Research article

Maximizing the goal-reaching probability before drawdown with borrowing constraint

  • Received: 22 January 2021 Accepted: 08 May 2021 Published: 11 June 2021
  • MSC : 49L20, 91G10, 93E20

  • We study the optimal investment problem in a constrained financial market,where the proportion of borrowed amount to the current wealth level is no more than a given constant. The objective is to maximize the goal-reaching probability before drawdown,namely,the probability that the value of the wealth process reaches the safe level before hitting a lower dynamic barrier. The financial market consists of a risk-free asset and multiple risky assets. By the construction of auxiliary market and convex analysis,we relax the borrowing constraint and investigate the new optimization problem in an auxiliary market,where there is no such borrowing constraint. Then,we find the relationship between the optimal results in auxiliary market and those in constrained market. The explicit expressions for the optimal investment strategy and the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown are derived in closed-form. Finally,we provide some numerical examples to show the effect of model parameters on the behaviors of investor.

    Citation: Yu Yuan, Qicai Li. Maximizing the goal-reaching probability before drawdown with borrowing constraint[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(8): 8868-8882. doi: 10.3934/math.2021514

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xian Wen, Haifeng Huo, Jinhua Cui . The optimal probability of the risk for finite horizon partially observable Markov decision processes. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28435-28449. doi: 10.3934/math.20231455
    [2] Wuyuan Jiang, Zechao Miao, Jun Liu . Optimal investment and reinsurance for the insurer and reinsurer with the joint exponential utility. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(12): 35181-35217. doi: 10.3934/math.20241672
    [3] Lu Zhi, Jinxia Wu . Adaptive constraint control for nonlinear multi-agent systems with undirected graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(11): 12051-12064. doi: 10.3934/math.2021698
    [4] Liandi Fang, Li Ma, Shihong Ding . Finite-time fuzzy output-feedback control for $ p $-norm stochastic nonlinear systems with output constraints. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(3): 2244-2267. doi: 10.3934/math.2021136
    [5] Min Wang, Jiao Teng, Lei Wang, Junmei Wu . Application of ADMM to robust model predictive control problems for the turbofan aero-engine with external disturbances. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(6): 10759-10777. doi: 10.3934/math.2022601
    [6] Yinghui Dong, Chengjin Tang, Chunrong Hua . Optimal investment of DC pension plan under a joint VaR-ES constraint. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 2084-2104. doi: 10.3934/math.2024104
    [7] Jamilu Adamu, Kanikar Muangchoo, Abbas Ja'afaru Badakaya, Jewaidu Rilwan . On pursuit-evasion differential game problem in a Hilbert space. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(6): 7467-7479. doi: 10.3934/math.2020478
    [8] Regina S. Burachik, Bethany I. Caldwell, C. Yalçın Kaya . Douglas–Rachford algorithm for control- and state-constrained optimal control problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 13874-13893. doi: 10.3934/math.2024675
    [9] T. K. Buvaneshwari, D. Anuradha . Solving bi-objective bi-item solid transportation problem with fuzzy stochastic constraints involving normal distribution. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(9): 21700-21731. doi: 10.3934/math.20231107
    [10] Chengjin Tang, Jiahao Guo, Yinghui Dong . Optimal investment based on performance measure with a stochastic benchmark. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2750-2770. doi: 10.3934/math.2025129
  • We study the optimal investment problem in a constrained financial market,where the proportion of borrowed amount to the current wealth level is no more than a given constant. The objective is to maximize the goal-reaching probability before drawdown,namely,the probability that the value of the wealth process reaches the safe level before hitting a lower dynamic barrier. The financial market consists of a risk-free asset and multiple risky assets. By the construction of auxiliary market and convex analysis,we relax the borrowing constraint and investigate the new optimization problem in an auxiliary market,where there is no such borrowing constraint. Then,we find the relationship between the optimal results in auxiliary market and those in constrained market. The explicit expressions for the optimal investment strategy and the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown are derived in closed-form. Finally,we provide some numerical examples to show the effect of model parameters on the behaviors of investor.



    The theory of optimal investment can date back to the seminal works of Merton [14]. From then on, the optimal investment problems have been paid great attention by the scholars all over the world and the stochastic control theory has been widely used in the literature of investment. The popular criteria include minimizing the probability of ruin, maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth, mean-variance criterion, etc. See, for example, Browne [5], Hipp & Plum [8], Promislow & Young [15], B¨auerle [4], Zhang et al. [22], Yuan et al. [20], Sun et al. [17].

    In the recent years, drawdown, which describes the event that the value of wealth drops to its historic higher-water mark becomes a frequently quoted risk metric. The occurrence of drawdown will result in larger portfolio losses, or even a long-term recession. Hence, the fund managers tend to make the investment decisions with low drawdown risks. Research on drawdown model is increasing rapidly in the past few years. See for example, Angoshtari et al. [2] and Chen et al. [7] both derived the minimum drawdown probability in a lifetime investment problem. Angoshtari et al. [1] and Han & Liang [11] considered an optimal investment problem in an infinite-time horizon. Under the thinning dependence/common shock structure, Han et al. [9, 10] studied the optimal reinsurance problem, which minimized the probability of drawdown with dependent risks.

    Most of the existing literature about drawdown solved the problems without borrowing constraint. However, the borrowing constraints do exist and the investor is not allowed to freely borrow money without any limitations. A few scholars have advocated and investigated the optimal investment problems under different borrowing constraints. For example, Bayraktar & Young [3] considered the problem of minimizing the probability of lifetime ruin, in which the individual continuously consumed either a constant dollar amount or a constant proportion of the wealth under the higher borrowing rate. Luo [13] derived the minimum ruin probability for an insurance company with proportional reinsurance and investment under the limited leverage rate constraint. Both of those results were obtained for only one risky asset in the financial market. For the multiple risky assets, Karatzas & Shreve [12] considered the optimal investment under the utility maximization framework. Yener [18] computed the optimal investment strategy with borrowing and short selling constraints, which minimized the probability of lifetime ruin. For more research on borrowing constraints, we refer readers to Yener [19], Yuan et al. [21], etc.

    Inspired by the above-mentioned work, we focus on an optimal investment problem with borrowing constraint, where the proportion of the borrowed amount to the current wealth level is no more than a given constant. The investor aims to maximize the goal-reaching probability before drawdown, i.e., the probability that value of the wealth process reaches safe level before some fixed proportion of its maximum value to date. To make the optimization problem tractable, we introduce an auxiliary market and allow the trading to be done as if there is no borrowing constraint in it. After finding the relationship between the constrained and auxiliary markets, we derive the optimal investment strategy under borrowing constraint by dynamic programming and convex analysis. We observe that the optimal investment strategy of maximizing goal-reaching probability before drawdown will also maximize goal-reaching probability before ruin. This phenomenon reveals that the drawdown levle only affects the evaluation of value function while it exerts no impact on the investor's optimal strategy.

    As far as we concerned, only Yuan et al. [21] investigated the minimum drawdown probability with borrowing constraints for one risky asset. The current paper extends the model of Yuan et al. [21] and includes it as a special case. The main contribution of this paper is threefold: (i) compared with the early work of [21], we further consider the case of multiple risky assets, where the method of truncation in [21] does not apply anymore. Therefore, following the analysis of Karatzas & Shreve [12] and Haluk Yener [18], an auxiliary market is introduced to tackle the constrained problem; (ii) the ruin level set in our paper is no longer fixed, which is totally different from Yener [18, 19]. A more general criterion, that is, maximizing the goal-reaching probability before drawdown is investigated in our paper, which covers the minimizing the probability of ruin/drawdown as a special case. (iii) the effect of model parameters on the optimal investment strategy and borrowing constraint point is investigated in our paper.

    The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the constrained market and the auxiliary market are presented. By the stochastic control theory, explicit expressions for the optimal strategy and corresponding maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown are obtained in Sections 3. In section 4, we introduce some numerical examples to show the impact of model parameters. Finally, we conclude the paper in Section 5.

    Let (Ω,F,P) be a complete probability space, with filtration F={Ft}t0 satisfying the usual conditions, where P is the real world probability measure and Ft stands for the information available until time t. Assume that all Brownian motions introduced below are well-defined and adapted processes defined on the complete probability space.

    The investor is allowed to invest in multiple risk assets (stocks), which evolve as

    dSi(t)=Si(t)[μidt+Nj=1σijdBj(t)],fori=1,2,,N,

    where μi and σij (i,j=1,2,,N) are all given constants; B(t)=(B1(t),,BN(t)) is a standard N-dimensional Brownian motion. Meanwhile, the investor can invest a non-negative amount in a risk-free asset that earns interest at the constant rate r. Hence, the market price of risk is defined by

    ζ=σ1(μr1N),

    where 1N=(1,,1), μ=(μ1,,μN), σ=(σ1,,σN) and σi=(σi,1,,σiN) for i=1,,N.

    In our model, we denote the fractions of the wealth invested in the risky assets by π(t)=(π1(t),, πN(t)) and the fraction (1π(t)1N) is then invested in the risk-free asset. We can see that π(t)1N<1 means that saving is existent; if π(t)1N>1, it means that the investor has to borrow money with risk-free rate r from the monetary market and invest all the wealth in the risky assets. However, borrowing amount is not limitless. Therefore, we suppose that the proportion of the borrowed amount to the current wealth level is no more than a given constant k (k0) in this paper. Besides, the investor's consumption process is assumed as C(Xπ(t))=aXπ(t)+b, where a (0a<r) and b (b>0) are two given constants. With the admissible strategy π(t) and consumption process, the wealth process satisfies the stochastic differential equation:

    dXπ(t)=[(ra)Xπ(t)+π(t)(μr1N)Xπ(t)b]dt+π(t)σXπ(t)dB(t), (2.1)

    where Xπ(0)=x. Before introducing the optimization objective, we state formally the definition of admissible strategies.

    Definition 2.1 (Admissible strategy in constrained market). A control π(t) is said to be admissible if it satisfies the following conditions:

    (i) π(t)1N1+k for all t>0;

    (ii) π(t) is Ft-progressively measurable and E(0π(t)2dt)< where π(t)=niπ2i(t);

    (iii) associated with π(t), the state equation (2.1) has a unique strong solution.

    Let Ac be the set of all admissible strategies in the constrained market. Define the maximum wealth value M(t) at time t by

    M(t)=max{sup0stXπ(s),M(0)},

    where M(0)=m>0. Note that we set x>m to allow the wealth process to have a financial past. Drawdown is the first time when the wealth process reaches α[0,1) times its maximum value. The hitting time τα is defined by τα=inf{t0|Xπ(t)αM(t)}. If α=0, the drawdown level is the same as the ruin level 0.

    Besides, if the value of wealth is large enough, say, at least x=b/(ra), then the investor can invest all the wealth in the risk-free asset and the wealth process becomes non-decreasing. As a result, drawdown will never happen in this case. For this reason, we call x safe level as given in Angoshtari et al. [1] and Han et al. [11]. The first hitting time to x is defined as τx=inf{t0|Xπ(t)x}. We set τα= (τx=) if the wealth process (2.1) never hits the level αM(t) (x).

    Now assume that the investor is interested in maximizing the probability of reaching the safe level x before drawdown (hitting αM(t)). We denote the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown by V(x,m), which depends on the initial wealth x and maximum (past) value m. Specifically, V is the maximum probability of τπx<τπα, thus, we derive the performance function as

    Jπ(x,m)=Px,m(τx<τα)=Ex,m(1{τx<τα}).

    Here, Px,m and Ex,m denote the probability and expectation conditional on Xπ(0)=x and M(0)=m, respectively, . Then, the corresponding value function is given by

    V(x,m)=supπAcJπ(x,m).

    Note that if xαm, then V(x,m)=0, and if x>x and x>αm, then V(x,m)=1. It remains for us to determine the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown on the demain

    O={(x,m)(R+)2|αmxmin(m,x),αm<x},

    * Note that if αm=x, then technically drawdown has occurred, but the investor could keep its wealth at \alpha m = x^*, thereafter by only investing in the risk-free asset. Therefore, we avoid this ambiguous case by assuming αm<x throughout.

    that is the topic of our paper.

    When considering the constraint that the proportion of borrowed amount to the current wealth level is no more than a non-negative constant k, the financial market becomes incomplete. Along the same lines in Karatzas & Shreve [12], we introduce a vector of fictitious parameters νRN to complete the market. After the completion of the market, we can allow the trading to be done as if there is no borrowing constraint in the auxiliary market. Hence, for each νRN, we obtain an optimal investment strategy πν. Then, it will be shown that if we find the ν, which minimizes the value function of the auxiliary market over a certain region, the optimal investment strategy πν is indeed the optimal investment strategy π under the borrowing constraint.

    Since we are investigating the borrowing constraint in this paper, one can define the constraint set of the investment strategy as

    K={πRN|π1N1+k}. (2.2)

    Then, for such closed convex set K, the support function of the convex set K is denoted by

    δ(ν)=supπK(πν),νRN,

    with δ(0)=0 and the effective domain is given by ˜K={νRN|δ(ν)<}. ˜K can be seen as the barrier cone of ˜K (Rockafellar [16], page 114). We have δ(ν)+πν0, ν˜K, if and only if πK. Meanwhile, according to the definition of support function, the effective domain ˜K can be written as

    ˜K={νRN|ν1=ν2==νN0},

    and δ(ν)=(1+k)ν10 on ˜K for some ν10. The fictitious process ν is used to pull the investment strategy back into the constrained set. On the one hand, if the borrowing constraint are not violated, the support function remains 0 and has no effect on the optimal strategy. On the other hand, if the borrowing constraint is violated, it becomes positive and turns optimal unconstrained strategy into constrained strategy.

    For any ν˜K, we define the assets of the auxiliary market as

    {dSν0(t)=(r+δ(ν(t)))Sν0(t)dt,dSνi(t)=Sνi(t)[(μi+νi(t)+δ(ν(t)))dt+Nj=1σijdBj(t)],fori=1,2,,N, (2.3)

    and the market price of risk in the auxiliary market becomes

    ζν(t)=ζ+σ1ν(t). (2.4)

    The wealth process of the investor in this auxiliary market follows the dynamics

    dXπν(t)=[(r+δ(ν)a)Xπν(t)+πν(t)(μ+ν(t)r1N)Xπν(t)b]dt+πν(t)σXπν(t)dB(t), (2.5)

    where Xπν(0)=x and the definition of admissible strategy in the auxiliary market is given by

    Definition 2.2 (Admissible strategy in auxiliary market). A control πν(t) is said to be admissible if it satisfies the following conditions:

    (i) πν(t) is Ft-progressively measurable and E(0πν(t)2dt)<;

    (ii) associated with πν(t), the state equation (2.5) has a unique strong solution.

    Let Aν be the set of all admissible strategies in the auxiliary market. Meanwhile, the hitting times τνα and τνx in the auxiliary market are modified to

    τνα=inf{t0:Xπν(t)αMν(t)},τνx=inf{t0:Xπν(t)x}.

    Define the candidate value function as

    Vν(x,m)=supπνAνPx,m(τνx<τνα).

    Based on the above discussion, we have the following lemma to show the relationship between the value function V(x,m) and candidate value function Vν(x,m).

    Lemma 2.1. If ν˜K satisfies the equality δ(ν)+πν=0, we have

    V(x,m)=Vν(x,m)=infν˜KVν(x,m)=infν˜KsupπνAνPx,m(τνx<τνα).

    Proof. This proof can be outlined from the Remark 8.2 in Karatzas & Shreve [12] or the Appendix in Yener [19], hence, we omit it here.

    To solve the problem, we split the optimization problem into two different cases: mx and m<x. Recall the safe level x, when mx, the wealth level will reach x before m and Mν(t)=m holds almost surely for all t0, which leads to a fixed drawdown level αm. However, when m<x, the maximum process Mν(t) may increase above m under some case, i.e., the drawdown level we set is not necessarily a fixed one.

    Before showing the HJB equation for the characterization of the candidate value function Vν and corresponding optimal strategy, we denote

    C2,1(O)={ϕ(x,m)|Vν(x,) is twice continuously differentiable on   O, and  Vν(,m) is once continuously differentiable on   O}.

    It follows from the standard arguments that the C2,1(O) candidate value function Vν(x,m) satisfies the following HJB equation:

    infν˜KsupπνAνLπVν(x,m)=0, (3.1)

    where

    LπVν(x,m)=[(r+δ(ν)a)x+πν(μ+νr1N)xb]Vνx(x,m)+12σπν2x2Vνxx(x,m). (3.2)

    The notations Vνx(x,m) and Vνxx(x,m) stand for the partial derivatives with respect to the first variable. Now we are going to give the verification theorem that a classical solution to the HJB equation, subject to the boundary conditions, is the value function.

    Applying the methods of Chen et al. [7], Angoshtari et al. [1], and Han et al. [11], we can obtain the following verification theorem directly, thus we omit the proof here.

    Theorem 3.1 (Verification Theorem). Suppose that Vν(x,m):O[0,1] is a bounded, continuous function, which satisfies the following conditions:

    (i)Vν(x,m)C2,1(O) is an increasing and concave function with respect to x;

    (ii)Vν(m,m)/m=0ifm<x;

    (iii)Vν(αm,m)=0 and Vν(x,m)=1;

    (iv) Vν(x,m) is the solution of the HJB Eq (3.1) for some (ν,πν)˜K×Ac.\

    Then, we have Vν(x,m)=V(x,m) on O, and πν is the optimal investment strategy under the borrowing constraint.

    According to Theorem 3.1, we now proceed to focus on the following boundary-value problem and try to find a solution of the Eq (3.1):

    {infν˜KsupπνAν{[(r+δ(ν)a)x+πν(μ+νr1N)xb]Vνx+12σπν2x2Vνxx}=0,Vν(αm,m)=0,Vν(x,m)=1, (3.3)

    for αmxxm.

    Assume that Vν(x,m)C2,1(O), Vνx(x,m)>0 and Vνxx(x,m)<0. From the first-order condition, we obtain the maximizer πν(x) as

    πν(x)=(σ)1ζν(x)VνxxVνxx, (3.4)

    where ζν(x) is given by (2.4). Inserting (3.4) into (3.3) yields

    infν˜K{[(r+δ(ν)a)xb]Vνx12ζ+σ1ν2(Vνx)2Vνxx}=0.

    Again, in view of the first-order condition, the minimum point of the fictitious parameter is ν=ν11N and ν1 is given by

    ν1={0,ifx>D1+kVνxVνxx,1K((1+k)xVνxxVνx+D),ifxD1+kVνxVνxx, (3.5)

    where K=1N(σσ)11N and D=ζσ11N. Given the maximum fictitious process ν, the optimal investment strategy πν(x) can be rewritten as

    πν={(σσ)1(μr1N)V0xxV0xx,ifx>D1+kVνxVνxx,(σσ)1(μr1Nν)VνxxVνxx,ifxD1+kVνxVνxx. (3.6)

    One can easily verify the optimality of (ν,πν). Due to the different expressions for the optimal investment strategy in different regions, we need to discuss the following two cases.

    Case 1: x>D1+kVνxVνxx. We can see that 1Nπν<1+k, that is, the borrowing constraint is not violated. Substituting πν=(σσ)1(μr1N)VνxxVνxx and ν=0 into the HJB Eq (3.3), then we have

    ξ0(x)=V0xV0xx=2[(ra)xb]ζ2, (3.7)

    and 1Nπ0(x)<1+k yields x0<x<x, where x0 is given by

    x0=2Db(1+k)ζ2+2D(ra)<x. (3.8)

    Case 2: xD1+kVνxVνxx. We can see that 1Nπν=1+k. Inserting πν=1K((1+k)xVνxxVνx+D) and ν=1K((1+k)xVνxxVνx+D)1N into the HJB Eq (3.3), we obtain

    ξν(x)=VνxVνxx=[b(ra+DK)x]+θ(x)ζ2D2K, (3.9)

    where θ(x) is defined as

    θ(x)=[b+(ra+DK)x]2+(1+k)x2K(ζ2D2K),

    and 1Nπν(x)1+k holds for αmxx0.

    Remark 3.1. One can see that if the wealth level decreases upon x0, the borrowing constraint works and the investor maintains the maximum leverage ratio 1+k. Thus, we call x0 borrowing constraint level.

    In the following theorem, according to the above analysis, we summarize the optimal results for the case of mx. Then combining with the verification theorem, we can verify that the resulting function are indeed the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown on O.

    Theorem 3.2. Suppose that mx. Let ξ0(x), ξν(x), x0 be given in (3.7),(3.9) and (3.8), respectively. Then, for any x[αm,x], the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown for the wealth process (2.1) is given by

    V(x,m)={g1(x,m)g2(x,m),αmx<max(αm,x0),g2(x,m)g2(x,m),max(αm,x0)xx,

    where the functions gi(x,m) (i=1,2) are given by

    {g1(x,m)=xαmexp{2yαmξν(ω)1dω}dy,g2(x,m)=αmx0αmexp{2yαmξν(ω)1dω}dy+xαmx0exp{2(αmx0αmξν(ω)1+yαmx0ξ0(ω)1)dω}dy. (3.10)

    The optimal investment strategy is

    π(x)={(σ)1ζν(x)ξν(x)x,αmx<max(αm,x0),(σ)1ζξ0(x)x,max(αm,x0)xx, (3.11)

    where ν is given by

    ν(x)={1K((1+k)xξν(x)+D)1N,αmx<max(αm,x0),01N,max(αm,x0)xx. (3.12)

    Proof. We only give the proof under the case of max(αm,x0)m<x, the other case αmm<max(αm,x0) can be proved similarly. Integrating ξ(x), which is defined by (3.14) from αm to x yields

    Vν(x,m)=ϕ1(m)g2(x,m),

    where g2(x,m) is given by (3.10) and ϕ1(m) is an unknown function to be determined.

    Based on the boundary condition Vν(x,m)=1, we have ϕ1(m)=1/g2(x,m). One can see that the function Vν(x,m) satisfies the conditions (i), (iii) and (iv) in Theorem 3.1. While condition (ii) is moot because mx. Hence, Vν(x,m) equals the value function V(x,m), which completes the proof.

    Remark 3.2. From (3.11), we can see that the optimal investment strategy is only dependent on the value of wealth x, while it has nothing to do with the drawdown proportion α. Hence, similar to Yuan et al. [21] and Han et al. [9, 10], the optimal investment strategy for maximizing the goal-reaching probability before drawdown coincides with the one for maximizing the goal-reaching probability before ruin until drawdown happens.

    Remark 3.3. Furthermore, from the optimal investment strategy (3.11), it is shown that the borrowing constraint violates when the wealth process decreases to the drawdown level. In fact, only when the wealth condition keeps deteriorating, the investor chooses to gamble on the risky asset in order to avoid the appearance of drawdown. When the value of wealth is close to the safe level, the investor becomes cautious and invests less in the risky asset.

    In the previous subsection 3.2, we derive the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown and the corresponding optimal strategy for the case of mx. In this subsection, we will consider the problem for the case of m<x.

    Again, following from the verification theorem, we turn to the following boundary-value problem

    {infν˜KsupπνAν{[(r+δ(ν)a)x+πν(μ+νr1N)xb]Vνx+12σπν2x2Vνxx}=0,Vν(αm,m)=0,Vν(x,m)=1,Vν(m,m)/m=0, (3.13)

    for αmxm<x. We can construct the solution which is actually the value function according to Theorem 3.1.

    To simplify further analysis, we define the function ξ(x) as follows

    ξ(x)={ξν(x)1,αmx<max(αm,x0),ξ0(x)1,max(αm,x0)xm<x, (3.14)

    with ξν(x) and ξ0(x) given by (3.9) and (3.7), respectively. From (3.3) and (3.13), it is obvious that the only difference is the boundary condition. As a result, the HJB equation (3.13) is equivalent to

    {VνxxVνx=ξ(x),Vν(αm,m)=0,Vν(x,m)=1,Vν(m,m)/m=0,

    Based on the above results, we can conclude the optimal results for the case of m<x in the following theorem.

    Theorem 3.3. Suppose that m<x. Let gi(x,m) be given in (3.10), ξ0(x), ξν(x), x0 be given in (3.7), (3.9) and (3.8), respectively. Then,

    (i) if max(αm,x0)m<x, for any x[αm,x], the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown for the wealth process (2.1) is given by

    V(x,m)={exp{xmf2(y)dy}g1(x,m)g2(x,x),αmx<max(αm,x0),exp{xmf2(y)dy}g2(x,m)g2(x,x),max(αm,x0)x<x,

    where

    f2(y)={α[1g2(y,y)2ξν(αy)1],x0αm,α[1g2(y,y)2ξ0(αy)1],αm<x0;

    (ii) if αmm<max(αm,x0), for any x[αm,x], the maximum goal-reaching probability before drawdown for the wealth process (2.1) is given by

    V(x,m)=exp{(x0mf1(y)xx0f2(y))dy}g1(x,m)g2(x,x),

    where

    f1(y)=α[1g1(y,y)2ξ0(αy)1].

    The optimal investment strategy π and fictitious process ν are given by (3.11) and (3.12), respectively.

    Proof. Similar to the proof of Theorem 3.2, we only give the proof under the case of max(αm,x0)m<x. Integrating ξ(x) from αm to x, we have

    Vν(x,m)=ϕ1(m)g2(x,m),

    where g2(x,m) is given by (3.10) and ϕ1(m) is a function of m to be determined.

    Differentiating Vν w.r.t m, we have

    Vνm=ϕ1(m)mg2(x,m)+ϕ1(m)g2(x,m)m=ϕ1(m)mg2(x,m)+ϕ1(m)(2αξ(αm)1g2(x,m)α).

    According to the boundary condition Vν/m=0, it follows that

    ϕ1(m)/mϕ1(m)=α(2ξ(αm)1+1g2(m,m)).

    We integrate both sides of this equation from m to x, which yields

    ϕ1(m)=ϕ1(x)exp{xmf2(y)dy}.

    Following the condition Vν(x,x)=1, we get ϕ1(x)=g2(x,x)1. One can easily verify that the function Vν satisfies the conditions of Theorem 3.1, which completes the proof.

    Remark 3.4. Comparing the expressions for optimal results under the cases of mx and m<x, it is plain to find that the optimal investment strategy remains the same, but the value functions make a difference due to the extra boundary condition.

    Remark 3.5. Furthermore, if we set N=1, that is, there is only one risky asset in the financial market, the optimal investment strategy can reduce to the one in Yuan et al. [21]. Meanwhile, the value function for minimum probability of drawdown ˉV(x,m) has a representation as

    ˉV(x,m)=1V(x,m),

    which can be seen from

    ˉV(x,m)=supν˜KinfπνAνPx,m(τνα<τνx)=supν˜KinfπνAν[1Px,m(τνx<τνα)]=1V(x,m).

    In this section, we investigate the effect of model parameters on the optimal investment strategy. To make the things simple, we set N=1 in this section, that is, there is one risky asset in the market. Unless otherwise stated, we set the basic parameters as α=0.2,k=0.5,r=0.05,μ=0.1,σ=0.1,a=0.01,b=0.1 and m=1.

    Figure 1 (a) shows that higher risk-free rate indicates the lower borrowing constraint level. The higher risk-free rate means lower risk premium. Thus, the investor chooses to retain the higher leverage rate in a worse condition. On the other hand, as μ increases, the amount put in the risky asset decreases, which can be seen in Figure 1 (b). This is because the higher risk premium makes the investor borrowing money at a lower wealth level.

    Figure 1.  The influence of r and μ on the optimal investment strategy.

    The Figure 2 gives that how the parameters of consumption function affect the optimal investment strategy. It can be seen that the increase in the consumption function, i.e., parameters a and b leads directly of the increase of the optimal investment strategy and borrowing constraint level, which is a natural consequence. As a fact, in order to avoiding drawdown, the higher consumption will drive the investor to invest more in the risky-asset, which makes the borrowing constraint level become higher in return.

    Figure 2.  The influence of a and b on the optimal investment strategy.

    The Figure 3 (a) illustrates that how the parameter k affects the optimal investment strategy and borrowing constraint level. With higher permissible borrowing ratio, the investor is influenced by the borrowing constraint at a lower wealth level. In Figure 3 (b), we can see that the optimal investment strategy has nothing to do with the volatility of risky asset, which is a rather surprising result. In fact, based the expression of (3.11), the optimal constrained investment strategy for only one risky asset follows that

    π(x)={1+k,αmx<max(αm,x1),2(ra)μr(xx),max(αm,x1)xx,
    Figure 3.  The influence of k and σ on the optimal investment strategy.

    where x1 is given by

    x1=x(1+k)(μr)2(ra).

    This behavior is not the first time in the optimal investment problems, which can be also found in Browne [6]. However, this does not hold when there are multiple risky assets in which to invest in (see (3.11) for details).

    In this paper, we consider the optimal investment problem with borrowing constraint under the criterion of maximizing the goal-probability before drawdown. Using the technique of stochastic control theory and convex analysis, we derive the optimal investment strategy and the corresponding value function. By analysis, we that the behavior of borrowing typically occurs with a lower wealth level and the borrowing constraint level strongly depend on the parameters of the risky asset, as well as the consumption process. For the further research, one can extend the model to the case with jump in the process of risky asset. Meanwhile, some other objective functions can be applied, such as utility maximization or mean-variance criteria. All of these problems are meaningful and challenging, and they are our future directions.

    The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for their careful reading and helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper, which led to a considerable improvement of the presentation of the work. The authors acknowledge the financial supports from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant No. 12071224].

    The authors declare that they have no competing interests.



    [1] B. Angoshtari, E. Bayraktar, V. R. Young, Optimal investment to minimize the probability of drawdown, Stochastics, 88 (2016), 946–958. doi: 10.1080/17442508.2016.1155590
    [2] B. Angoshtari, E. Bayraktar, V. R. Young, Minimizing the probability of lifetime drawdown under constant consumption, Insur. Math. Econ., 69 (2016), 210–223. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.05.007
    [3] E. Bayraktar, V. R. Young, Minimizing the probability of lifetime ruin under borrowing constraints, Insur. Math. Econ., 41 (2007), 196–221. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2006.10.015
    [4] N. B¨auerle, Benchmark and mean-variance problems for insurers, Math. Method. Ope. Res., 62 (2005), 159–165. doi: 10.1007/s00186-005-0446-1
    [5] S. Browne, Optimal investment policies for a firm with a random risk process: Exponential utility and minimizing the probaiblity of ruin, Math. Oper. Res., 22 (1995), 468–493.
    [6] S. Browne, Survival and growth with a liability: Optimal portfolios in continuous time, Math. Oper. Res., 20 (1997), 937–958.
    [7] X. Chen, D. Landriault, B. Li, D. Li, On minimizing drawdown risks of lifetime investments, Insur. Math. Econ., 65 (2015), 46–54. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.08.007
    [8] C. Hipp, M. Taksar, Optimal non-proportional reinsurance, Insur. Math. Econ., 47 (2010), 246–254. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2010.04.001
    [9] X. Han, Z. Liang, K. C. Yuen, Optimal proportional reinsurance to minimize the probability of drawdown under thinning-dependence structure, Scand. Actuar. J., 2018 (2018), 863–889. doi: 10.1080/03461238.2018.1469098
    [10] X. Han, Z. Liang, C. Zhang, Optimal proportional reinsurance with common shock dependence to minimise the probability of drawdown, Annals of Actuarial Science, 13 (2019), 268–294. doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000210
    [11] X. Han, Z. Liang, Optimla reinsurance and investment in danager and safe-region, Optima. Contr. Appl. Met., 41 (2020), 765–792. doi: 10.1002/oca.2568
    [12] I. Karatzas, S. Shreve, Method of mathematical finance, New York: Springer, 1998.
    [13] S. Luo, Ruin Minimization for Insurers with Borrowing Constrainsts, N. Am. Actuar. J., 12 (2008), 143–174. doi: 10.1080/10920277.2008.10597508
    [14] R. C. Merton, Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuoustime case, Rev. Econ. Stat., 51 (1969), 247–257. doi: 10.2307/1926560
    [15] S. D. Promislow, V. R. Young, Minimizing the probability of ruin when claims follow Brownian motion with drift, N. Am. Actuar. J., 9 (2005), 110–128. doi: 10.1080/10920277.2005.10596214
    [16] R. T. Rockafellar, Convex analysis, Princeton University Press, 1970.
    [17] H. Sun, Z. Sun, Y. Huang, Equilibrium investment and risk control for an insurer with non-Markovian regime-switching and no-shorting constraints, AIMS Mathematics, 5 (2020), 6996–7013. doi: 10.3934/math.2020449
    [18] H. Yener, Minimizing the lifetime ruin under borrowing and short-selling constraints, Scand. Actuar. J., 2014 (2014), 535–560. doi: 10.1080/03461238.2012.745448
    [19] H. Yener, Maximizing survival, growth and goal reaching under borrowing constraints, Quant. Financ., 15 (2015), 2053–2065. doi: 10.1080/14697688.2014.972435
    [20] Y. Yuan, Z. Liang, X. Han, Optimal investment and reinsurance to minimize the probability of drawdown with borrowing costs, J. Ind. Manag. Optim., 2021, Doi: 10.3934/jimo.2021003.
    [21] Y. Yuan, H. Mi, H. Chen, Mean-variance problem for an insurer with dependent risks and stochastic interest rate in a jump-diffusion market, Optimization, 2021, Doi: 10.1080/02331934.2021.1887179.
    [22] X. Zhang, H. Meng, Y. Zeng, Optimal investment and reinsurance strategies for insurers with generalized mean-variance premium principle and no-short selling, Insur. Math. Econ., 67 (2016), 125–132. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.01.001
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Yakun Liu, Jingchao Li, Jieming Zhou, Yingchun Deng, Optimal Investment and Reinsurance to Maximize the Probability of Drawup Before Drawdown, 2024, 26, 1387-5841, 10.1007/s11009-024-10096-9
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2021 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2724) PDF downloads(80) Cited by(1)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog