
In this paper, the competitive equilibrium of the Bertrand game is discussed with bounded rationality and the utility function. When the parameters changing and the number of firms increasing, the competitive equilibrium valve of Bertrand duopoly game is gradually being blurred. When the number of competitors is more than four, it is very difficult to derive the value of the equilibrium points. How to find the general competitive equilibrium points for Bertrand game, which is studied from spatial agglomeration with mean value theorem. A Bertrand duopoly game is proposed based on a demand function. Celestial bodies motion as method is introduced to handle the number and stability of competitive equilibrium points, and the stable points is symmetry. The results are supported by numerical computation and simulations.
Citation: Bingyuan Gao, Yaxin Zheng, Jieyu Huang. General equilibrium of Bertrand game: A spatial computational approach[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(9): 10025-10036. doi: 10.3934/math.2021582
[1] | Erxi Zhu . Time-delayed feedback control for chaotic systems with coexisting attractors. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 1088-1102. doi: 10.3934/math.2024053 |
[2] | Wen Li, Deyi Li, Yuqiang Feng, Du Zou . Existence and stability of fuzzy Pareto-Nash equilibria for fuzzy constrained multi-objective games with fuzzy payoffs. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(7): 15907-15931. doi: 10.3934/math.2023812 |
[3] | Chengqing Pan, Haishu Lu . On the existence of solutions for systems of generalized vector quasi-variational equilibrium problems in abstract convex spaces with applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 29942-29973. doi: 10.3934/math.20241447 |
[4] | Huimin Li, Shuwen Xiang, Yanlong Yang, Chenwei Liu . Differential evolution particle swarm optimization algorithm based on good point set for computing Nash equilibrium of finite noncooperative game. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1309-1323. doi: 10.3934/math.2021081 |
[5] | José Luis Díaz Palencia, Abraham Otero . Instability analysis and geometric perturbation theory to a mutual beneficial interaction between species with a higher order operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(9): 17210-17224. doi: 10.3934/math.2022947 |
[6] | Ailing Li, Mengting Lv, Yifang Yan . Asymptotic stability for quaternion-valued BAM neural networks via a contradictory method and two Lyapunov functionals. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(5): 8206-8223. doi: 10.3934/math.2022457 |
[7] | Chenxuan Nie, Dan Jin, Ruizhi Yang . Hopf bifurcation analysis in a delayed diffusive predator-prey system with nonlocal competition and generalist predator. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(7): 13344-13360. doi: 10.3934/math.2022737 |
[8] | Jaicer López-Rivero, Hugo Cruz-Suárez, Carlos Camilo-Garay . Nash equilibria in risk-sensitive Markov stopping games under communication conditions. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 23997-24017. doi: 10.3934/math.20241167 |
[9] | Shunyou Xia, Chongyi Zhong, Chunrong Mo . A common fixed point theorem and its applications in abstract convex spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(3): 5236-5245. doi: 10.3934/math.2025240 |
[10] | Ruofeng Rao, Xiaodi Li . Input-to-state stability in the meaning of switching for delayed feedback switched stochastic financial system. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(1): 1040-1064. doi: 10.3934/math.2021062 |
In this paper, the competitive equilibrium of the Bertrand game is discussed with bounded rationality and the utility function. When the parameters changing and the number of firms increasing, the competitive equilibrium valve of Bertrand duopoly game is gradually being blurred. When the number of competitors is more than four, it is very difficult to derive the value of the equilibrium points. How to find the general competitive equilibrium points for Bertrand game, which is studied from spatial agglomeration with mean value theorem. A Bertrand duopoly game is proposed based on a demand function. Celestial bodies motion as method is introduced to handle the number and stability of competitive equilibrium points, and the stable points is symmetry. The results are supported by numerical computation and simulations.
After all these years the equilibrium and stability of Bertrand [1] (price) competition in an identical product market has been a topic of extensively study. Although the cases where the number and stability of equilibrium points have been thoroughly discussed, the case where the number and stability of general equilibrium points of n firms based on space agglomeration has not been analyzed. Our purpose of the present paper is to fill this gap.
For price equilibrium. Since 1883, Bertrand's comment of Cournot's oligopoly turned out to the widely used model [2]. To this day, the Bertrand oligopoly model is one of the foundations of game theory and microeconomics. It has been a topic of extensively study of the equilibrium of Bertrand. Dastidar [3,4] detected that there exists a Bertrand's equilibrium in a duopoly competition with a homogeneous product when the cost function is completely superadditive on [0, ∞). The result showed that the values of equilibrium price are much between both firms, and it exists a non-degenerate mixed equilibrium involving the prices (Hoernig, [5]). Sekiguchi et al. [6] showed, on quantum version in duopoly market, the equilibrium of the model of price competition also existed. Ogawa and Kato [7] revealed that the equilibrium price under two firms setting those prices simultaneously has a range and it equals to the study of Dastidar [3]. With the increasing of speed of adjustment, under bounded rationality (Zhang et al., [8]; Bertrand, [9]), the stability of Nash equilibrium point of a duopoly game of Bertrand model will change and cause bifurcation and chaos to occur (Ahmed et al., [10]; Ma et al., [11]). In an asymmetric triopoly, a continuum of equilibria may exist (Hirata, [12]), and the motion of the system is chaotic (Rofin and Mahanty, [13]). In the dynamical system of four heterogeneous firms, the existence and stability of fixed points were investigated, and it showed the chaotic behavior of the game (Elsadany et al., [14]). Ania [15] revealed a characterization of the set of evolutionarily stable prices existed under Bertrand oligopoly with homogeneous product by evolutionary game theory. Although an equilibria exists in a conspecific product market, the competitive price equilibrium is the only steady one. In the long run, the prices of Bertrand competition under decreasing returns will converge to the Walrasian outcome (Abbink and Brandts, [16]; Carlos et al., [17]). Specifically, as long as the equilibrium identity is nonblack, the equilibrium price shrinks to the competitive price (Hirata and Matsumura, [18]). When there are more than five oligarchs, the equilibrium price become more chaosic and may not be derived. Yu and Yu [19] found Nash equilibrium only existed in the stability region. Sun and Ma [20] further detected local stable region of Nash equilibrium point for dynamical behaviors of the system. Using converse Lyapunov theorems, Kebriaei and Rahimi-Kian [21] found the equilibrium region that belongs to the basin of attraction. In an n-person game, Ezro [22] prove the existence of an equilibrium point. Barthel and Hoffmann [23] analyzed the existence and stability of Nash equilibria in N-firm Cournot-Bertrand oligopolies. From all of the above, the equilibrium of price competition is discussed on some aspect of duopoly, triopoly, four firms, five firms and n firms. However, Li and Kendall [24] pointed out that exact solutions to the replicator equation are difficult to obtain. This paper aims to obtain general equilibrium solutions for Bertrand model.
For the equilibrium from the spatial agglomeration. Hamilton et al. [25] and Anderson and Neven [26] showed spatial agglomeration in equilibrium. Hotelling [27] revealed that the duopoly firms will cluster in the middle of the line model (Pal, [28]), in middle, there's only one equilibrium. However, centrally clustered equilibrium is only a special case (Mayer, [29]). D'Aspremont [30] revised a little for Hotelling's model, there isn't only a location for the solution of a price equilibrium. Takanori [31] extended spatial agglomeration to a model with multiple cities, the result showed firms can agglomerate at a point. Matsushima [32] further modified spatial gathering based on a circular city, firms will gather at two points. Moreover, other researchers (Anderson and Neven, [26]; Gupta et al., [33]; Sarkar et al., [34]; Takanori, [35]; Benassi, [36]; Gao and Du, [37]) mainly concentrate on spatial agglomeration of quantity competition. Whether price competitive equilibrium or quantity competitive equilibrium, for two bargainors, the system solution is always dynamically stable (THeocharis, [38]); if the number is three, the result makes it clear that we shall get finite oscillations about the equilibrium district; if the number is more than three, the agglomeration is not so robust (Picard and Tabuchi, [39]), the competitive state will always be unstable. That is to say, when there are many firms in the identical market, general equilibrium points are difficult to be derived. Yu [40] showed whether it is Bertrand competition or Cournot competition, there exist many equilibrium points, the equilibrium place shows spatial gathering by pairs (Yu and Lai, [41]), and in equilibrium place, the enterprises can obtain a more higher price, occasionally save a "sale", and the prices are without any regular pattern (Pitchik, [42]).
However, to this days, the general equilibrium points of Bertrand game have not been investigated. When the number of competitors is more than four, it is very difficult to derive the value of the equilibrium points. This paper aims to detect the general competitive equilibrium points for Bertrand game, which is studied from spatial agglomeration with mean value theorem.
In this framework, Section 2 discusses a dynamic price game with demand function and utility function. With the parameters changing, the bifurcation of equilibrium points appears and gradually becomes chaotic. Section 3 considered in a congeneric price oligopoly where there are n firms, along with identical constant cost functions. The mean value theorem is employed. A discrete general equilibrium price choice in a homogeneous price oligopoly is explored. Section 4 further considered the number and stability of general equilibrium points of Bertrand. The celestial body motion is introduced. The final section is concluding remarks of the paper.
A Bertrand duopoly game is considered with demand function. Each firm j chooses a real number pj, which is the price of product to be priced by her. The payoff of j'th firm is formulated as follows:
πj(pj,p−j)=pjqj(pj,p−j)−Cj(pj,p−j) |
where Cj(pj,p−j) is the cost function. The standard notation p−j is used to indicate the vector p with the component pj omitted. The optimal price of the firms could be calculated by solving the following problem,
maxpjπj(pj,p−j)=pjqj(pj,p−j)−Cj(pj,p−j) |
For maximizing profits for the firm, this paper puts a partial derivative πj(pj,p−j) with respect to pj equal to zero,
∂πj(pj,p−j)∂pj=qj(pj,p−j)+∂qj(pj,p−j)∂pjpj−∂Cj(pj,p−j)∂pj=0 |
For the discrete dynamical system each firm can determine the corresponding profit-maximizing price with expectation of the rival's price. The relative profit maximization will be discussed in the next section. The utility function of the representative consumer in one market is given by:
U(p1,p2)=a(p1+p2)−12(p21+p22+2bp1p2) |
The demand functions come from the maximization of the utility function of the representative consumer, are the following:
q1=a−p1−bp2, and
q2=a−p2−bp1
where p1 and p2 are the prices, q1 and q2 are the outputs, respectively. The parameter b is used to measure the degree of products differentiation. As b is one, the products is interacting, and as b is zero, the products is non-interacting. To improve the game of this work, a cost functions is considered:
Ci(pi)=cipi+ripipji,j=1,2,i≠j
ci is the marginal cost.
In a game, there are two players, they produce differentiated goods of kinds 1 and 2. With the previous assumptions, the absolute profits of each firm are seen below respectively:
π1(p1,p2)=p1(a−p1−bp2)−c1p1−r1p1p2 |
π2(p1,p2)=p2(a−p2−bp1)−c2p2−r2p1p2 |
The difference between the absolute profit is measured by the relative profit. The relative profits of firm 1 is defined by R1 and that of firm 2 by R2. The relative profits of the two firms are derived by:
R1(p1,p2)=π1(p1,p2)−π2(p1,p2)=p1(a−p1−(b+r1)p2)−p2(a−p2−(b+r2)p1)−c1p1+c2p2 |
R2(p1,p2)=π2(p1,p2)−π1(p1,p2)=p2(a−p2−(b+r2)p1)−p1(a−p1−(b+r1)p2)−c2p2+c1p1 |
Firm 1 chooses her action through maximizing her relative profit with respect to p1, firm 2 chooses her action through maximizing her relative profit with respect to p2,
a−c1−2p1−(b1−b2)p2=0, and
a−c2−2p2−(b2−b1)p1=0
where b1=b+r1 and b2=b+r2.
Two firms adjustment mechanism is considered, that is,
pi(t+1)=pi(t)+αipiΦi(pi),i=1,2
where Φi(pi) is marginal relative profit of ith firm. αi is the speed of adjustment mechanism. The discrete dynamical system of prices can be given as:
{p1(t+1)=p1(t)+α1p1(t)(a−c−2p1(t)−bp2(t))p2(t+1)=p2(t)+α2p2(t)(a−c−2p2(t)−bp1(t)) | (2.1) |
where c marginal cost of industry. α1, α2 adjustment coefficient. b coefficient of association.
In order to study the price behavior of the solutions of the nonlinear dynamic system, the equilibrium points are taken as nonnegative fixed points. It is clear that the system (1) has four fixed points in the following form:
E0=(0,0), |
E1=(a−c2,0),a>c, |
E2=(0,a−c2),a>c, |
E3=(a−c2+b,a−c2+b),a>c |
Obviously, E0, E1 and E2 are boundary equilibrium points and they are unstable. E3 is a Nash equilibrium point and it is stable. Zhao [43] further discussed the instability of the boundary equilibrium point and the stability condition of the internal equilibrium.
When α = 3.7, b = 0.1 and c = 0.2, the bifurcation appears and gradually becomes chaotic in the system (1). Such as Figure 1.
where x denotes p1, y denotes p2. The left diagram of Figure 1 shows the equilibrium points of p1 and p2 are much and chaotic. The middle diagram shows the values of p1 become chaotic with α. The right diagram shows the values of p2 become chaotic with α. That is to say, it is very difficult to find optimal equilibrium value. In this paper, we further detect a general equilibrium point for Bertrand model when there are n firms. A differentiation theorem is tried to be introduced to handle this question.
Now, we suppose that there are n (n⩾3) firms in one market. The cost function is identical or similar for each firm, and without loss of generality, the market demand function is defined:
Qi=α−piβ,i=1,2,⋯,n. | (3.1) |
where Qi is defined as the quantity, α is constant, β is correlation coefficient, pi is assumed to be the price.
When i = 1, only a firm exists in one market. The scenario is called the monopoly. The profit of a firm can be denoted:
π(p)=−p2β+α+cβp−αcβ | (3.2) |
π(p) is defined as the profit of a firm and taken partial derivative:
π′(p)=−2pβ+α+cβ | (3.3) |
The optimal price can be obtained from formula (4):
p=α+c2 | (3.4) |
parameter
α>0,β>0,α>c |
When i = n, the market belongs to a perfect competition. The price equals the marginal cost p=c(p).
Define 1. pm is one of convex points, and presumed one of general equilibrium points of the Bertrand model.
Imperfect competition is between monopoly and perfect competition. A space gathering concept model illuminates imperfectly competitive market. Such as Figure 2. The region is taken as a chaotic area between m and n. The general equilibrium points P1, P2, ⋯, Pn move around the field.
The m endpoint is defined as the monopoly market, and the n endpoint represents the perfectly competitive market.
Assumption 1. m=α+c2, n=c(p). Based on the mean-value theorem, at each point of an open interval (m,n), there is a point z in (m, n) such that
f′(z)=f′(pm)=α−c | (3.5) |
Then, a general equilibrium point is derived for Bertrand model,
pm=α+c−αβ+βc2 | (3.6) |
With gradually developing of the market, the oligarch enterprises may aggregate, the economic system will become stable. As Figure 3, the solutions of system form a lower convex surface. With the changing of parameters of α and β, the surface of solutions don't change. It is clearly that the stable situation of pm is a complicated surface. The convexity is called attractor. The points are defined as the general equilibrium points. It will not become unstable with the increasing number of firms.
From (2) and (7), a general equilibrium production can be derived,
qm=α−c+αβ−βc2β | (3.7) |
From (3), (7) and (8), the profit of equilibrium is calculated,
πm=(α−c)2−(αβ−βc)24β | (3.8) |
If there exists only a firm in one market, a monopoly market emerges, the price and production can be derived,
p=α+c2 | (3.9) |
q=α−c2β | (3.10) |
πmonopoly is defined as the profit of monopoly,
πmonopoly=(α−c)24β | (3.11) |
From above the value of (10)>(7), the value of (12)>(9). It is clear that the equilibrium situation of the Bertrand can bring about lower price than monopoly. For profit, monopoly structure can generate more profit than any other market structure. The scenario is consistent with reality.
In one market, many of the similar or homogenous firms try their best to achieve profit, market share and so on. They are aggregated by a market attractive force in one market. On the influence of attraction, the firms can produce more goods. The price of goods fluctuates with the equilibrium price in the market. Many years later, quantity supplied is roughly equal to quantity demanded, the market will gradually become stable. We take the phenomenon of stable market as the motion of the celestial body. Such as the earth, moon and sun, they keep balance with attractive force. Being similar to the celestial bodies, a market remains stable with market attractiveness.
Assumption 2. In a dynamic economics system, there exist two market, K1 and K2. K1 is treated as the monopoly market. K2 is taken as the perfectly competitive market. Imperfect competition locates between K1 and K2.
As from Figure 4, based on Lagrangian points and market attractiveness, there exist five general equilibrium points, L1, L2, L3, L4 and L5 respectively. K1, K2, L1, L2 and L3 lie on the same line. The points of L4 and L5 lie in the third corners of the two equilateral triangles and stable. L1, L2 and L3 are unstable points.
Find the solution of L1 in the Eq (13)
K1(R−r1)2=K2r12+K1R2−r1(K1+K2)R3 | (4.1) |
The relationship between L1, K1 and K2 defined r1. R is indicated as structure coefficient between K1 and K2. r1 can be derived from the formula (13),
r1≈R3√K23K1 |
Find the solution of L2 in the Eq (14):
K1(R+r2)2+K2r22=K1R2+r2(K1+K2)R3 | (4.2) |
The relationship between L2, K1 and K2 defined r2.
r2≈R3√K23K1 |
Find the solution of L3 in the Eq (15):
K1(R−r3)2+K2(2R−r3)2=(K1+2K2K1+K2R−r3)(K1+K2)R3 | (4.3) |
The relationship between L3, K1 and K2 defined r3.
r3≈R7K212K1 |
The solutions of L4 and L5 are symmetric. It is easy to derive respectively.
Assumption 3. Making K1 = p = α+c2, and K2 = p = c.
The general equilibrium points of Bertrand model can be derived.
L1=(R⋅(1−3√23(α+c)),0) |
L2=(R⋅(1+3√23(α+c)),0) |
L3=(−R⋅(1+5c6(α+c)),0) | (4.4) |
L4=(R2⋅(α−cα+3c),√32R) |
L5=(R2⋅(α−cα+3c),−√32R) |
Obviously, the value of E3 belongs to L4. the value of E1 belongs to L1 or L2. It shows that the general equilibrium points for n (n⩾3) competitors of the Bertrand model were detected with celestial bodies motion.
In this paper, the competitive equilibrium of the Bertrand game is discussed with bounded rationality and the utility function. The chaotic region of the Bertrand model is illustrated. A market structure model of space gathering is established. Further analyzing uniform linear demand of the Bertrand model, we calculate the price of monopoly and that of perfect competition respectively. The general equilibrium points are derived by the mean value theorem. At the same time, the number and stability of equilibrium points are discussed on the basis of the celestial motion theory. The results show that only five general equilibrium points exist in the Bertrand model, three of them are unstable, others are stable. The research generalized the result of the equilibrium points of dynamics system of Bertrand model. Numerical computation and simulation are given to support the consequences.
In addition, the exploration provides additional information of competitive equilibrium for Bertrand (price) competition. When one firm will enter into a relative market, according to the industry marginal cost and demand function, at least a general equilibrium price can be calculated, as the firm may obtain competitive advantage.
The authors are grateful for the editor and the anonymous reviewers considering our manuscript. This work is supported in part by Program for Applied Economics Foundation of Yuncheng University (Grant number XK-2020015) and Program for Doctor scientific research of Yuncheng University (Grant number YQ-2021016).
The authors declare that there is no conflicts of interest in this paper.
[1] | J. Bertrand, Thˊeorie mathˊematique de la richesse sociale, Journal des Savants., 67 (1883), 499-508. |
[2] | A. Cournot, Recherches sur les Principes Mathˊematique de la Thˊeorie des Richesses. Hachette, Paris, 1838. English translation by N.T. Bacon, published in Economic Classics, Macmillan, 1897. |
[3] |
KG. Dastidar, On the existence of pure strategy Bertrand equilibrium, Econ. THeor., 5 (1995), 19-32. doi: 10.1007/BF01213642
![]() |
[4] |
KG. Dastidar, Bertrand equilibrium with subadditive costs, Econ. Lett., 112 (2011), 202-204. doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.04.014
![]() |
[5] |
SH. Hoernig, Mixed Bertrand equilibria under decreasing returns to scale an embarrassment of riches, Econ. Lett., 74 (2002), 359-362. doi: 10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00564-X
![]() |
[6] | Y. Sekiguchi, K. Sakahara, T. Sato, Existence of equilibria in quantum Bertrand-Edgeworth duopoly game, Quantum. Inf. Process., 11 (2010), 1371-1379. |
[7] | A. Ogawa, K. Kato, Price competition in a mixed duopoly, Econ. B., 12 (2006), 1-5. |
[8] |
J. Zhang, Q. Da, Y. Wang, The dynamics of bertrand model with bounded rationality, Chaos Soliton. Fract., 39 (2009), 2048-2055. doi: 10.1016/j.chaos.2007.06.056
![]() |
[9] | J. Bertrand, Complex dynamics of Bertrand duopoly games with bounded rationality, World. Acad. Sci., Eng. Technol., 79 (2013), 106-110. |
[10] | E. Ahmed, A. A. Elsadany, T. Puu, On Bertrand duopoly game with differentiated goods, Appl. Math. Comput., 251 (2015), 169-179. |
[11] | J. Ma, W. Di, H. Ren, Complexity dynamic character analysis of retailers based on the share of stochastic demand and service, Complexity, 2017 (2017), 1-12. |
[12] | D. Hirata, Asymmetric bertrand-edgeworth oligopoly and mergers, B E J. Theor. Econ., 9 (2008), 1-25. |
[13] |
T. M. Rofin, B. Mahanty, Impact of price adjustment speed on the stability of bertrand-nash equilibrium and profit of the retailers, Kybernetes, 47 (2018), 1494-1523. doi: 10.1108/K-08-2017-0301
![]() |
[14] | A. A. Elsadany, H. N. Agiza, E. M. Elabbasy, Complex dynamics and chaos control of heterogeneous quadropoly game, Appl. Math. Comput., 219 (2013), 11110-11118. |
[15] |
AB. Ania, Evolutionary stability and Nash equilibrium in finite populations, with an application to price competition, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 65 (2008), 472-488. doi: 10.1016/j.jebo.2005.12.002
![]() |
[16] |
K. Abbink, J. Brandts, 24. Pricing in Bertrand competition with increasing marginal costs, Game. Econ. Behav., 63 (2008), 1-31. doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2007.09.007
![]() |
[17] |
C. Alˊos-Ferrer, A. B. Ania, K. R. Schenk-Hoppe, An evolutionary model of bertrand oligopoly, Game. Econ. Behav., 33 (2000), 1-19. doi: 10.1006/game.1999.0765
![]() |
[18] |
D. Hirata, T. Matsumura, On the uniqueness of Bertrand equilibrium, Oper. Res. Lett., 38 (2010), 533-535. doi: 10.1016/j.orl.2010.08.010
![]() |
[19] | Y. Yu, W. Yu, The stability and duality of dynamic cournot and bertrand duopoly model with comprehensive preference, Appl. Math. Comput., 395 (2021), 125852. |
[20] |
Z. Sun, J. Ma, Complexity of triopoly price game in chinese cold rolled steel market, Nonlinear Dynam., 67 (2012), 2001-2008. doi: 10.1007/s11071-011-0124-1
![]() |
[21] |
H. Kebriaei, A. Rahimi-Kian, On the stability of quadratic dynamics in discrete time n-player cournot games, Automatica, 48 (2012), 1182-1189. doi: 10.1016/j.automatica.2012.03.021
![]() |
[22] |
M. Ezro, Equilibrium points of rational n-person games, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 54 (1976), 1-4. doi: 10.1016/0022-247X(76)90230-4
![]() |
[23] |
A. Barthel, E. Hoffmann, On the existence and stability of equilibria in N-firm Cournot-Bertrand oligopolies, Theory. Decis., 88 (2020), 471-491. doi: 10.1007/s11238-019-09739-y
![]() |
[24] |
J. Li, G. Kendall, On nash equilibrium and evolutionarily stable states that are not characterised by the folk theorem, Plos One, 10 (2015), e0136032. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0136032
![]() |
[25] |
JH. Hamilton, J-F. Thisse, A. Weskamp, Spatial discrimination: Bertrand vs. Cournot in a model of location choice, Reg. Sci. Urban. Econ., 19 (1989), 87-102. doi: 10.1016/0166-0462(89)90035-5
![]() |
[26] |
SM. Anderson, DJ. Neven, Cournot competition yields spatial agglomeration, Int. Econ. Rev., 32 (1991), 793-808. doi: 10.2307/2527034
![]() |
[27] |
H. Hotelling, Stability in competition, Econ. J., 39 (1929), 41-57. doi: 10.2307/2224214
![]() |
[28] | D. Pal, does Cournot competition yield spatial agglomeration? Econ. Lett., 60 (1998), 49–53. |
[29] |
T. Mayer, Spatial Cournot competition and heterogeneous production costs across locations, Reg. Sci. Urban. Econ., 30 (2000), 325-352. doi: 10.1016/S0166-0462(99)00043-5
![]() |
[30] |
C. D'Aspremont, G. F. Thisse, On hotelling's "stability in competition", Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 47 (1979), 1145-1150. doi: 10.2307/1911955
![]() |
[31] | A. Takanori, Competition between cities and their spatial structure, Discussion Paperss., 2015 (2015). |
[32] |
N. Matsushima, Cournot competition and spatial agglomeration revisited, Econ. Lett., 73 (2001), 175-177. doi: 10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00481-5
![]() |
[33] |
B. Gupta, D. Pal, J. Sarkar, Spatial Cournot competition and agglomeration in a model of location choice, Reg. Sci. Urban Econ., 27 (1997), 261-282. doi: 10.1016/S0166-0462(97)00002-1
![]() |
[34] |
J. Sarkar, B. Gupta, D. Pal, Location equilibrium for Cournot oligopoly in spatially separated markets, J. Reg. Sci., 37 (1997), 195-212. doi: 10.1111/0022-4146.00051
![]() |
[35] |
A. Takanori, Demand creation and location: a variable consumer-distribution approach in spatial competition, Ann. Reg. Sci., 51 (2013), 775-792. doi: 10.1007/s00168-013-0562-4
![]() |
[36] |
C. Benassi, Dispersion equilibria in spatial Cournot competition, Ann. Reg. Sci., 52 (2014), 611-625. doi: 10.1007/s00168-014-0603-7
![]() |
[37] | B. Gao, Y. Du, Exploring general equilibrium points for cournot model, Discrete Dyn. Nat. Soc., 67 (2018), 1-7. |
[38] |
RD. THeocharis, On the stability of the Cournot solution on the oligopoly problem, Rev. Econ. Stud., 27 (1960), 133-134. doi: 10.2307/2296135
![]() |
[39] |
P. M. Picard, T. Tabuchi, Self-organized agglomerations and transport costs, Econ. Theory, 42 (2010), 565-589. doi: 10.1007/s00199-008-0410-4
![]() |
[40] |
C. M. Yu, Price and quantity competition yield the same location equilibria in a circular market, Pap. Reg. Sci., 86 (2007), 643-655. doi: 10.1111/j.1435-5957.2007.00141.x
![]() |
[41] |
C. M. Yu, F. C. Lai, Cournot competition in spatial markets: some further results, Pap. Reg. Sci., 82 (2003), 569-580. doi: 10.1007/s10110-003-0154-2
![]() |
[42] |
O. C. Pitchik, Equilibrium in hotelling's model of spatial competition, Econometrica, 55 (1987), 911-922. doi: 10.2307/1911035
![]() |
[43] | L. Zhao, Dynamic analysis and chaos control of bertrand triopoly based on differentiated products and heterogeneous expectations, Discrete Dyn. Nat. Soc., 2020 (2020). |
1. | Huimin Li, Shuwen Xiang, Shiguo Huang, Enquan Luo, An adaptive differential evolution algorithm based on relaxation strategy to realize the Nash equilibrium of multi-oligopoly game, 2024, 47, 1607-3606, 1571, 10.2989/16073606.2024.2328354 |