Conducting global trade in national currencies greatly increases complexity and fragility of the modern financial system and, therefore, requires creation of new, much more accurate methods of macroeconomic and monetary regulation than those available today. The current practice of macroeconomic regulation relies on the system of national accounts (SNA) based on the Leontief input-output method. Its analytical tools are explained by the possibility of calculating the volume of output of a product and its cost in natural units. Moreover, it offers no explanation to the relationship between the composition of the output and relative prices. This disadvantage significantly complicates practical application of the Leontief method, since primary accounting reports operate with cost rather than physical indicators, forcing the introduction of various kinds of simplifications into the input-output model, which significantly reduces its analytical capabilities. The article presents a physical concept of value, on the basis of which the input-output model is supplemented by the definition of the material law of relative price formation. This addition turns the input-output method from an applied analysis tool into a complete theory of production, and in the future opens up fundamentally new, previously non-existent opportunities for the empirical studies of economic development and creation of highly effective methods of macroeconomic regulation. The price formation model, methodologically explained in the article, is a synthesis of the W. Leontief's concept of economy as a circular flow and P. Sraffa's model of the price mechanism of income distribution. It is basically our own concept of economic reproduction viewed as sharing by the producers of the common material resource of the production system. We claim that our findings regarding single-product industries in W. Leontief's and P. Sraffa's models can be generalized and applied to J. von Neumann's model of the balanced economic growth in multi-product industries.
Citation: Nikolay I. Kuryshev, Vladimir R. Tsibulsky. Scarcity of resources as a determining factor of value in input-output models (objectivist concept of capital)[J]. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(3): 208-226. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023013
Conducting global trade in national currencies greatly increases complexity and fragility of the modern financial system and, therefore, requires creation of new, much more accurate methods of macroeconomic and monetary regulation than those available today. The current practice of macroeconomic regulation relies on the system of national accounts (SNA) based on the Leontief input-output method. Its analytical tools are explained by the possibility of calculating the volume of output of a product and its cost in natural units. Moreover, it offers no explanation to the relationship between the composition of the output and relative prices. This disadvantage significantly complicates practical application of the Leontief method, since primary accounting reports operate with cost rather than physical indicators, forcing the introduction of various kinds of simplifications into the input-output model, which significantly reduces its analytical capabilities. The article presents a physical concept of value, on the basis of which the input-output model is supplemented by the definition of the material law of relative price formation. This addition turns the input-output method from an applied analysis tool into a complete theory of production, and in the future opens up fundamentally new, previously non-existent opportunities for the empirical studies of economic development and creation of highly effective methods of macroeconomic regulation. The price formation model, methodologically explained in the article, is a synthesis of the W. Leontief's concept of economy as a circular flow and P. Sraffa's model of the price mechanism of income distribution. It is basically our own concept of economic reproduction viewed as sharing by the producers of the common material resource of the production system. We claim that our findings regarding single-product industries in W. Leontief's and P. Sraffa's models can be generalized and applied to J. von Neumann's model of the balanced economic growth in multi-product industries.
[1] | Abalkin LI (2000) The Russian School of Economic Thought: The Search for Self-Determination. Russian Soc Sci Rev 43: 60–82. https://doi.org/10.2753/RSS1061-1428430260 doi: 10.2753/RSS1061-1428430260 |
[2] | Blaug M (1994) Economic Theory in Retrospect. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511805639 |
[3] | Champernowne DG (1945) A Note on J. v. Neumann's Article on "A Model of Economic Equilibrium". Rev Econ Stud 13: 10–18. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296112 doi: 10.2307/2296112 |
[4] | Fratini SM (2019) On the Second Stage of The Cambridge Capital Controversy. J Econ Surv 33: 1073–1093. https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12312 doi: 10.1111/joes.12312 |
[5] | Garegnani P (2010) Capital in neoclassical theory: some remarks. Financ Bus 3: 4–19. |
[6] | Garegnani P (2012) On the present state of the capital controversy. Camb J Econ 3: 1417–1432. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bes063 doi: 10.1093/cje/bes063 |
[7] | Klukin PN (2008) F. Quesnay's Creative Thought in 1736–1756 in Relation to the Metaphysics of "Obviousness" and Political Economy Tradition. Quest Econ 12: 84–98. https://doi.org/10.32609/0042-8736-2008-12-84-98 doi: 10.32609/0042-8736-2008-12-84-98 |
[8] | Klukin PN (2013) Development of the theory of economic circulation in the XX century and its modern perspectives. Bulletin of the Kiev National Taras Shevchenko University. Series: Economics 146: 42–46. |
[9] | Klukin PN (2014) The Russian tradition of economic analysis (1890–1935). |
[10] | Kurz HD, Salvadori N (2000) Classical roots of input-output analysis: a short account of its long prehistory. Econ Syst Res 12: 153–179. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535310050005671 doi: 10.1080/09535310050005671 |
[11] | Kurz HD, Salvadori N (2007) An Extended Interpretation of the Input-Output Concept: A Comparative Analysis of Early Works by W. Leontief and P. Sraffa. Bulletin of Saint Petersburg University 2: 3–21. |
[12] | Kurishev NI (2022) An extension of the model of W.W. Leontief's model by limiting the material resources of the production system (the Objectivist concept of value). Reg Econ: Theory Pract 20: 1760–1785. |
[13] | Leontief V (1928) Die Wirtschaft als Kreislauf, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik. 60: 577–623. |
[14] | Leontief V (1936) Quantitative input and output relations in the economic systems of the United States. Rev Econ Stat 18: 105–125. |
[15] | Leontief V (1941) The Structure of American Economy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. |
[16] | Leontief V (1987) Input–output analysis, In: Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., Newman, P., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan, 2: 860–864. |
[17] | Mill J (1826) Elements of Political Economy. |
[18] | Neumann J (1937) Ube rein okonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes. Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums 8: 73–83. |
[19] | Neumann J (1945) А Model of General Economic Equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 13: 1–9. |
[20] | Pantaleoni М (1894) Principii di economia pura, Firenze, G. Barbèra. |
[21] | Pospelov I (2009) Modeling the Russian economy in the conditions of crisis. Quest Econ 11: 50–75. |
[22] | Samuelson PA (1991) Leontief's the economy as a circular flow: an introduction. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 2: 177–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/0954-349X(91)90011-G doi: 10.1016/0954-349X(91)90011-G |
[23] | Sraffa P (1926) The laws of returns under competitive conditions. Econ J 36: 535–550. |
[24] | Sraffa P (1960) Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press. |