The Banzhaf value with grey data is a solution concept in cooperative grey games that has been extensively studied in the context of operations research. The author aims to define the traits of the Banzhaf value in cooperative grey games, where the values of coalitions are depicted as grey numbers within intervals. The grey Banzhaf value is defined by several axioms, including the grey dummy player, grey van den Brink fairness, and grey superadditivity. By presenting these axioms, this investigation contributes novel insights to the axiomatic characterization of the grey Banzhaf value, offering a distinct perspective. Finally, the study concludes by presenting applications in cooperative grey game models, thereby enriching the understanding of this concept.
Citation: Mustafa Ekici. On an axiomatization of the grey Banzhaf value[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 30405-30418. doi: 10.3934/math.20231552
[1] | Giovanni G. Soares, Ernesto Estrada . Navigational bottlenecks in nonconservative diffusion dynamics on networks. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 24297-24325. doi: 10.3934/math.20241182 |
[2] | Mansoor G. Al-Thani, Ziyu Sheng, Yuting Cao, Yin Yang . Traffic Transformer: Transformer-based framework for temporal traffic accident prediction. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(5): 12610-12629. doi: 10.3934/math.2024617 |
[3] | Yongyan Zhao, Jian Li . Integrating artificial intelligence with network evolution theory for community behavior prediction in dynamic complex systems. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2042-2063. doi: 10.3934/math.2025096 |
[4] | Antonio Hernando, Gabriel Aguilera-Venegas, José Luis Galán-García, Sheida Nazary . An interlocking system determining the configuration of rail traffic control elements to ensure safety. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 21471-21495. doi: 10.3934/math.20241043 |
[5] | Changgui Wu, Liang Zhao . Finite-time adaptive dynamic surface control for output feedback nonlinear systems with unmodeled dynamics and quantized input delays. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 31553-31580. doi: 10.3934/math.20241518 |
[6] | Aziz Khan, Thabet Abdeljawad, Manar A. Alqudah . Neural networking study of worms in a wireless sensor model in the sense of fractal fractional. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 26406-26424. doi: 10.3934/math.20231348 |
[7] | Hashem Najafi, Abdallah Bensayah, Brahim Tellab, Sina Etemad, Sotiris K. Ntouyas, Shahram Rezapour, Jessada Tariboon . Approximate numerical algorithms and artificial neural networks for analyzing a fractal-fractional mathematical model. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28280-28307. doi: 10.3934/math.20231447 |
[8] | Mohsen Bakouri, Abdullah Alqarni, Sultan Alanazi, Ahmad Alassaf, Ibrahim AlMohimeed, Mohamed Abdelkader Aboamer, Tareq Alqahtani . Robust dynamic control algorithm for uncertain powered wheelchairs based on sliding neural network approach. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 26821-26839. doi: 10.3934/math.20231373 |
[9] | Iftikhar Ahmad, Hira Ilyas, Muhammad Asif Zahoor Raja, Tahir Nawaz Cheema, Hasnain Sajid, Kottakkaran Sooppy Nisar, Muhammad Shoaib, Mohammed S. Alqahtani, C Ahamed Saleel, Mohamed Abbas . Intelligent computing based supervised learning for solving nonlinear system of malaria endemic model. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(11): 20341-20369. doi: 10.3934/math.20221114 |
[10] | Ateq Alsaadi . Advancing water quality management: A synergistic approach using fractional differential equations and neural networks. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(3): 5332-5352. doi: 10.3934/math.2025246 |
The Banzhaf value with grey data is a solution concept in cooperative grey games that has been extensively studied in the context of operations research. The author aims to define the traits of the Banzhaf value in cooperative grey games, where the values of coalitions are depicted as grey numbers within intervals. The grey Banzhaf value is defined by several axioms, including the grey dummy player, grey van den Brink fairness, and grey superadditivity. By presenting these axioms, this investigation contributes novel insights to the axiomatic characterization of the grey Banzhaf value, offering a distinct perspective. Finally, the study concludes by presenting applications in cooperative grey game models, thereby enriching the understanding of this concept.
In 1873, Clifford-Klein space forms made their way into mathematics history with a talk given by W. K. Clifford at the British Association for the Advancement of Sciences meeting in Bradford in September 1873 and a paper he published in June of the same year. Clifford's talk was titled on a surface of zero curvature and finite extension, and this is the only information that is available in the meeting proceedings. However, we have further information about it because to F. Klein, who attended Clifford's discussion and provided various versions of it [11]. In the context of elliptic geometry—which Clifford conceived in Klein's way as the geometry of the part of projective space limited by a purely imaginary quartic—Clifford described a closed surface which is locally flat, the today so-called Clifford surface (this name was introduced by Klein [11]). This surface is constructed by using Clifford parallels; Bianchi later provided a description by moving a circle along an elliptic straight line in such a way that it is always orthogonal to the straight line. So Clifford's surface is the analogue of a cylinder; but since it closed - it is often called a torus.
Let (M,g) be a compact minimal hypersurface of the unit sphere Sn+1 with the immersion ψ:M→Sn+1. Then we have the immersion ¯ψ=ι∘ψ:M→Rn+2 in the Euclidean space Rn+2, where ı:Sn+1→Rn+2 is the inclusion map. The problem of finding sufficient conditions for the hypersurface M of the unit sphere Sn+1 to be the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n or the unit sphere Sn is one of an by the interesting questions in the differential geometry and specifically in the geometry of the hypersurfaces in a sphere. Many authors including the author of the article with others studied this problem in various ways (cf. [1,4,5,6,7,8]). For notation and background information, the interested reader is referred to [2,3].
We denote by A=AN and A¯N=−I the shape operators of the immersion ψ and ¯ψ corresponding to the unit normal vector field N∈X(Sn+1) and ¯N∈X(Rn+2), respectively, where X(Sn+1) and X(Rn+2) are the Lie algebras of smooth vector field on Sn+1 and Rn+2, respectively.
Note that we can express the immersion ¯ψ as
¯ψ=v+f¯N=u+ρN+f¯N, |
where v is the vector field tangential to Sn+1, u is the vector field tangential to M, ρ=<¯ψ,N>, f=<¯ψ,¯N> and <,> is the Euclidean metric.
In [7], we obtained the Wang-type inequality [12] for compact minimal hypersurfaces in the unit sphere S2n+1 with Sasakian structure and used those inequalities to characterize minimal Clifford hypersurfaces in the unit sphere. Indeed, we obtained two different characterisations (see [7, Theorems 1 and 2]).
In this paper, our main aim is to obtain the classification by imposing conditions over the tangent and normal components of the immersion. Precisely, we will prove that if ρ2(1−β)+φ2(α−1α)≥0 and Z(φ)={x∈M:φ(x)=0} is a discrete set where α and β are two constants satisfies (n−1)α≤Ric≤β,β≤1, then M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n (cf. Theorem 3.1). Also, in this paper, we will show that if M has constant scalar curvature S with u is a nonzero vector field and ▽ρ=λ▽f, λ∈R∗, then M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n (cf. Theorem 5.2). Also, we will study the cases:
(i) when v is a nonzero vector field normal to M or tangent to M,
(ii) if u is a nonzero conformal vector field,
(iii) the case if v is a nonzero vector field with ρ is a constant or f is a constant.
Let (M,g) be a compact minimal hypersurface of the unit sphere Sn+1, n∈Z+ with the immersion ψ:M→Sn+1 and let ¯ψ=ι∘ψ:M→Rn+2. We shall denoted by g the induced metric on the hypersurface M as well as the induced metric on Sn+1. Also, we denote by ▽, ¯N and D the Riemannian connections on M, Sn+1 and Rn+2, respectively. Let N∈X(Sn+1) and ¯N∈X(Rn+2) be the unit normal vector fields on Sn+1 and Rn+2, respectively and let AN and A¯N=−I be the shape operators of the immersions ψ and ¯ψ, respectively.
The curvature tensor field of the hypersurface M is given by the Gauss formula:
R(X,Y)Z=g(Y,Z)X−g(X,Z)Y+g(AY,Z)AX−g(AX,Z)AY, | (2.1) |
for all X,Y,Z∈X(M).
The global tensor field for orthonormal frame of vector field {e1,…,en} on Mn is defined as
Ric(X,Y)=n∑i=1{g(R(ei,X)Y,ei)}, | (2.2) |
for all X,Y∈χ(M), the above tensor is called the Ricci tensor.
From (2.1) and (2.2) we can derive the expression for Ricci tensor as follows:
Ric(X,Y)=(n−1)g(X,Y)−g(AX,AY), | (2.3) |
If we fix a distinct vector eu from {e1,…,en} on M, suppose which is u. Then, the Ricci curvature Ric is defined by
Ric=n∑p=1,p≠u{g(R(ei,eu)eu,ei)}=(n−1)‖u‖2−‖Au‖2, | (2.4) |
and the scalar curvature S of M is given by
S=n(n−1)−‖A‖2, | (2.5) |
where ‖A‖ is the length of the shape operator A.
The Ricci operator Q is the symmetric tensor field defined by
QX=n∑i=1R(X,ei)ei, | (2.6) |
where {e1,...,en} is a local orthonormal frame and it is well known that the Ricci operator Q satisfies g(QX,Y)=Ric(X,Y) for all X,Y∈X(M). Also, it is known that
∑(▽Q)(ei,ei)=12(▽S), | (2.7) |
where the covariant derivative (▽Q)(X,Y)=▽XQY−Q(▽XY) and ▽S is the gradient of the scalar curvature S.
The Codazzi equation of the hypersurface is
(▽A)(X,Y)=(▽A)(Y,X), | (2.8) |
for all X,Y∈X(M), where the covariant derivative (▽A)(X,Y)=▽XAY−A(▽XY). A smooth vector field ζ is called conformal vector field if its flow consists of conformal transformations or equivalently,
{Ł}ζg=2τg, |
where Łζg is the Lie derivative of g with respect to ζ.
For a smooth function k, we denote by ▽k the gradient of k and we define the Hessian operator Ak:X(M)→X(M) by AkX=▽X▽k. Also, we denote by △ the Laplace operator acting on C∞(M) the set of all smooth functions on M. It is well known that the sufficient and necessary condition for a connected and complete n -dimensional Riemannian manifold (M,g) to be isometric to the sphere Sn(c), is there is a non-constant smooth function k∈C∞(M) satisfying Ak=−ckI, which is called Obata's equation.
Now, we will introduce some lemmas that we will use to prove the results of this paper:
Lemma 2.1. (Bochner's Formula) [9] Let (M,g) be a compact Riemannian manifold and h∈C∞(M). Then,
∫M{Ric(▽h,▽h)+‖Ah‖2−(△h)2}=0. |
Lemma 2.2. [9] Let (M,g) be a Riemannian manifold and h∈C∞(M). Then
n∑i=1(▽Ah)(ei,ei)=Q(▽h)+▽(△h), |
where {e1,...,en} is a local orthonormal frame and (▽Ah)(X,Y)=▽XAh(Y)−Ah(▽XY),X,Y∈X(M).
Lemma 2.3. Let (M,g) be a compact minimal hypersurface of the unit sphere Sn+1, n∈Z+ with the immersion ψ:M→Sn+1 and let ¯ψ=ι∘ψ:M→Rn+2. Then
(i) ▽Xu=(1−f)X+ρAX for any X∈X(M), ▽ρ=−Au and ▽f=u.
(ii) △ρ=−ρ‖A‖2 and △f=n(1−f).
(iii) ∫{ρtrA3+(n2−1)(1−f)}=0 and ∫ρ2‖A‖2=∫‖Au‖2.
(iv) Let φ=1−f. Then ▽φ=−u, △φ=−nφ and ∫‖u‖2=n∫φ2, where v is the vector field tangential to Sn+1, u is the vector field tangential to M, ρ=<¯ψ,N>, f=<¯ψ,¯N> and <,> is the Euclidean metric on Rn+2.
Proof. (i) Note that as ¯ψ=u+ρN+f¯N, for any X∈X(M):
X=DXu+X(ρ)N+ρDXN+X(f)¯N+fDX¯N=▽Xu+g(AX,u)N−g(X,u)¯N+X(ρ)N−ρAX+X(f)¯N+fX, |
by equating tangential and normal component, we get
▽Xu=(1−f)X+ρAX, |
▽ρ=−Au, |
and
▽f=u. |
(ii) As M is a minimal hypersurface of Sn+1,
△ρ=−∑g(▽eiAu,ei)=−∑[g((1−f)ei+ρAei,Aei)+g(u,▽eiAei)]=−ρ‖A‖2, |
and
△f=∑g(▽eiu,ei)=−∑[g((1−f)ei+ρAei,ei)=n(1−f). |
(iii)
divA▽ρ=−∑[g((1−f)ei+ρAei,A2ei)+g(u,▽eiA2ei)]=−(1−f)‖A‖2−ρtrA3+12▽S=(1−f)(S−n(n−1))−ρtrA3+12divSu−n2S(1−f)=(1−n2)(1−f)S−n(n−1)(1−f)−ρtrA3+12divSu. |
So, if M is a compact, we get
∫{ρtrA3+(n2−1)(1−f)S}=0. |
Also, note that
12△ρ2=−ρ2‖A‖2+‖Au‖2. |
So, since M is a compact, we get
∫ρ2‖A‖2=∫‖Au‖2. |
(iv) Let φ=1−f. Then,
▽φ=−▽f=−u. |
Also,
△φ=−△f=−nφ |
Also, note that
12△φ2=−nφ2+‖u‖2. |
Since M is a compact, we get
∫‖u‖2=n∫φ2. |
Note that as △f=n(1−f), f is a constant if and only if f=1. In Section 3, we study the case when Z(φ)={x∈M:φ(x)=0} is a discrete set and ρ2(1−β)+φ2(α−1)≥0, where α and β are two constants satisfying (n−1)α≤Ric≤(n−1)β, β<1. In Section 4, we study the cases v is a nonzero vector field with f or ρ is a constant, the cases v is a nonzero vector field tangent or normal to the minimal hypersurface M and the case if u is a nonzero conformal vector field. In Section 5, we study the case under the restriction Au=λu, λ∈R.
Note that on using Lemma 2.3(iii), we get
0=∫{ρ2‖A‖2−‖Au‖2}. |
Combining Lemma 2.3(iv) with Eq (2.2), we conclude
0=∫{ρ2(n(n−1)−S)+Ric(u,u)−n(n−1)φ2}. |
Let α and β be two constants satisfying (they exist owing to compactness of M) (n−1)α≤Ric≤(n−1)β,β<1. Then, using above equation, we get
0≥∫{n(n−1)ρ2−n(n−1)βρ2+(n−1)α‖u‖2−n(n−1)φ2}=n(n−1)∫{ρ2(1−β)+φ2(α−1)}. |
Assume that ρ2(1−β)+φ2(α−1)≥0, which in view of the above inequality implies
ρ2=(1−α1−β)φ2. |
Assume that Z(φ) is a discrete set, then on using (ρφ)2=1−α1−β on M−Z(φ). As ρ and φ are continuous functions and Z(φ) is a discrete set we get (ρφ)2=1−α1−β on M. So ρ=κφ, κ=√1−α1−β is a constant. Thus, by Lemma 2.3(i), we have
‖A‖2ρ=nκφ, |
and hence
κφ(‖A‖2−n)=0, |
thus either κ=0 or φ(‖A‖2−n)=0. If κ=0, then α=1 and therefore M isometric to the unit sphere Sn and it will imply β=1, which is a contradiction with our assumption β≠1. So φ(‖A‖2−n)=0, but as φ≠0 on M−Z(φ) and Z(φ) is a discrete set we get ‖A‖2=n on all M, by continuity of the function ‖A‖2, and therefore M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n. Thus, we have proved the following theorem:
Theorem 3.1. Let M be a compact connected minimal hypersurface of Sn+1 and α and β be two constants such that (n−1)α≤Ric≤(n−1)β,β<1. If ρ2(1−β)+φ2(α−1)≥0 and Z(φ)={x∈M:φ(x)=0} is discrete, then M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n.
In this section, we study the cases v is a nonzero vector field that is either tangent or normal to the minimal hypersurface M. Also, we will study the cases v is a nonzero vector field with f or ρ is a constant, and the case if u is a nonzero conformal vector field.
Theorem 4.1. Let M be a complete minimal simply connected hypersurface of Sn+1.
(i) If v is a nonzero vector field tangent to M, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
(ii) If v is a nonzero vector field normal to M, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Proof. (i) As ρ=0, using Lemma 2.3(i) and (iv), we get
▽X(▽φ)=φX, |
for any X∈X(M). So AφX=−φX for any XinX(M). If φ is a constant then u=0 and v=0, which is a contradiction. So φ is nonconstant function satisfies the Obata's equation and therefore M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
(ii) Note that as u=0 and divu=n(1−f) (Lemma 3.2(ii)), we get f=1, so by Lemma 3.1(i), we have ρAX=0 for all X∈X(M), but ρ≠0 since v is nonzero vector field. So AX=0 for all X∈X(M) and therefore M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Theorem 4.2. Let M be a complete minimal simply connected hypersurface of Sn+1.
(i) If v is a nonzero vector field and ρ is a constant, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
(ii) If v is a nonzero vector field and f is a constant, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Proof. (i) If ρ≠0, then by using Lemma 2.3(ii), we get ρ‖A‖2=0 and therefore M isometric to the unit sphere Sn. If ρ=0, then by using Lemma 2.3(i) and (iv) we get ▽Xu=−φX for any X∈X(M). So AφX=−φX for any X∈X(M). If φ is a constant then u=0 and v=0, which is a contradiction. So φ is nonconstant function satisfies the Obata's equation and therefore M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
(ii) If f is a constant, then u=▽f=0, so ▽ρ=−Au=0, so ρ is a constant and hence ρ‖A‖2=0, so either ρ=0 or M isometric to the unit sphere Sn. Assume, ρ=0 then u=▽f=0 and thus v=0, which is a contradiction. So M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Theorem 4.3. Let M be a complete minimal simply connected hypersurface of Sn+1. If u is a nonzero conformal vector field, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Proof. Assume u is a conformal vector field with potential map σ then for any X,Y∈X(M):
2σg(X,Y)=g(▽Xu,Y)+g(▽Yu,X)=2(1−f)g(X,Y)+2ρg(AX,Y). |
So ρAX=(σ+f−1)X for any X∈X(M).
If ρ=0, then M isometric to the unit sphere Sn (by Theorem 4.2(i)).
If ρ≠0, then A=FI, F=κ+f−1ρ, that is M is a totally umplical hypersurface of Sn+1 but M is minimal hypersurface of Sn+1 so M isometric to the unit sphere Sn.
Theorem 5.1. Let M be a complete minimal simply connected hypersurface of Sn+1. If Au=λu, λ∈R and △ρ≠0, then
‖A‖2=λ2(n−1)‖u‖2+nφ2n(n−1)φ2−(n−1−λ2)‖u‖2. |
Proof. We know that
‖Aρ‖2=∑g(Aρei,Aρei)=λ2∑g((1−f)ei+ρAei,(1−f)ei+ρAei)=λ2[nφ2+ρ2‖A‖2]. |
Also,
‖Af‖2=∑g(Afei,Afei)=∑g((1−f)ei+ρAei,(1−f)ei+ρAei)=nφ2+ρ2‖A‖2. |
By using Lemma 2.3(iii), we get
∫ρ2‖A‖2=λ2∫‖A‖2. |
Using the Bochner's Formula (Lemma 2.1) for the smooth function ρ:
0=∫{Ric(▽ρ,▽ρ)+‖Aρ‖2−(△ρ)2}=∫{λ2(n−1−λ2)‖u‖2+λ2nφ2+λ4‖u‖2−ρ2‖A‖4}=∫{λ2(n−1)‖u‖2+λ2nφ2−ρ2‖A‖4}. |
This implies
ρ2‖A‖4=λ2[(n−1)‖u‖2+nφ2]. |
Now, using the Bochner's Formula (Lemma 2.1) for the smooth function f:
0=∫{Ric(▽f,▽f)+‖Af‖2−(△f)2}=∫{(n−1−λ2)‖u‖2+ρ2‖A‖2−n(n−1)φ2}. |
Now as △ρ≠0, ρ△ρ≠0 and hence ρ2‖A‖2≠0 and therefore
‖A‖2=λ2(n−1)‖u‖2+nφ2n(n−1)φ2−(n−1−λ2)‖u‖2. |
Theorem 5.2. Let M be a complete minimal simply connected hypersurface of Sn+1 with constant scalar curvature S. If u is a nonzero vector field, Au=λu, λ∈R∗, then M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n.
Proof. We notice that
∑(▽Aρ)(ei,ei)=−∑▽ei▽eiAu=−λ∑[−ei(f)ei+ei(ρ)Aei]=λ(1+λ2)u. |
Also for any X∈χ(M), we have
g(Q▽ρ,X)=−λRic(u,X)=−λ(n−1−λ2)g(u,X). |
Thus
Q▽ρ=−λ(n−1−λ2)u, |
and
▽(△ρ)=−▽(ρ‖A‖2)=−[ρ▽‖A‖2−λ‖A‖2u]. |
Using Lemma 2.2, we get
λ(1+λ2)u=−λ(n−1−λ2)u−ρ▽‖A‖2+λ‖A‖2u. |
But ‖A‖2 is a constant, since the scalar curvature S is a constant (see Eq (2.2)). Thus
λ(1+λ2)u=λ(1+λ2)u−λnu+λ‖A‖2u, |
and so
λ(n−‖A‖2)u=0, |
since λ≠0 and u is a nonzero vector field, ‖A‖2=n and therefore M isometric to the Clifford hypersurface Sℓ(√ℓn)×Sm(√mn), where ℓ,m∈Z+,ℓ+m=n.
Remark 5.1. Note that the structure of [10] can be viewed as an example of the current article's structure in specific cases. In other words, the structure used for the article [10] can be recovered specifically if we select l=1,m=2 and n=3. Because of this, the structure used in this article is the generalized case of [10].
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
[1] |
R. Branzei, S. Z. Alparslan Gök, O. Branzei, Cooperative games under interval uncertainty: on the convexity of the interval undominated cores, Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 19 (2011), 523–532. http://doi.org/10.1007/s10100-010-0141-z doi: 10.1007/s10100-010-0141-z
![]() |
[2] | L. Y. Yu, The grey forecast for urban domestic wastes, Environ. Pollut. Control, 5 (1986), 7–9. |
[3] | S. Liu, Y. Lin, Grey prediction, Springer, 2006. https://doi.org/10.1007/1-84628-342-6_9 |
[4] | S. F. Liu, Y. Lin, Introduction to grey systems theory, Springer, 2010. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-16158-2_1 |
[5] | Z. Li, Primary applications of grey system theory in the study of earthquake forecasting, J. Seismol., 4 (1986), 27–31. |
[6] | C. Lee, Grey system theory win application on earthquake forecasting, J. Seismol., 4 (1986), 27–31. |
[7] | M. Wang, W. Liu, Long period forecasting of first frost by grey system theory, Fuzzy Math., 2 (1985), 59–66. |
[8] | D. Julong, On Grey and fuzzy decision of lining Building of irrigation channels, Syst. Sci. Compr. Stud. Agric., 2 (1985), 26–30. |
[9] | E. Kose, I. Temiz, S. Erol, Grey system approach for economic order quantity models under uncertainty, J. Grey Syst., 1 (2011), 71–82. |
[10] | B. Li, J. Deng, The grey model of biological prevention and cure systems of aphis gossypii Glover, Explor. Nature, 3 (1984), 44–46. |
[11] | J. Deng, Grey system and agriculture, J. Shanxi Agric. Sci., 5 (1985), 34–37. |
[12] | L. Senra, Grey forecasting the freight volume for vehicle of railway, J. Xiangfan Univ., 1 (1986), 33–35. |
[13] | G. Hong, Grey classification of medical diagnosis, Explor. Nat., 4 (1986), 69–75. |
[14] | B. Cheng, The grey control on industrial process, J. Huangshi College, 1 (1986), 11–23. |
[15] | D. Zhang, Grey relational analysis of the shape function and the level of body quality for youngsters and children, Sport Science in Guizhou Province, 2 (1986), 1–5. |
[16] | X. Ma, P. Zhen, The forecasting of creep behaviour for low alloy steel, Fuzzy Math. 2 (1985), 85–88. |
[17] | X. Jiling, Analysis of potentials of the load of judicial system of China, Grey Syst., 1988,195–210. |
[18] |
E. F. H. Qasim, S. Z. A. Gök, O. Palanci, An application of cooperative grey games to post-disaster housing problem, Int. J. Supply Oper. Manage., 6 (2019), 57–66. http://doi.org/10.22034/2019.1.4 doi: 10.22034/2019.1.4
![]() |
[19] | E. F. H. Qasim, S. Z. A. Gök, O. Palanci, G. W. Weber, Airport situations and games with grey uncertainty, Int. J. Ind. Eng. Oper. Res., 1 (2019), 51–59. |
[20] |
U. A. Yılmaz, S. Z. A. Gök, M. Ekici, O. Palanci, On the grey equal surplus sharing solutions, Int. J. Supply Oper. Manage., 5 (2018), 1–10. http://doi.org/10.22034/2018.1.1 doi: 10.22034/2018.1.1
![]() |
[21] |
J. Deng, Control problems of Grey Systems, Syst. Control Lett., 5 (1982), 288–294. http://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6911(82)80025-X doi: 10.1016/S0167-6911(82)80025-X
![]() |
[22] |
W. Xie, C. Liu, W. Z. Wu, A novel fractional grey system model with non-singular exponential kernel for forecasting enrollments, Expert Syst. Appl., 219 (2023), 119652. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2023.119652 doi: 10.1016/j.eswa.2023.119652
![]() |
[23] | M. Zhang, Y. Lan, J. Chen, A comprehensive college coaches evaluation model based on AHP and grey correlation theory, 2015 IEEE Fifth International Conference on Big Data and Cloud Computing, 2015. http://doi.org/10.1109/BDCloud.2015.69 |
[24] | S. Liu, Y. Yang, J. Y. Forrest, Grey models for decision making, Springer, 2010. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-19-6160-1_10 |
[25] |
S. A. Javed, A. Gunasekaran, A. Mahmoudi, DGRA: multi-sourcing and supplier classification through dynamic grey relational analysis method, Comput. Ind. Eng., 173 (2022), 108674. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2022.108674 doi: 10.1016/j.cie.2022.108674
![]() |
[26] |
M. Ekici, O. Palanci, S. Z. A. Gök, The grey Shapley value: an axiomatization, IOP Conf. Ser., 300 (2018), 012082. http://doi.org/10.1088/1757-899X/300/1/012082 doi: 10.1088/1757-899X/300/1/012082
![]() |
[27] | O. Palanci, The new axiomatization of the grey Shapley value, J. Grey Syst., 33 (2021), 67–77. |
[28] |
O. Palanci, M. O. Olgun, S. Ergun, S. Z. A. Gök, G. W. Weber, Cooperative grey games: grey solutions and an optimization algorithm, Int. J. Supply Oper. Manage., 4 (2017), 202–215. http://doi.org/10.22034/2017.3.02 doi: 10.22034/2017.3.02
![]() |
[29] |
G. Owen, Multilinear extensions and the Banzhaf value, Naval Res. Logist. Q., 22 (1975), 741–750. http://doi.org/10.1002/nav.3800220409 doi: 10.1002/nav.3800220409
![]() |
[30] | L. S. Shapley, A value for n-person games, Princeton University Press, 1953. |
[31] |
E. Lehrer, An axiomatization of the Banzhaf value, Int. J. Game Theory, 17 (1988), 89–99. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01254541 doi: 10.1007/BF01254541
![]() |
[32] |
H. Haller, Collusion properties of values, Int. J. Game Theory, 23 (1994), 261–281. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01247318 doi: 10.1007/BF01247318
![]() |
[33] |
V. Feltkamp, Alternative axiomatic characterizations of the Shapley and Banzhaf values, Int. J. Game Theory, 24 (1995), 179–186. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01240041 doi: 10.1007/BF01240041
![]() |
[34] |
A. S. Nowak, On an axiomatization of the Banzhaf value without the additivity axiom, Int. J. Game Theory, 26 (1997), 137–141. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01262517 doi: 10.1007/BF01262517
![]() |
[35] |
H. P. Young, Monotonic solutions of cooperative games, Int. J. Game Theory, 14 (1985), 65–72. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01769885 doi: 10.1007/BF01769885
![]() |
[36] |
A. Casajus, Marginality, differential marginality, and the Banzhaf value, Theory Decision, 71 (2011), 365–372. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-010-9224-5 doi: 10.1007/s11238-010-9224-5
![]() |
[37] |
R. van den Brink, An axiomatization of the Shapley value using a fairness property, Int. J. Game Theory, 30 (2002), 309–319. http://doi.org/10.1007/s001820100079 doi: 10.1007/s001820100079
![]() |
[38] |
Y. Kamijo, T. Kongo, Axiomatization of the Shapley value using the balanced cycle contributions property, Int. J. Game Theory, 39 (2010), 563–571. http://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-009-0187-0 doi: 10.1007/s00182-009-0187-0
![]() |
[39] |
S. Hart, A. Mas-Colell, Potential, value, and consistency, Econometrica, 57 (1989), 589–614. http://doi.org/10.2307/1911054 doi: 10.2307/1911054
![]() |
[40] |
Y. Chun, A new axiomatization of the Shapley value, Game. Econ. Behav., 1 (1989), 119–130. http://doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(89)90014-6 doi: 10.1016/0899-8256(89)90014-6
![]() |
[41] |
R. B. Myerson, Conference structures and fair allocation rules, Int. J. Game Theory, 9 (1980), 169–182. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01781371 doi: 10.1007/BF01781371
![]() |
[42] | S. Tijs, Introduction to game theory, Springer, 2003. |
[43] | R. E. Moore, Methods and applications of interval analysis, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, 1979. http://doi.org/10.1137/1.9781611970906 |
[44] |
O. Palanci, S. Z. A. Gök, S. Ergün, G. W. Weber, Cooperative grey games and grey Shapley value, Optimization, 64 (2015), 1657–1668. http://doi.org/10.1080/02331934.2014.956743 doi: 10.1080/02331934.2014.956743
![]() |
[45] |
A. Casajus, Differential marginality, van den Brink fairness, and the Shapley value, Theory Decision, 71 (2009), 163–174. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-009-9171-1 doi: 10.1007/s11238-009-9171-1
![]() |
[46] |
J. J. M. Derks, H. H. Haller, Null players out? Linear values for games with variable supports, Int. J. Game Theory Rev., 1 (1999), 301–314. http://doi.org/10.1142/S0219198999000220 doi: 10.1142/S0219198999000220
![]() |
[47] |
S. H. Tijs, T. Parthasarathy, J. A. M. Potters, V. R. Prasad, Permutation games: another class of totally balanced games, Oper. Res. Spektrum, 6 (1984), 119–123. http://doi.org/10.1007/BF01721088 doi: 10.1007/BF01721088
![]() |
[48] | J. C. Harsanyi, A bargaining model for cooperative n-person games, Princeton University Press, 1959. http://doi.org/10.1515/9781400882168-019 |