more funding support can promote the improvement of the innovation efficiency of technology-driven firms. Additionally, firms should start from improving R&D efficiency, and take measures from aspects of researchers, R&D funds, knowledge sharing and so on. In return for the spillover effect bonus of KGT, joint R&D should be actively conducted with the government, universities, scientific research institutions and upstream and downstream firms, giving full play to the advantages of different participants and adjusting the resource allocation structure to overcome the R&D problems of KGT. These recommendations have positive and practical value for enterprises to conduct KGT R&D and for the government to optimize technology policies in a complex market environment.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.

    (ⅰ) Effects of r:

    πIR1r=2a2t(2r)((λ2λ+4t)r2(λ+2t1))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. Let f1(t)def=(λ2λ+4t)r2(λ+2t1)=0, and there is t1=(2λr)(1λ)4(1r). Under the condition of 22<r<1, if 0<λ<4rr222r2 and tIR0<t<t1, then πIR1r>0; if 0<λ<4rr222r2 and t>t1, then πIR1r<0.

    πIR2r=a2(2(λ4+6λ2tλ3+t2)r28(λ3+(2t1)λ2+2(2λt+2t2t))r+8(2t+1)λ2+8(2t1)λ+16t(t1))(r2t+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1))(4(λr+2t1)(λ2+4t)r2)3. When t>tIR0, there is 2(λ4+6λ2tλ3+t2)r28(λ3+(2t1)λ2+2(2λt+2t2t))r+8(2t+1)λ2+8(2t1)λ+16t(t1)>0, r2t+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1)<0, and 4(λr+2t1)(λ2+4t)r2>0. Therefore, if t>tIR0, then πIR2r<0.

    csIRr=a2((40t3+2λ(7λ8)t2+λ3(λ1)t)r4(8t2(6t4λ2+7λ3)4λ2(3λ27λ+4)tλ4(λ1)2)r3(144t3+24(5λ23λ5)t2+12(λ4+2λ38λ2+5λ)t+6λ3(λ1)2)r2+(64t2(6t+2λ2+λ6)+8(λ4+4λ37λ26λ+8)t+12λ2(λ1)2)r256t332(λ2+4λ9)t216(λ3+λ27λ+5)t8λ(λ1)2)(4(λr+2t1)(λ2+4t)r2)3. When t>tIR0, there is (40t3+2λ(7λ8)t2+λ3(λ1)t)r4(8t2(6t4λ2+7λ3)4λ2(3λ27λ+4)tλ4(λ1)2)r3(144t3+24(5λ23λ5)t2+12(λ4+2λ38λ2+5λ)t+6λ3(λ1)2)r2+(64t2(6t+2λ2+λ6)+8(λ4+4λ37λ26λ+8)t+12λ2(λ1)2)r256t332(λ2+4λ9)t216(λ3+λ27λ+5)t8λ(λ1)2<0, and 4(λr+2t1)(λ2+4t)r2>0. Therefore, if t>tIR0, then csIRr<0.

    swIRr=a2(λ6r32r2(r+3)λ5+(r2(rt+12t+1)+12(1t)r+4(2t+3))rλ4(r4t+28r3t+6(4t+1)r28(4t3)r+8(2t+1))λ3+(2r3t(7rt+8(2t+1))24t(5t4)r2+4(32t214t+3)r16(2t2+t1))λ2(8r3t2(2r7)18t(4t5)r216t(4t3)r+8(16t214t+1))λ+8t(5r4t23t(2t1)r33t(6t+5)r2+8(6t26t+1)r2(16t(t1)+5)))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. When t>tIR0, there is (λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1)<0, and λ6r32r2(r+3)λ5+(r2(rt+12t+1)+12(1t)r+4(2t+3))rλ4(r4t+28r3t+6(4t+1)r28(4t3)r+8(2t+1))λ3+(2r3t(7rt+8(2t+1))24t(5t4)r2+4(32t214t+3)r16(2t2+t1))λ2(8r3t2(2r7)18t(4t5)r216t(4t3)r+8(16t214t+1))λ+8t(5r4t23t(2t1)r33t(6t+5)r2+8(6t26t+1)r2(16t(t1)+5))<0. Therefore, if t>tIR0, then swIRr>0.

    bIRr=a((2λ2(λ1)+8t(λ+1))r28(λ2(12t)λ+4t)r+8(2t+1)λ+8(2t1))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. Let f2(t)def=(2λ2(λ1)+8t(λ+1))r28(λ2(12t)λ+4t)r+8(2t+1)λ+8(2t1)=0, there is t2=(2λr)2(1λ)4(r2+2)(λ+1)8r(λ+2). When 0<r<22, t2>0. Therefore, when 0<r<22, if t>t2, then bIRr>0; if tIR0<t<t2, then bIRr<0.

    (ⅱ) Effects of t:

    πIR1t=a2(2r)2(λr2)22((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2<0.

    πIR2t=2a2(r2)(λr2)(r2λ+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1))(r2λ4λ+2r)((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. When t>tIR0, there is r2λ+(λ2λ+2t)r2(2t+λ1)<0, and r2λ4λ+2r<0. Therefore, πIR2t<0.

    csIRt=a2(3r56r44r3+8r2)λ4+(32r(r21)3r58r2(r21))λ3(2r)((r3((5r+2)tr+2(710t))+20r2+16(rtr1))λ2(8r3t(r+2)+4(12t)(5r2+2r4))λ4(tr36r2t2r+8t))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. Let f3(t)def=(3r56r44r3+8r2)λ4+(32r(r21)3r58r2(r21))λ3(2r)((r3((5r+2)tr+2(710t))+20r2+16(rtr1))λ2(8r3t(r+2)+4(12t)(5r2+2r4))λ4(tr36r2t2r+8t). When t>tIR0, f3(t) can be positive or negative. Therefore, if f3(t)>0, then csIRt<0; if f3(t)<0, then csIRt>0.

    swIRt=a2(r2)(λr2)(λ3r(r3+8)4(2r3+r2+2r+4)λ2+((2r3(5r6)16(r1)(r2))t+4(7r2+4))λ12r(r1)(r+3)t+16(12r))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. Let f4(t)def=λ3r(r3+8)4(2r3+r2+2r+4)λ2+((2r3(5r6)16(r1)(r2))t+4(7r2+4))λ12r(r1)(r+3)t+16(12r). When t>tIR0, f4(t) can be positive or negative. Therefore, if f4(t)>0, then swIRt<0; if f4(t)<0, then swIRt>0.

    bIRt=a(r2)(λr2)(4r28)((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2<0.

    (ⅰ) Effects of r:

    πJR1r=2a2t(2r)((λ2+4tλ)r4t2λ+2)((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. When 0<r<0.914394 and t>tJR0, there is ((λ2+4tλ)r4t2λ+2)<0. Therefore, πJR1r<0.

    πJR2r=2a2t((λ4+(1+8t)λ32λ2t+8t2)r4((8t2)λ34λ2+6(6t+1)λ40t)λr3+12((4t1)λ34λ2t+(1+2t)λ4t(2t+3))r2+8((3(12t)λ2+6(2t1)λ+12t2+4t1)r2(2t+1)λ8t2+2))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. When 0<r<0.914394 and t>tJR0, there is (λ4+(1+8t)λ32λ2t+8t2)r4((8t2)λ34λ2+6(6t+1)λ40t)λr3+12((4t1)λ34λ2t+(1+2t)λ4t(2t+3))r2+8((3(12t)λ2+6(2t1)λ+12t2+4t1)r2(2t+1)λ8t2+2))<0. Therefore, πJR2r<0.

    csJRr=8a2t2((1/4λ2+t+5/2λ)r4+(λ4λ26t5)r3+(6t3)r2+8(λ2+2)r16λ)((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. Let f5(t)def=((1/4λ2+t+5/2λ)r4+(λ4λ26t5)r3+(6t3)r2+8(λ2+2)r16λ)=0, then t5=(2λr)((λ+10)r3+16(1λ)r2+32(λr))4r2(r26r+6). Let g1(λ)def=(λ+10)r3+16(1λ)r2+32(λr)=0, there is λ1=2r(165r23r)r316r2+32(0,1). If λ1<λ<1 and tJR0<t<t5, then csJRr<0; if λ1<λ<1 and t>t5, then csJRr>0.

    swJRr=2a2t2((8λ3+7λ2+28t+6λ)r4+4((λ2λ418(λ2+t)3)r3+4(12λ2(λ1)6t+24λ3)r2+32(6t+2λ+1)r+4(32t32λ+1))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. When t>tJR0, there is (8λ3+7λ2+28t+6λ)r4+4((λ2λ418(λ2+t)3)r3+4(12λ2(λ1)6t+24λ3)r2+32(6t+2λ+1)r+4(32t32λ+1)<0. Therefore, we can obtain swJRr<0.

    bJRr=16at(2λr)(rλ)((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. If λ<r<0.914394, then bJRr>0; if 0<r<λ, then bJRr<0. βJRr=4(2r)(1λ)(λr2)3<0.

    (ⅱ) Effects of t:

    πJR1t=a2(λr2)2(r2)22((4t+1)r2+4(r2t+1))2<0.

    πJR2t=a2(λr2)2((λ4(4t+1)λ2)r4+4(λ22λ3+(4t+1)λ8t)r3+4((2t+5)λ24λ+2t1)r2+16(6t+1(2t+1)λ)r64t)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. Let f6(t)def=(λ4(4t+1)λ2)r4+4(λ22λ3+(4t+1)λ8t)r3+4((2t+5)λ24λ+2t1)r2+16(6t+1(2t+1)λ)r64t=0, then t6=(λr2)2(rλ+r4)(λ1)r4(r4λ2+4(2λ)r32(λ2+1)r2+8(λ3)r). If tJR0<t<t6, then πJR2t>0; if t>t6, then πJR2t<0.

    csJRt=a2t(λr2)2(5r4+4r3+32(1r2))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3<0.

    swJRt=a2(λr2)2((8(2λ7)r32(2λ2+3)r4+8(λ2+10)r2+32((4λ)r5))t+λ4r48λ3r3+24λ2r232rλ+16)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))3. When t>tJR0, there is (8(2λ7)r32(2λ2+3)r4+8(λ2+10)r2+32((4λ)r5))t+λ4r48λ3r3+24λ2r232rλ+16<0. Therefore, swJRt<0.

    bJRt=4a(r22)(λr2)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2<0. βJRt=0.

    (ⅰ) Effects of r:

    πSR1r=a2((15λ3(λ1)1283λ2t32λt+256t2)r6+(60λ4+72λ3+592λ2t12λ2384λt768t2+244t)r5+(32λ4348λ3+96λ2t+472λ2+928λt512t2156λ512t)r4+(288λ4320λ32688λ2t192λ2++1280λt+3072t2+224λ768t)r3+(1872λ3384λ4+1600λ2t1840λ22624λt1024t2+432λ+1920t80)r2+(192(λ3λ2λ+1)+2816λ2384λ41536λt3072t2+256t)r+576λ41920λ32304λ2t+1920λ2+2560λt+2048t2192(2λ+1)1280t)2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, (15λ3(λ1)1283λ2t32λt+256t2)r6+(60λ4+72λ3+592λ2t12λ2384λt768t2+244t)r5+(32λ4348λ3+96λ2t+472λ2+928λt512t2156λ512t)r4+(288λ4320λ32688λ2t192λ2++1280λt+3072t2+224λ768t)r3+(1872λ3384λ4+1600λ2t1840λ22624λt1024t2+432λ+1920t80)r2+(192(λ3λ2λ+1)+2816λ2384λ41536λt3072t2+256t)r+576λ41920λ32304λ2t+1920λ2+2560λt+2048t2192(2λ+1)1280t)>0 exists. Therefore, πSR1r<0.

    πSR2r=8a2(2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ+2t1)r2+2(λλ24t)r+12(λ1)+16t)((3λ3(λ1)4λ2t40λt64t2)r6+(40λ2t+36λ2(1λ)+192λt+128t2112t)r5+(10λ3(λ1)+72λ2t148λ2+16λt+128t2+148λ+80t)r4+(160λ3(λ1)192λ2t160λ2704λt512t2+384t)r3+(88λ3(1λ)288λ2t+520λ2+256(2λ+t)520λ416t)r2+(96λ2(1λ)+256λ2+768λt+512t2+96(λ1)256t)r+96λ3(λ1)+256λ2t672λ2896λt512t2+672λ+384t)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))3. When t>tSR0, (3λ3(λ1)4λ2t40λt64t2)r6+(40λ2t+36λ2(1λ)+192λt+128t2112t)r5+(10λ3(λ1)+72λ2t148λ2+16λt+128t2+148λ+80t)r4+(160λ3(λ1)192λ2t160λ2704λt512t2+384t)r3+(88λ3(1λ)288λ2t+520λ2+256(2λ+t)520λ416t)r2+(96λ2(1λ)+256λ2+768λt+512t2+96(λ1)256t)r+96λ3(λ1)+256λ2t672λ2896λt512t2+672λ+384t<0 exists. Let f7(t)def=2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ+2t1)r2+2(λλ24t)r+12(λ1)+16t=0, then t7=(r+6)λλ2r62(r2+2r4). If tSR0<t<t7, then πSR2r>0. If t>t7, then πSR2r<0.

    csSRr=4a2((48tλ3(λ1)(232λ2+304λ)t2128t3)r10+(33λ666λ580λ4t+33λ4384λ3t16λ2t2+464λ2t+1312λt2+768t3224t2)r9+(480λ4306λ5+612λ4+1440λ3t+1920λ2t2306λ32592λ2t+768λt2+672λt+2016t2)r8+(170λ6340λ5416λ4t490λ4+3136λ3t224λ2t2+1320λ31568λ2t10624λt24608t3660λ22048λt832t2+896t)r7+(2242λ55184λ4t4484λ48800λ3t5152λ2t2+1898λ3+19136λ2t+3776λt2+3072t3+688λ24512λt11520t2344λ640t)r6+(4392λ52196λ6+λ4(5376t+2472)λ3(9600t336)+2304λ2t2576λ2t+33408λt2+9216t3+4668λ2+9600λt+11520t24800t)r5+(14976λ4t5688λ5+11376λ4+18944λ3t+2688λ2t25152λ349024λ2t19456λ28192t31072λ2+9984λt+19328t2+536λ+5120t)r4+(5840λ611680λ513952λ4t3952λ4+13568λ3t5632λ2t2+19584λ3+7808λ2t47104λt26144t39104λ214848λt28160t21376λ+7424t+688)r3+(4896λ516896λ4t9792λ413440λ3t+7680λ2t2+5184λ3+48384λ2t+30720λt2+6144t3576λ27296λt4608t2+288λ10752t)r2+(9600λ54800λ6+11008λ4t+1344λ47680λ3t4096λ2t212288λ38192λ2t+24576λt2+4800λ2+7680λt+20480t2+2688λ2816t134)r+6144λ4t8192λ2t212288λt216384λ28192t2+6144t)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))3. When t>tSR0, the numerator of csSRr is positive. Therefore, csSRr>0.

    swSRr=2a2((21λt(λ1)112t2)r6+(24λ248λ3+λ2(24158t)+256λt+288t298t)r5+(112λ(λ2+1)+λ2(52t224)192λt+320t2+140t)r4+(216λ3108λ4+λ2(720t108)1152λt1344t2+432t)r3(500λ(λ2+1)+λ2(560t1000)1248λt320t2+688t)r2+(120λ3(λ2)+λ2(96832t)+1280λt+1536t2+48λ448t24)r+576λ3+λ2(768t1152)1536λt1024t2+576λ+768t)2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, the numerator of swSRr is negative. Therefore, swSRr<0.

    bSRr=2a((21λ(λ1)112t(λ+1))r6+(60λ(1λ)+256λt+320t)r5+((λ1)(52λ2140)+320t(λ+1))r4+(288λ(λ1)1152λt1536t)r3+((1λ)(560λ2++688)320t(λ+1))r2+(384λ(1λ)+1280λt+1792t)r+768(λ21)(λ1)1024t(λ+1)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, there is (21λ(λ1)112t(λ+1))r6+(60λ(1λ)+256λt+320t)r5+((λ1)(52λ2140)+320t(λ+1))r4+(288λ(λ1)1152λt1536t)r3+((1λ)(560λ2++688)320t(λ+1))r2+(384λ(1λ)+1280λt+1792t)r+768(λ21)(λ1)1024t(λ+1)<0. Therefore, bSRr<0.

    sSRr=((15λ3(λ1)80λt(λ+1))r6+(48λ2(1λ)+256λt+176λ2t)r5+(32λ444λ3+λ2(192t136)+256λt+148λ+64t)r4+(288λ316λ4λ2(832t+384)1280λt64t+112)r3+(656λ3384λ4+λ2(448t+592)+448λt784λ80)r2+(λ2(768λ2t+384)576λ3+1024λt+192λ256t)r+576λ4768λ2(λ+t)384λ2512λt+768λ+256t192)t(3r4+14r34(7r2+8r12))λ+2r2(7r10)+16(32r))2. When t>tSR0, there is (15λ3(λ1)80λt(λ+1))r6+(48λ2(1λ)+256λt+176λ2t)r5+(32λ444λ3+λ2(192t136)+256λt+148λ+64t)r4+(288λ316λ4λ2(832t+384)1280λt64t+112)r3+(656λ3384λ4+λ2(448t+592)+448λt784λ80)r2+(λ2(768λ2t+384)576λ3+1024λt+192λ256t)r+576λ4768λ2(λ+t)384λ2512λt+768λ+256t192)<0. Therefore, sSRr>0.

    (ⅱ) Effects of t:

    πSR1t=2a2(3λ2r8+8λ(λ+1)r7(62λ2+64λ+28)r6+8(λ2+13λ+12)r5+(224λ2+192λ+40)r4(144λ2+560λ+416)r3+(224(1λ2)+64λ)r2+(192λ2+640λ+448)r384(λ+1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, there exists 3λ2r8+8λ(λ+1)r7(62λ2+64λ+28)r6+8(λ2+13λ+12)r5+(224λ2+192λ+40)r4(144λ2+560λ+416)r3+(224(1λ2)+64λ)r2+(192λ2+640λ+448)r384(λ+1)<0. Therefore, πSR1t<0.

    πSR2t=16a2(2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ+2t1)r2+2(λλ24t)r+12(λ1)+16t)(3λ2r8+2λ(7λ+10)+(8λ46λ2+28)r6(116λ2+184λ+40)r5+24(10λ2+2λ5)r4+(304λ2+512λ+176)r3+64(25λ8λ2)r2(256λ2+448λ+192)r+384λ(λ+1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))3. When t>tSR0, 3λ2r8+2λ(7λ+10)+(8λ46λ2+28)r6(116λ2+184λ+40)r5+24(10λ2+2λ5)r4+(304λ2+512λ+176)r3+64(25λ8λ2)r2(256λ2+448λ+192)r+384λ(λ+1)>0 exists. The function 2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ+2t1)r2+2(λλ24t)r+12(λ1)+16t has been defined as f7(t) presented in the above appendix as part of πSR2r. Therefore, if tSR0<t<t7, then πSR2t>0. If t>t7, then πSR2t<0.

    csSRt=16a2(15λ2r12t+(76λt(λ+1)12λ3(λ+1))r11+(56λ412λ3232λ2t44λ280λt+28t)r10+(48λ3184λ4+λ2(104800)1008λt+32λ208t)r9+(160λ3464λ4+(1532t+496)λ2+1216λt80λ+64t112)r8+(1008λ4+16λ3+(3248t992)λ2+4784λt192λ+1536t+160)r7+(1440λ4688λ3(5232t+1968)λ26208λt+512λ1488t+704)r6(2592λ4+256λ3+(6336t3488)λ2+10496λt384λ+4160t+1024)r5+(1216λ31984λ4+λ2(9536t+3328)+14336λt1088λ+5056t1472)r4+(3200λ4+256λ3+λ2(5888t5376)+10752λt256λ+4864t+2176)r3+(1024λ4768λ3λ2(8704t+2048)15360λt+768λ6656t+1024)r2(1536λ4+λ2(2048t3072)4096λt2048t1536)r+3072)t+6144λt+3072t)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))3. When t>tSR0, the numerator of csSRt is positive. Therefore, csSRt<0.

    swSRt=a2(9λ2r8+84λ(λ+1)r7+(28λ2+72λ+196)r6(976λ2+1536λ+560)r5+(176λ2384λ496)r4+(3136λ2+5760λ+2624)r3(1664λ2+2560λ+896)r2(3072λ2+6144λ+3072)r+2304(λ2+1)+4608λ)2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, there is (9λ2r8+84λ(λ+1)r7+(28λ2+72λ+196)r6(976λ2+1536λ+560)r5+(176λ2384λ496)r4+(3136λ2+5760λ+2624)r3(1664λ2+2560λ+896)r2(3072λ2+6144λ+3072)r+2304(λ2+1)+4608λ)>0. Therefore, swSRt<0.

    bSRt=16a(r44r2+4)(3λr4+14(λ+1)r34(7λ+5)r232(λ+1)r+48(λ+1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tSR0, there is 3λr4+14(λ+1)r34(7λ+5)r232(λ+1)r+48(λ+1)>0. Therefore, bSRt<0.

    sSRt=(1λ)(λr2)(5λr212λ+2r)t2(3r4+14r34(7r2+8r12))λ+2r2(7r10)+16(32r)). When t>tSR0, there is (3r4+14r34(7r2+8r12))λ+2r2(7r10)+16(32r)>0 and 5λr212λ+2r<0. Therefore, sSRt>0.

    πIR1πJR1=0.

    πIR1πSR1=a2(r2)(λr2)(7tλr4+(5λ2(λ1)+6t(λ+1))r3+(8λ(1λ)4t(9λ+1))r2+(12λ2(1λ)16t(λ+1)+4(1λ))r+24λ(λ1)+16t(3λ+1))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1)). When t>tJR0, we can get 7tλr4+(5λ2(λ1)+6t(λ+1))r3+(8λ(1λ)4t(9λ+1))r2+(12λ2(1λ)16t(λ+1)+4(1λ))r+24λ(λ1)+16t(3λ+1)>0,(λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1)<0 and (16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1)>0. Therefore, πIR1<πSR1.

    In conclusion, πSR1>πIR1=πJR1.

    πIR2πJR2=a2(1λ)(2λr)(tλ(λ+1)r3+2t(13λ)r2+2(λ2λ+8t)r4(4tλ1))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. When t>tJR0, the numerator of (πIR2πJR2) is negative. Therefore, πIR2<πJR2.

    πSR2πJR2=8a2(2r4t+(λ2λ+4t)r36(λ2t1)r2+2rλ(1λ)8rt+12(λ1)+16t)2((4t+1)r2+4(r2t+1))2(2((a2+6a+1)t8t2)a2)tr4+4(2((a2+a2)t+a2+2a)+1)tr3+(64t38(a2+10a+6)t2+4(10a(a+1)+1)t+2(2a+1)2)r2+(32(1a2a)t216(3a+2)t+8(2a+1)2)r+8(2t1)(2((a2+4a+2)t2t2)(2a+1)2)((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))22((4t+1)r2+4(r2t+1))2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tJR0, the numerator of (πSR2πJR2) is positive. Therefore, πSR2>πJR2.

    In conclusion, πSR2>πJR2>πIR2.

    csIRcsJR=a2(1λ)(2λr)(6r2t+(λ2λ4t)r2(λ+4t1))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. Let f8(t)def=6r2t+(λ2λ4t)r2(λ+4t1)=0, there is t8=(1λ)(2λr)2(3r22r4). If tJR0<t<t8, then csIR>csJR; if t>t8, then csIR<csJR.

    csIRcsSR=a2(4(2r)2t2+4rt(r2)((r2+2r4)t+(λ1)(λr2))+((r2+2r4)t+(λ1)(λr2))2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))22((20t2r8+16t(2λ22λ+t)r7+(11λ422λ3+32λ2t+11λ296λt208t2+64t)r6+(136λ268λ3192λ2t+256λt64(t+1)68λ)r5+(46λ323λ4224λ2t11λ2+576λt+720t224λ352t+12)r4+(324λ3+(384t648)λ2+64t(t10λt)324λ+256t)r3+(136λ368λ4+512λ2t160λ21152λt1024t2+184λ+640t92)r2+(768λ2384λ3256λ2t+512λt384λ256t)r+144(λ42λ(λ2λ+1))384t(λ2+1)+768λt+512t2))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2)2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1))2. When t>tJR0, the numerator of (csIRcsSR) is negative. Therefore, csIR<csSR.

    Considering csJRcsSR, we can find the numerator of (csJRcsSR) is negative. Therefore, csJR<csSR.

    In conclusion, if tJR0<t<t8, then csSR>csIR>csJR; if t>t8, then csSR>csJR>csIR.

    swIRswJR=a2((λ4t+λ2t+4t2)r4(8λ3t+2λ2t+6λt+48t2)r3+(2λ3λ4+16λ2tλ2+24λt+32t2+8t)r2+4(λ3+2λ2t2λ28λt+32t2+λ10t)r4(λ2+4λt+32t22λ12t+1))2((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2. When t>tJR0, the numerator of (swIRswJR) is negative. Therefore, swIR<swJR.

    swJRswSR=a2(t((λ43t)r44(2λ3+7t)r3+24(λ2+2t)r2+32(2tλ)r16(6t1))((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+16(4(rλ+t)3(λ2+1)))+a2(3r4t+28r3t+16(λ22λ3t+1)r28(8rt9λ12t)36(λ2+1))((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2)4((λ2+4t)r24(λr+2t1))2((16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1)). When t>tJR0, the numerator of (swJRswSR) is negative and (16t3λ2)r428λr3+4(7λ16t+5)r2+64(rλ+t)48(λ2+1)>0. Therefore, swJR<swSR.

    In conclusion, swSR>swJR>swIR.



    [1] J. Wang, R. J. Xie, W. T. Hu, The influencing factors and promotion countermeasures of industrial generic technology diffusion based on differential game, Discrete. Dyn. Nat. Soc., 2021 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/6643922 doi: 10.1155/2021/6643922
    [2] J. Ma, Developing joint R&D institutes between Chinese universities and international enterprises in China's innovation system: A case at Tsinghua University. Sustainability, 11 (2019), 7133. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11247133 doi: 10.3390/su11247133
    [3] A. Gambardella, M. S. Giarratana, General technological capabilities, product market fragmentation, and markets for technology, Res. Policy., 42 (2013), 315–325. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.08.002 doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.08.002
    [4] E. Maine, E. Garnsey, Commercializing generic technology: The case of advanced materials ventures, Res. Policy., 35 (2006), 375–393. https://doi.org/j.respol.2005.12.006
    [5] M. P. Feldman, J. W. Yoon, An empirical test for general purpose technology: An examination of the cohen-boyer rDNA technology, Ind. Corp. Change., 21 (2012), 249–275. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtr040 doi: 10.1093/icc/dtr040
    [6] M. Coccia, The source and nature of general purpose technologies for supporting next K-waves: Global leadership and the case study of the U.S. Navy's mobile user objective system, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 116 (2017), 331–339. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.05.019 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2016.05.019
    [7] A. Schaefer, D. Schiess, R. Wehrli, Long-term growth driven by a sequence of general purpose technologies, Econ. Model., 37 (2014), 23–31. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2013.10.014 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2013.10.014
    [8] L. Ardito, A. M. Petruzzelli, V. Albino, Investigating the antecedents of general purpose technologies: A patent perspective in the green energy field, J. Eng. Technol. Manage., 39 (2016), 81–100. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jengtecman.2016.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jengtecman.2016.02.002
    [9] Y. Liu, J. Du, J. Yang, An incentive mechanism for general purpose technologies R&D based on the concept of super-conflict equilibrium: Empirical evidence from nano industrial technology in China, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 147 (2019), 185–197. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2019.07.014 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2019.07.014
    [10] S. Petralia, Mapping general purpose technologies with patent data, Res. Policy., 49 (2020), 104013. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2020.104013 doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2020.104013
    [11] L. Wang, H. Shu, G. P. Zhu, A study on the relationship between different technological absorptive capacities and R&D investment in joint R&D, In: 2013 International Conference on Management Science and Engineering 20th Annual Conference Proceedings, Harbin, China, 2013, 1974–1980. https://doi.org/10.1109/ICMSE.2013.6586535
    [12] D. Rotolo, D. Hicks, B. R. Martin, What is an emerging technology? Res. Policy., 44 (2015), 1827–1843. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2015.06.006 doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2015.06.006
    [13] Y. L. Zheng, B. Yang, L. Wang, Research on the evolution of industrial generic technology R&D behavior and multiple failures, Sci. Res. Manag., 40 (2019), 164–174. https://doi.org/10.13580/j.cnki.fstc.2019.05.004 doi: 10.13580/j.cnki.fstc.2019.05.004
    [14] R. Du, S. Z. Ai, Cross-organizational knowledge acquisition through flexible hiring and joint R&D: Insights from a survey in China, Expert. Syst. Appl., 35 (2008), 434–441. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2007.07.009 doi: 10.1016/j.eswa.2007.07.009
    [15] N. Arranz, J. C. F. de Arroyabe, Joint R&D projects: Experiences in the context of European technology policy, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 73 (2006), 860–885. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2005.11.003 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2005.11.003
    [16] D. Zhao, M. Wang, X. Wang, Analysis and control strategy for relationship risk in manufacturer-supplier joint R&D, In: 2008 4th International Conference on Wireless Communications, Networking and Mobile Computing, Dalian, China, 2008, 1–4. https://doi.org/10.1109/WiCom.2008.2469
    [17] J. Hagedoorn, Understanding the rationale of strategic technology partnering: Interorganizational modes of cooperation and sectoral differences, Strateg. Manag. J., 14 (1993), 371–385. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250140505 doi: 10.1002/smj.4250140505
    [18] Y. C. Zhou, B. Zhang, J. Zou, J. Bi, K. Wang, Joint R&D in low-carbon technology development in China: A case study of the wind-turbine manufacturing industry, Energ. Policy, 46 (2012), 100–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.03.037 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2012.03.037
    [19] J. Chen, C. Sun, Y. Wang, J. Liu, P. Zhou, Carbon emission reduction policy with privatization in an oligopoly model, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res., 30 (2023), 45209–45230. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-24256-2 doi: 10.1007/s11356-022-24256-2
    [20] N. Arranz, J. C. F. de Arroyabe, Joint R&D projects as complex systems: A framework of analysis, Ieee. T. Eng. Manage., 55 (2008), 552–565. https://doi.org/doi:10.1109/TEM.2008.927816
    [21] L. Leydesdorff, On the normalization and visualization of author co-citation data: Salton's cosine versus the Jaccard index, J. Am. Soc. Inf. Sci. Tec., 59 (2008), 77–85. https://doi.org/10.1002/asi.20732 doi: 10.1002/asi.20732
    [22] C. Bekar, K. Carlaw, R. Lipsey, General purpose technologies in theory, application and controversy: A review, J. Evol. Econ., 28 (2018), 1005–1033. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0546-0 doi: 10.1007/s00191-017-0546-0
    [23] J. Heikkilä, J. Rissanen, T. Ali-Vehmas, Coopetition, standardization and general purpose technologies: A framework and an application, Telecommun. Policy., 47 (2023), N.PAG. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2022.102488 doi: 10.1016/j.telpol.2022.102488
    [24] A. da Ponte, G. Leon, I. Alvarez, Technological sovereignty of the EU in advanced 5G mobile communications: An empirical approach, Telecommun. Policy., 47 (2023), N.PAG. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2022.102459 doi: 10.1016/j.telpol.2022.102459
    [25] M. Shafique, J. Hagedoorn, Look at U: Technological scope of the acquirer, technological complementarity with the target, and post-acquisition R&D output, Technovation., 115 (2022), N.PAG. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2022.102533 doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2022.102533
    [26] K. Vu, P. Hanafizadeh, E. Bohlin, ICT as a driver of economic growth—a survey of the literature and directions for future research, Telecommun. Policy., 44 (2020), Article 101922. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2020.101922 doi: 10.1016/j.telpol.2020.101922
    [27] F. P. Appio, A. Martini, G. Fantoni, The light and shade of knowledge recombination: Insights from a general-purpose technology, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 125 (2017), 154–165. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.07.018 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2017.07.018
    [28] O. Kokshagina, T. Gillier, P. Cogez, P. L. Masson, B. Weil, Using innovation contests to promote the development of generic technologies, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 114 (2017), 152–164. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.07.035 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2016.07.035
    [29] Y. Zheng, C. Bai, L. Wang, C. Han, M. Yang, A. Pappu, Evolutionary game analysis on the diffusion of general purpose technologies with government multiple supports, Econ. Innov. New Tech., 2023, 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2023.2196418 doi: 10.1080/10438599.2023.2196418
    [30] S. Franzò, N. Doppio, A. Natalicchio, F. Frattini, L. Mion, Designing innovation contests to support external knowledge search in small and medium-sized enterprises, Technovation., 121 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2022.102684 doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2022.102684
    [31] J. Cen, L. Zhou, Z. Zhang, Who are building technical knowledge mansions? Impact of patent cooperation networks on the generic technology R&D performance of emerging enterprises, Technol. Anal. Strateg., 34 (2022), 1384–1401. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2021.1962521 doi: 10.1080/09537325.2021.1962521
    [32] W. M. Cohen, D. A. Levinthal, Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D, Econ. J., 99 (1989), 569–596. https://doi.org/10.2307/2233763 doi: 10.2307/2233763
    [33] K. Konstantinos, P. Alexandros, P. Margarita, I. George, Absorptive capacity, innovation, and financial performance, J. Bus. Res., 64 (2011), 1335–1343. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2010.12.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2010.12.005
    [34] H. del Carmen, A. Daniel, L. Francisco Javier, R. M. Antonia, The impact of absorptive capacity on technological acquisitions engineering consulting companies, Technovation., 27 (2007), 417–425. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2007.04.003 doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2007.04.003
    [35] L. A. Grunfeld, Meet me halfway but don't rush: Absorptive capacity and strategic R&D investment revisited, Int. J. Ind. Organ., 21 (2003), 1091–1109. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-7187(03)00076-6 doi: 10.1016/S0167-7187(03)00076-6
    [36] F. Caputo, P. Soto-Acosta, C. Chiacchierini, A. Mazzoleni, P. Passaro, Smashing local boundaries for sustain companies' innovativeness: The role of international R&D teams, J. Bus. Res., 128 (2021), 641–649. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.04.062 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.04.062
    [37] P. Pourkarimi, E. Kam, The impact of R&D and advertising on firm performance in high-tech industries—evidence from the U.S. information and communications technology industry, J. Quant. Econ., 20 (2022), 723–753. https://doi.org/10.1007/S40953-022-00302-1 doi: 10.1007/S40953-022-00302-1
    [38] Q. Yan, L. Yang, Optimal licensing schemes for a mixed ownership firm when facing uncertain R&D outcomes and technology spillover, Int. Rev. Econ. Financ., 58 (2018), 550–572. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2018.06.003 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2018.06.003
    [39] F. A. Blanco, F. J. Delgado, M. J. Presno, R&D expenditure in the EU: Convergence or divergence? Econ. Res.-Ekon. Istraživanja., 33 (2020), 1685–1710. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2020.1756371 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2020.1756371
    [40] J. Kučera, M. Fiľa, R&D expenditure, innovation performance and economic development of the EU countries, Entrep. Sustain., 9 (2022), 227–241. https://doi.org/10.9770/JESI.2022.9.3(14) doi: 10.9770/JESI.2022.9.3(14)
    [41] S. Kim, K. C. Park, Government funded R&D collaboration and it's impact on SME's business performance, J. Informetr., 15 (2021), 101197. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joi.2021.101197 doi: 10.1016/j.joi.2021.101197
    [42] X. Tong, Z. Wang, X. Li, The influence of government subsidy on enterprise innovation: Based on Chinese high-tech enterprises, Econ. Res.-Ekon. Istraživanja., 35 (2021), 1481–1499. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2021.1972818 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2021.1972818
    [43] W. S. Wu, K. Zhao, Government R&D subsidies and enterprise R&D activities: Theory and evidence, Econ. Res.-Ekon. Istraživanja., 35 (2021), 391–408. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2021.1893204 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2021.1893204
    [44] A. M. Spence, Product differentiation and welfare, Am. Econ. Rev., 66 (1976), 407–414. https://doi.org/10.1016/0309‐586X(76)90008-X doi: 10.1016/0309‐586X(76)90008-X
    [45] J. Chen, X. Xie, J. Liu, Capacity sharing with different oligopolistic competition and government regulation in a supply chain, Manag. Decis. Econ., 41 (2020), 79–92. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3094 doi: 10.1002/mde.3094
    [46] Q. Dong, J. C. Bárcena-Ruiz, Corporate social responsibility and partial privatization of state holding corporations, J. Econ., 132 (2021), 223–250. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00725-5 doi: 10.1007/s00712-020-00725-5
    [47] X. Wang, X. Zhang, L. Zhu, Imperfect market, emissions trading scheme, and technology adoption: A case study of an energy-intensive sector, Energ. Econ., 81 (2019), 142–158. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.03.014. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2019.03.014
    [48] J. Chen, C. Sun, J. Shi, J. Liu, Technology R&D and sharing in carbon emission reduction in a duopoly, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 183 (2022), 121936. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121936 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121936
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1408) PDF downloads(77) Cited by(0)

Figures and Tables

Tables(2)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog