Coefficients |
Coefficients |
||
The objective of the current paper is to investigate the dynamics of a new bioeconomic predator prey system with only predator's harvesting and Holling type Ⅲ response function. The system is equipped with an algebraic equation because of the economic revenue. We offer a detailed mathematical analysis of the proposed model to illustrate some of the significant results. The boundedness and positivity of solutions for the model are examined. Coexistence equilibria of the bioeconomic system have been thoroughly investigated and the behaviours of the model around them are described by means of qualitative theory of dynamical systems (such as local stability and Hopf bifurcation). The obtained results provide a useful platform to understand the role of the economic revenue v. We show that a positive equilibrium point is locally asymptotically stable when the profit v is less than a certain critical value v∗1, while a loss of stability by Hopf bifurcation can occur as the profit increases. It is evident from our study that the economic revenue has the capability of making the system stable (survival of all species). Finally, some numerical simulations have been carried out to substantiate the analytical findings.
Citation: Kerioui Nadjah, Abdelouahab Mohammed Salah. Stability and Hopf bifurcation of the coexistence equilibrium for a differential-algebraic biological economic system with predator harvesting[J]. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(1): 1641-1660. doi: 10.3934/era.2020084
[1] | Kerioui Nadjah, Abdelouahab Mohammed Salah . Stability and Hopf bifurcation of the coexistence equilibrium for a differential-algebraic biological economic system with predator harvesting. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(1): 1641-1660. doi: 10.3934/era.2020084 |
[2] | Miao Peng, Rui Lin, Zhengdi Zhang, Lei Huang . The dynamics of a delayed predator-prey model with square root functional response and stage structure. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(5): 3275-3298. doi: 10.3934/era.2024150 |
[3] | San-Xing Wu, Xin-You Meng . Hopf bifurcation analysis of a multiple delays stage-structure predator-prey model with refuge and cooperation. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(2): 995-1036. doi: 10.3934/era.2025045 |
[4] | Ruizhi Yang, Dan Jin . Dynamics in a predator-prey model with memory effect in predator and fear effect in prey. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(4): 1322-1339. doi: 10.3934/era.2022069 |
[5] | Yujia Xiang, Yuqi Jiao, Xin Wang, Ruizhi Yang . Dynamics of a delayed diffusive predator-prey model with Allee effect and nonlocal competition in prey and hunting cooperation in predator. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(4): 2120-2138. doi: 10.3934/era.2023109 |
[6] | Mengxin He, Zhong Li . Dynamic behaviors of a Leslie-Gower predator-prey model with Smith growth and constant-yield harvesting. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(11): 6424-6442. doi: 10.3934/era.2024299 |
[7] | Fengrong Zhang, Ruining Chen . Spatiotemporal patterns of a delayed diffusive prey-predator model with prey-taxis. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(7): 4723-4740. doi: 10.3934/era.2024215 |
[8] | Yichao Shao, Hengguo Yu, Chenglei Jin, Jingzhe Fang, Min Zhao . Dynamics analysis of a predator-prey model with Allee effect and harvesting effort. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(10): 5682-5716. doi: 10.3934/era.2024263 |
[9] | Mengting Sui, Yanfei Du . Bifurcations, stability switches and chaos in a diffusive predator-prey model with fear response delay. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(9): 5124-5150. doi: 10.3934/era.2023262 |
[10] | Xiaowen Zhang, Wufei Huang, Jiaxin Ma, Ruizhi Yang . Hopf bifurcation analysis in a delayed diffusive predator-prey system with nonlocal competition and schooling behavior. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(7): 2510-2523. doi: 10.3934/era.2022128 |
The objective of the current paper is to investigate the dynamics of a new bioeconomic predator prey system with only predator's harvesting and Holling type Ⅲ response function. The system is equipped with an algebraic equation because of the economic revenue. We offer a detailed mathematical analysis of the proposed model to illustrate some of the significant results. The boundedness and positivity of solutions for the model are examined. Coexistence equilibria of the bioeconomic system have been thoroughly investigated and the behaviours of the model around them are described by means of qualitative theory of dynamical systems (such as local stability and Hopf bifurcation). The obtained results provide a useful platform to understand the role of the economic revenue v. We show that a positive equilibrium point is locally asymptotically stable when the profit v is less than a certain critical value v∗1, while a loss of stability by Hopf bifurcation can occur as the profit increases. It is evident from our study that the economic revenue has the capability of making the system stable (survival of all species). Finally, some numerical simulations have been carried out to substantiate the analytical findings.
Human beings face the twin problems of food scarcity and environmental destruction. There is a great interest in studying and designing bio-economic models with regard to the biodiversity for humanity's long-term gains. Researchers strive to produce certain potentially advantageous outcomes in order to ensure the sustainable growth of the ecosystem and to preserve the enduring prosperity.
More recently, the study of population dynamics with harvesting has become an interesting topic in mathematical bio-economics due to its importance related to the optimal management of renewable resources [5]. In
Net Economic Revenue (NER) = Total Revenue (TR)-Total Cost (TC). | (1) |
Many research efforts have been focused on the investigation of this sort of dynamics. In [13-16], the authors have studied the dynamical behaviour of a class of predator-prey ecosystems formulated from several differential equations and an algebraic equation. They have obtained interesting results, such as stability of interior equilibrium, Hopf bifurcation, limit cycle, singularity induced bifurcation, and its control, and so on. But in all of these studied models, only the prey population is subjected to harvesting. The interaction between predator and their prey was investigated by using different functional response such as Holling Ⅰ and Ⅱ with the assumption that there is a natural mortality of the isolated predator species. In [17], the authors have studied the dynamics of the Beddington-DeAngilis predator-prey system with predator harvesting.
As far as we are aware, the dynamical analysis of a predator-prey model where both prey and predator grow logistically with Holling Ⅲ functional response, subject to predator harvesting, has not been previously investigated. Thus, in the present research, we investigate this type of models and discuss its dynamical behaviours, such as stability and Hopf bifurcation [1,2]. Moreover, we aim to find some principles which are theoretically beneficial for the management and the control of the renewable resources.
To achieve the ahead set goals, we organized the present article as follows: we begin our study by describing the concept behind model building and specifying its biological significance. Sequentially, we establish the positivity and boundedness of solutions for the model. Next, we examine the existence of the positive equilibrium, then we provide a detailed description of the stability and the Hopf bifurcation analysis of the system. Finally, we give a numerical simulation experiments to confirm the derived theoretical results.
In this section, we aim to develop a model that combines both economic and biological aspects in resource management. The model is structured as follows: starting by the predation rate, it is known that the physiological prey absorption capabilities by a predator are limited even if a large number of prey is available. Such a response function presenting a plateau for large prey densities is called Holling Ⅱ functional response [10-12] in which the rate of capture increases with increasing prey density and approaches saturation gradually. Type Ⅲ of Holling response function is similar to Type Ⅱ except at low prey density, where the rate of prey capture accelerates. In our proposed model, we assume that there exists an upper limit for the maximum predation rate. To achieve this aim, we have considered the predation term as
limx→∞ax2d+x2=a. |
Moreover, one way to add realism to the model is to consider the effects of crowding. Space and resources are limited even if there are more density of the populations. Therefore, the growth rates of both preys and predators are supposed to be logistic. Taking into account the above hypothesis, we propose a model which consists of prey having density
{˙x=rx(1−xK)−ax2yd+x2,˙y=sy(1−yN)+bx2yd+x2. | (2) |
where
It is known that the harvest effort is an important factor to construct a useful bioeconomic mathematical model, for this reason, and taking unto-account (1), we extend the system (2) by considering the following algebraic equation which describes the economic profit
E(t)(py(t)−c)=v, | (3) |
where
Based on (2) and (3), a singular differential-algebraic model that consists of two differential equations and an algebraic equation can be established as follows:
{˙x=rx(1−xK)−ax2yd+x2,˙y=sy(1−yN)+bx2yd+x2−Ey,0=E(py−c)−v, | (4) |
which is a semiexplicit DAE of the form
{˙z=f(v,X),0=g(v,X), | (5) |
where we denote
f(v,X)=(f1(v,X)f2(v,X))=(x(r(1−xK)−axyd+x2) y(s(1−yN)+bx2d+x2−E)), |
g(v,X)=E(py−c)−v. |
For biological considerations, we are only interested in the dynamics of this model in the positive octant
x(0)=x0≥0,y(0)=y0≥0,E(0)=E0=vpy0−c,py0−c>0. | (6) |
Proposition 1. The system (4) equipped by the initial conditions (6) have a unique maximal solution
Proof. Let
{˙x=rx(1−xK)−ax2yd+x2,˙y=sy(1−yN)+bx2yd+x2−vypy−c, | (7) |
its vectorial form is
F(z)=(x(r(1−xK)−axyd+x2) y(s(1−yN)+bx2d+x2−vpy−c)). |
Clearly
Regarding the positivity of solution for the system (4), we introduce the following proposition:
Proposition 2. Any smooth solution of (4), defined on the maximal interval
Proof. From the system (7), it follows that
From the second equation of (7), we deduce that for all
py(t)−c≠0. | (8) |
Suppose that there exist
In the predator-prey ecosystem, the impulse process of the ecosystem is typically related to the accelerated development of the species population. If this trend persists for a period of time, the biomass of population will be outside of the environment carrying capacity and the predator-prey ecosystem will be out of control, which is catastrophic for the ecosystem.
Clearly, when the predator biomass
To answer the boundedness of the solution for the system (4), we impose a realistic ecological constraint in the context that the economic policy requires a minimum level
y(t)≥ymin>cp,∀t≥0. | (9) |
This constraint will affect the fishing effort
0<E(t)≤Emax=vpymin−c,∀t≥0. | (10) |
Proposition 3. All solutions of the system (4) subject to the initial conditions (6) and constraint (10) are bounded in
Proof. Suppose that
dψdt=bdxdt+adydt,=rbx(1−xK)+asy(1−yN)−aEy. |
Hence for each
dψdt+μψ=rbx(1−xK)+asy(1−yN)−aEy+μbx+μay,=(rbx−rbKx2+μbx)+(asy−asNy2−aEy+μay),=bx[(r+μ)−rKx]+ay[(s+μ−E)−sNy],≤bx[(r+μ)−rKx]+ay[(s+μ)−sNy],≤bK(r+μ)24r+aN(s+μ)24s:=η. |
By using the theory of differential inequality [3], we obtain
0≤ψ(t)≤ημ(1−e−μt)+ψ(0)e−μt≤max(ψ(0),ημ). |
Taking limit
limt→∞ψ(t)≤ημ. |
Hence all the solutions of the system (4) subject to initial conditions (6) and constraint (10) are confined in the region
H={(x,y,E)T∈R3+:0<E≤Emax, 0≤ψ=bx+ay≤ημ+ϵ,for ϵ>0}. |
Our objective in this section is to inspect the existence of the positive equilibrium points and to study their stabilities.
An equilibrium point of the system (4) is a solution of the following equations:
{f1(v,X)=0,f2(v,X)=0,g(v,X)=0. | (11) |
By the analysis of the roots for (11), it follows that
(ⅰ) If
r(1−xK)d+x2ax−N(1+bx2s(d+x2))=0, |
or equivalently the fifth degree equation
x5−Kx4+(2d+NabK/(rs)+NaK/r)x3−2dKx2+(d2+NadK/r)x−d2K=0, |
satisfying
y∗i=rKax∗i(K−x∗i)(d+(x∗i)2), i=1,2,...,5. |
(ⅱ) If
psy2−s(Np+c)y+N(cs+v)=0, |
satisfying
s(1−r(1−xK)d+x2Nax)+bx2d+x2−vp(r(1−xK)d+x2ax)−c=0, |
or equivalently
{P(x)=8∑i=0pixi=0,Q(x)=3∑i=0qixi>0, | (12) |
where
p0=d3K2pr2s,p1=−(acd2K2rs+ad2K2Nprs+2d3Kpr2s),p2=a2cdK2Ns+acd2Krs+ad2KNprs+d3pr2s+3d2K2pr2s+a2dK2Nv,p3=−(abdK2Npr+2acdK2rs+2adK2Nprs+6d2Kpr2s),p4=a2bcK2N+abdKNpr+a2cK2Ns+2acdKrs+2adKNprs+3d2pr2s+3dK2pr2s+a2K2Nv,p5=−(abK2Npr+acK2rs+aK2Nprs+6dKpr2s),p6=abKNpr+acKrs+aKNprs+3dpr2s+K2pr2s,p7=−2Kpr2s,p8=pr2s, |
and
q0=dKpr,q1=−(acK+dpr),q2=Kpr,q3=−pr. |
Since there are three sign changes in the sequence of coefficients
Let
Proposition 4. The number of the interior equilibrium of (4) is exactly
m=μ(0)−μ(ˉx1), if Q(x) has one root, | (13) |
or
m=μ(0)−μ(ˉx1)+μ(ˉx2)−μ(ˉx3), if Q(x) has three roots, | (14) |
where
Proof. The number of the interior equilibrium of (4) is equal to the number of the positive solutions of (12). Thus we have
● If
● If
m=μ(0)−μ(ˉx1)+μ(ˉx2)−μ(ˉx3), |
positive solutions satisfying
In this section we study the stability of an interior equilibrium
For the analysis of the local stability of
¯X=(x,y,¯E)T,Q=(1000100−Eeppye−c1), |
then we get
x=x,y=y,¯E=E+Eepypye−c. |
Then, the system can be expressed as follows:
{˙x=x(r(1−xK)−axyd+x2),˙y=y(s(1−yN)+bx2d+x2−¯E+Eepypye−c),0=(¯E−Eepypye−c)(py−c)−v. | (15) |
We denote also by
f(v,¯X)=(f1(v,¯X)f2(v,¯X))=(x(r(1−xK)−axyd+x2)y(s(1−yN)+bx2d+x2−¯E+Eepypye−c)), |
g(v,¯X)=(¯E−Eepypye−c)(py−c)−v,¯X=(x,y,¯E)T, |
and we can conclude that the system (15) has a positive equilibrium point
¯Xe=(xe,ye,¯Ee)T=(xe,ye,Ee+Eepypye−c)T, |
and
For the system (15), we consider the following local parametrization:
¯X=φ(v,Y)=¯Xe+U0Y+V0h(v,Y),g(v,φ(v,Y))=0. |
Here
{˙y1=f1(v,φ(v,Y)),˙y2=f2(v,φ(v,Y)). | (16) |
Consequently, the Jacobian matrix
A(v)=(Dy1f1(v,φ(v,Y))Dy2f1(v,φ(v,Y))Dy1f2(v,φ(v,Y))Dy2f2(v,φ(v,Y))),=(D¯Xf1(v,¯Xe)D¯Xf2(v,¯Xe))(D¯Xg(v,¯Xe)UT0)−1(0I2),=(Dxf1(v,¯Xe(v))Dyf1(v,¯Xe(v))Dxf2(v,¯Xe(v))Dyf2(v,¯Xe(v)),=(xe(−rK+aye(x2e−d)(x2e+d)2)−ax2ex2e+d2bdxeye(x2e+d)2ye(−sN+pEepye−c)). |
Therefore, the characteristic equation of the matrix
λ2+a1(v)λ+a2(v)=0, | (17) |
where
a1(v)=xe(rK−aye(x2e−d)(x2e+d)2)+ye(sN−pEepye−c),a2(v)=xeye(−rK+aye(x2e−d)(x2e+d)2)(−sN+pEepye−c)+2abdx3eye(x2e+d)3. |
Result 1. For the positive equilibrium point
(ⅰ) If
(ⅱ) If
(ⅲ) If
Remark 1. The positive equilibrium point
The Hopf bifurcation is a very interesting type of bifurcations of systems. It refers to the local birth or death of a periodic solution from an equilibrium point as a parameter crosses a critical value named bifurcation value.
In this fragment, we discuss the Hopf bifurcation in the system (15) from the equilibrium point
λ1,2=−12a1(v)±i√a2(v)−a21(v)4,:=α(v)±iω(v). |
Let
v∗=(pye(v∗)−c)2pye(v∗)(sNye(v∗)+xe(v∗)(rK−aye(v∗)((xe(v∗))2−d)((xe(v∗))2+d)2)), |
if
rK=aye(v∗)((xe(v∗))2−d)((xe(v∗))2+d)2, | (18) |
then
v∗=s(pye(v∗)−c)2pN. | (19) |
Moreover
α(v∗)=0,ω(v∗)=√2abdye(v∗)(xe(v∗))3((xe(v∗))2+d)3>0, |
which implies that if
σ=18[3a3x5e(d−x2e)(d+x2e)6(−ye(3d−x2e)+4d)+spω∗2N(pye−c)+3p2cEeω∗2(pye−c)3], | (20) |
which determines the direction of the Hopf bifurcation through the interior equilibrium
Theorem 5.1. For the system (4), there exist a positive constant
Case 1.: If
Case 2.: If
Proof. The proof of Theorem 5.1 is detailed in Appendix A.
Now the computer simulation modelling using MATLAB software will be carried out to illustrate the analytical results that we have established in the previous sections. The next numerical example shows the different dynamical behaviours when the economic profit increases through a certain value
r=0.728025,a=1,b=0.72,c=0.28,d=0.3,p=3,s=0.75,K=4,N=0.8. | (21) |
For the set of parameter values (21), we calculate the coefficients
Coefficients |
Coefficients |
||
The polynomial
We analyse the local stability of the two equilibria
● For the second equilibrium
● For the first equilibrium
Since
In order to determine a high precision Hopf bifurcation values
h(v)=s(pye(v)−c)2pN−v, |
then (19) can be written as
h(v)=0, | (22) |
to approximate its solution we develop a Matlab code based on the bisection method applied to the interval
We have
Remark 2. Compared with the systems proposed in [14,15,17] in which logistic growth for prey or predator species and Holing type Ⅱ or Beddington-DeAngelis functional response are considered, our model consider logistic growth for both prey and predator species and Holing type Ⅲ functional response, which make our model more realistic, moreover it focuses on economic interest of commercial harvest effort on predator. Another advantage is that the proposed model has multiple interior equilibria which gives more opportunities for fishermen in control theory to stabilize the ecosystem at the interior equilibrium point that represents its ideal performance.
This paper has deal with a differential-algebraic biological economic system.We have taken predator functional response to prey in a form that approaches to a constant even when the prey population increases. We consider the dynamical behaviour of the system when only the predator is subjected to harvesting. From the biological perspective, we are only interested on the positive equilibrium points. The number of positive equilibria is investigated by means of Descartes' rule of signs and is calculated numerically using a Matlab code which has been developed based on the Euclidean algorithm. The obtained results have shown that the proposed system has an even number of positive equilibria between 0 and 8. This gives special importance to the proposed system because the diversity of positive equilibria gives more opportunities in control theory to choose the point that represents the ideal performance of the ecosystem. The local stability of the interior equilibria is curried out by analysing their corresponding characteristic equation and the proposed numerical example has shown that the system has two interior equilibria one of them is unstable saddle point and the other one is a focus point that changes its stability property when varying the economic revenue
This research was supported by the Algerian General Directorate for Scientific Research and Technological Development (DGRSDT).
In order to explore the direction of the Hopf bifurcation in the system (15) according to [4,7] when
{˙y1=ω∗y2+12a111y21+a112y1y2+12a122y22+16a1111y31+12a1112y21y2+12a1122y1y22+16a1222y32+O(∣Y∣4),˙y2=−ω∗y1+12a211y21+a212y1y2+12a222y22+16a2111y31+12a2112y21y2+12a2122y1y22+16a2222y32+O(∣Y∣4). | (23) |
where
It can be proved that the system (16) with
{˙y1=f1y1(v∗,¯Xe)y1+f1y2(v∗,¯Xe)y2+12f1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)y21+f1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)y1y2+12f1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y22+16f1y1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)y31+12f1y1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)y21y2+12f1y1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y1y22+16f1y2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y32+O(∣Y∣4),˙y2=f2y1(v∗,¯Xe)y1+f2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y2+12f2y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)y21+f2y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)y1y2+12f2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y22+16f2y1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)y31+12f2y1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)y21y2+12f2y1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y1y22+16f2y2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)y32+O(∣Y∣4). | (24) |
In the following, we shall calculate the coefficients of the parametric system (24). We derive
D¯Xf1(v,¯X)=(r(1−xK)−axyx2+d+x(−rK+ay(x2−d)(x2+d)2),−ax2x2+d,0),D¯Xf2(v,¯X)=(2bdxy(x2+d)2,s(1−yN)+bx2x2+d+pEeypye−c−¯E+y(−sN+pEepye−c),−y),D¯Xg(v,¯X)=(0,¯Ep−2p2Eeypye−c+pEecpye−c,py−c),Dφ(v,Y)=(Dy1φ(v,Y),Dy2φ(v,Y)),=(D¯Xg(v,¯X)UT0)−1(0I2),=(100101py−c(−¯Ep+2p2Eeypye−c−pEecpye−c)). | (25) |
Therefore
f1y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)=r(1−xK)−axyx2+d+x(−rK+ay(x2−d)(x2+d)2),f1y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)=−ax2x2+d,f2y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)=2bdxy(x2+d)2, |
f2y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)=s(1−yN)+bx2x2+d+pEeypye−c−¯E+y(−sN+pEepye−c)−ypy−c(−¯Ep+2p2Eeypye−c−pEecpye−c). | (26) |
Substituting
f1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=0,f2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=0,f1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=−ax2ex2e+d,f2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=2bdxeye(x2e+d)2. | (27) |
In view of equations (26), we can deduce that
D¯Xf1y1(v,¯X)=(2(−rK+ay(x2−d)(x2+d)2)+2ayx2(3d−x2)(x2+d)3,−2axd(x2+d)2,0),D¯Xf1y2(v,¯X)=(−2axd(x2+d)2,0,0),D¯Xf2y1(v,¯X)=(2bdy(d−3x2)(x2+d)3,2bdx(x2+d)2,0),D¯Xf2y2(v,¯X)=(2bdx(x2+d)2,−2sN−¯Epc(py−c)2+pEec2(py−c)2(pye−c),pypy−c−1). | (28) |
From equations (25) and (28), we get
f1y1y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1y1(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)=2(−rK+ay(x2−d)(x2+d)2)+2ayx2(3d−x2)(x2+d)3,f1y1y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1y1(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)=−2axd(x2+d)2,f1y2y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1y2(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)=−2axd(x2+d)2,f1y2y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1y2(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)=0,f2y1y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2y1(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)=2bdy(d−3x2)(x2+d)3,f2y1y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2y1(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)=2bdx(x2+d)2,f2y2y1(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2y2(v,¯X)Dy1φ(v,Y)= 2bdx(x2+d)2,f2y2y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2y2(v,¯X)Dy2φ(v,Y)= −2sN−2pc¯E(py−c)2+2p2Eecy(py−c)2(pye−c). | (29) |
substituting
f1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=2ayex2e(3d−x2e)(x2e+d)3,f1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=−2adxe(x2e+d)2,f2y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f2y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=2bdxe(x2e+d)2, |
f2y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=2bdye(d−3x2e)(x2e+d)3,f2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=−2spyeN(pye−c),f1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=0. | (30) |
By equations (29), we get
D¯Xf1y1y1(v,¯X)=(24adyx(d−x2)(x2+d)4,2ad(3x2−d)(x2+d)3,0),D¯Xf1y1y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf1y2y1(v,¯X)=(2ad(3x2−d)(x2+d)3,0,0),D¯Xf1y2y2(v,¯X)=(0,0,0),D¯Xf2y1y1(v,¯X)=(24bdyx(x2−d)(x2+d)4,2bd(d−3x2)(x2+d)3,0),D¯Xf2y1y2(v,¯X)=D¯Xf2y2y1(v,¯X)=(2bd(d−3x2)(x2+d)3,0,0),D¯Xf2y2y2(v,¯X)=(0,4p2cE(py−c)3+2p2cEe(py−c)2(pye−c),−2pc(py−c)2). | (31) |
Substituting
D¯Xf1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=(24adyexe(d−x2e)(x2e+d)4,2ad(3x2e−d)(x2e+d)3,0),D¯Xf1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=D¯Xf1y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=(2ad(3x2e−d)(x2e+d)3,0,0),D¯Xf1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=(0,0,0),D¯Xf2y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=(24bdyexe(x2e−d)(x2e+d)4,2bd(d−3x2e)(x2e+d)3,0),D¯Xf2y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=D¯Xf2y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=(2bd(d−3x2e)(x2e+d)3,0,0),D¯Xf2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=(0,6p2cEe(pye−c)3,−2pc(pye−c)2), Dφ(v∗,0)=(Dy1φ(v∗,0), Dy2φ(v∗,0))=(100100). | (32) |
From equations (32), we have
f1y1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=24adyexe(d−x2e)(x2e+d)4,f2y1y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=24bdyexe(x2e−d)(x2e+d)4,f2y2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=6p2cEe(pye−c)3,f1y1y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y2y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=2ad(3x2e−d)(x2e+d)3, |
f2y1y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f2y1y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=f2y2y1y1(v∗,¯Xe)=2ad(d−3x2e)(x2e+d)3,f1y2y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y2y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f1y2y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=0,f2y1y2y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f2y2y1y2(v∗,¯Xe)=f2y2y2y1(v∗,¯Xe)=0. | (33) |
According to equations (24), (27), (30) and (33), the parametric system of the system (16) with
{˙y1=−ax2ed+x2ey2+ayex2e(3d−x2e)(d+x2e)3y21−2axed(d+x2e)2y1y2+4adxeye(d−x2e)(d+x2e)4y31+ad(3x2e−d)(d+x2e)3y21y2+O(∣Y∣4),˙y2=2bdxeye(d+x2e)2y1+bdye(d−3x2e)(d+x2e)3y21+2bdxe(d+x2e)2y1y2−spyeN(pye−c)y22+4bdxeye(x2e−d)(d+x2e)4y31+bd(d−3x2e)(d+x2e)3y21y2+p2cEe(pye−c)3y32+O(∣Y∣4). | (34) |
Compared with the normal form (24), we should normalize the parametric system (34) with the following nonsingular linear transformation:
(y1y2)=P(u1u2), |
where
{˙y1=ω∗y2+a2x4eye(3d−x2e)(d+x2e)4y21+2adxeω∗(d+x2e)2y1y2+4da3x5e(d−x2e)(d+x2e)6y31−a2dω∗x2e(3x2e−d)(d+x2e)4y21y2+O(∣Y∣4),˙y2=−ω∗y1−axeω∗(d−3x2e)2(d+x2e)2y21+ω∗2yey1y2+spyeω∗N(pye−c)y22−2a2x4eω∗(x2e−d)(d+x2e)4y31+axeω∗2(d−3x2e)2(d+x2e)2y21y2+p2cEeω∗2(pye−c)3y32+O(∣Y∣4). | (35) |
According to the Hopf bifurcation theory [7], the direction of the Hopf bifurcation is determined by the signal of
16σ=1ω∗{a111(a211−a112)+a222(a212−a122)+(a211a212−a112a122)} |
+(a1111+a1122+a2112+a2222),=6a3x5e(d−x2e)(d+x2e)6(−ye(3d−x2e)+4d)+2spω∗2N(pye−c)+6p2cEeω∗2(pye−c)3. | (36) |
[1] |
Hopf bifurcation and chaos in fractional-order modified hybrid optical system. Nonlinear Dynamics (2012) 69: 275-284. ![]() |
[2] |
M.-S. Abdelouahab and R. Lozi, Hopf-like bifurcation and mixed mode oscillation in a fractional-order FitzHugh-Nagumo model, AIP Conference Proceedings 2183, 100003, (2019). doi: 10.1063/1.5136214
![]() |
[3] | G. Birkhoff and G.-C. Rota, Ordinary Differential Equations, 4th edition, John Wiley and Sons, Inc., New York, 1989. |
[4] | Normal forms and bifurcations for the differential-algebraic systems. Acta Math. Appl. Sinica (2000) 23: 429-443. |
[5] | C. W. Clark, Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, 2nd edition, John Wiley and Sons, New York, 1990. |
[6] |
The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery. Journal of Political Economy (1954) 62: 124-142. ![]() |
[7] |
J. Guckenheimer and P. Holmes, Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical Systems, and Bifurcations of Vector Fields, Springer-Verlag, New York, 1983. doi: 10.1007/978-1-4612-1140-2
![]() |
[8] | J. Hale, Theory of Functional Differential Equations, 2nd edition, Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 3. Springer-Verlag, New York-Heidelberg, 1977. |
[9] | P. Henrici, Applied and Computational Complex Analysis, Vol. 1: Power Series-Integration-Conformal Mapping-Location of Zeros, Pure and Applied Mathematics. Wiley-Interscience [John Wiley & Sons], New York-London-Sydney, 1974. |
[10] |
The components of predation as revealed by a study of small mammal predation of the European pine sawfly. Canadian Entomology (1959a) 91: 293-320. ![]() |
[11] |
Some characteristics of simple types of predation and parasitism. Canadian Entomology (1959) 91: 385-398. ![]() |
[12] |
The functional response of predators to prey density and its role in mimicry and population regulation. Memoirs of the Entomological Society of Canada (1965) 97: 5-60. ![]() |
[13] | Effort dynamics in a prey-predator model with harvesting. Int. J. Inf. Syst. Sci. (2010) 6: 318-332. |
[14] |
Dynamics of a predator-prey ecological system with nonlinear harvesting rate. Wuhan Univ. J. Nat. Sci. (2015) 20: 25-33. ![]() |
[15] |
Hopf bifurcation for a predator-prey biological economic system with Holling type Ⅱ functional response. J. Franklin Inst. (2011) 348: 1114-1127. ![]() |
[16] |
Bifurcation and control in a differential-algebraic harvested prey-predator model with stage structure for predator. Internat. J. Bifur. Chaos Appl. Sci. Engrg. (2008) 18: 3159-3168. ![]() |
[17] |
W. Zhu, J. Huang and W. Liu, The stability and Hopf bifurcation of the differential-algebraic biological economic system with single harvesting, 2015 Sixth International Conference on Intelligent Control and information Processing (ICICIP), Wuhan, (2015), 92–97. doi: 10.1109/ICICIP.2015.7388150
![]() |
1. | M.-S. Abdelouahab, A. Arama, R. Lozi, Bifurcation analysis of a model of tuberculosis epidemic with treatment of wider population suggesting a possible role in the seasonality of this disease, 2021, 31, 1054-1500, 123125, 10.1063/5.0057635 | |
2. | Jiao Jiang, Xiushuai Li, Xiaotian Wu, The Dynamics of a Bioeconomic Model with Michaelis–Menten Type Prey Harvesting, 2023, 46, 0126-6705, 10.1007/s40840-022-01452-4 | |
3. | Nan Xiang, Aying Wan, Hongyan Lin, Diffusion-driven instability of both the equilibrium solution and the periodic solutions for the diffusive Sporns-Seelig model, 2022, 30, 2688-1594, 813, 10.3934/era.2022043 | |
4. | Binhao Hong, Chunrui Zhang, Bifurcations and chaotic behavior of a predator-prey model with discrete time, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 13390, 10.3934/math.2023678 | |
5. | Noufe H. Aljahdaly, Laith Abualigah, Theoretical and semi-analytical simulation for a two-predator-one-prey model during the mating period, 2023, 18, 1932-6203, e0289410, 10.1371/journal.pone.0289410 | |
6. | Shuanghong Zhang, Han Yang, Fanqi Yu, Fuzzy Optimal Guaranteed Cost Control of a Single Specie Bio-Economic Singular Systems in Algae Environment, 2024, 12, 2169-3536, 116218, 10.1109/ACCESS.2024.3445150 |
Coefficients |
Coefficients |
||