China's manufacturing industry has registered phenomenal development in the past 40 years,which has become the most remarkable aspect of China's economic miracle. In this article,we interrogate labor productivity growth mechanisms in that industry during 1998–2007. Specifically,we assess the relative importance of efficiency,technology,and capital deepening changes in the growth process. Methodologically,we employ a nonparametric tripartite decomposition while controlling for technology and ownership heterogeneity using the concept of metafrontier. We find that most of the productivity growth was driven by capital deepening (125.60%),followed by technology progress (62.47%),and a small fraction (11.23%) was due to efficiency improvement. We also demonstrate strong productivity convergence in China's manufacturing industry,which was driven by technology change and capital deepening effects. These results suggest that China's overall industry development benefited from market mechanism in resource allocation and technology diffusion,but further improvement is possible. Finally,we point out that China's industry can still benefit from capital accumulation in the near future but long-term productivity growth must be based on technology progress.
Citation: Ming He, Barnabé Walheer. Technology intensity and ownership in the Chinese manufacturing industry: A labor productivity decomposition approach[J]. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 110-137. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020007
Related Papers:
[1]
Mengxin Wang, Lang Li, Hanyong Lan .
The measurement and analysis of technological innovation diffusion in China's manufacturing industry. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(4): 452-471.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021024
[2]
Edward Y. Uechi .
Determining a proportion of labor and equipment to achieve optimal production: A model supported by evidence of 19 U.S. industries from 2000 to 2020. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(2): 266-290.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024012
[3]
Kewei Ma, Guido Ferrari, Zichuan Mi .
SAM-based analysis of China’s economic system and measurement of the effects of a VAT rate cut after the tax reform. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 26-52.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020002
[4]
Jiehua Ma, Shuanglian Chen .
Does land transfer have an impact on land use efficiency? A case study on rural China. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(2): 112-134.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022007
[5]
Pavel Ivanov, Tatyana Altufeva .
Stimulating the processes of attracting investments in industry of the constituent entities of the Russian Federation. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(3): 352-366.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024016
[6]
Guido Ferrari, Yanyun Zhao, José Mondéjar Jiménez, Luca Secondi .
The economy of Tuscany in the post Covid-19 era: struggling with energy crisis and inflation. What to do to resume the journey?1. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 1-26.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024001
[7]
Dachen Sheng, Opale Guyot .
Corporate governance in Chinese manufacturing sector: Ownership structure, monitoring and firms' earning quality. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(4): 421-443.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023024
[8]
Tinghui Li, Xue Li .
Does structural deceleration happen in China? Evidence from the effect of industrial structure on economic growth quality. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 155-173.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020009
[9]
Shengyin Ouyang, Ziqing Du, Meiling Cai .
Statistical measurement of the impact of monetary policy on price levels. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 188-203.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020011
[10]
Shuang Luo, Wenting Lei, Peng Hou .
Impact of artificial intelligence technology innovation on total factor productivity: an empirical study based on provincial panel data in China. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(2): 172-194.
doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024008
Abstract
China's manufacturing industry has registered phenomenal development in the past 40 years,which has become the most remarkable aspect of China's economic miracle. In this article,we interrogate labor productivity growth mechanisms in that industry during 1998–2007. Specifically,we assess the relative importance of efficiency,technology,and capital deepening changes in the growth process. Methodologically,we employ a nonparametric tripartite decomposition while controlling for technology and ownership heterogeneity using the concept of metafrontier. We find that most of the productivity growth was driven by capital deepening (125.60%),followed by technology progress (62.47%),and a small fraction (11.23%) was due to efficiency improvement. We also demonstrate strong productivity convergence in China's manufacturing industry,which was driven by technology change and capital deepening effects. These results suggest that China's overall industry development benefited from market mechanism in resource allocation and technology diffusion,but further improvement is possible. Finally,we point out that China's industry can still benefit from capital accumulation in the near future but long-term productivity growth must be based on technology progress.
1.
Introduction
China has achieved phenomenal growth in its industrial sector since the 1980s. From 1980 to 2017, total industrial value added increased from 603.9 billion to 26.7 trillion RMB, or 43.2 times.1 Nowadays, the country accounts for 20.9% of the world's industrial value added, and is the top producer of 220 industrial products.2 The strong industry explains why China is often called the factory of the world.
1 Source: National Bureau of Statistics. Industrial value added is in 2015 constant price.
Against the backdrop of China's great leap in industrial development was vibrant productivity growth. From 1980 to 2017, the labor productivity in China's industry increased 22 times and reached $21, 567 per worker, which was far higher than that of middle-income countries ($16, 905 per worker) but slightly lower than that of upper-middle-income countries ($23, 427 per worker).3 Although a huge productivity gap still exists between China and developed economies, data show that China is catching up rapidly.4 Clearly, labor productivity growth is the key to understanding China's industrial development.
3 Source: National Bureau of Statistics and World Bank Open Data.
4 Over the 1997–2017 period, the growth rate of labor productivity was 8.1% per annum in China, compared with 1.9% in the European Union, 2.2% in Japan, and 1.7% in the United States. Data source: World Bank Open Data and author's own calculations.
In this article, we interrogate the mechanism of labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry. We address two research questions. First, what are the driving forces of labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry? Second, does China's manufacturing industry exhibit productivity convergence that is suggested by the neoclassical growth theory and empirical evidence (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1991; Baumol, 1986)? Unfortunately, answers provided by the extant literature are usually mixed, and sometimes contradictory. Growth decomposition has been widely applied to investigate China's regional economic growth, but not its industry (Badunenko and Tochkov, 2010; Henderson et al., 2007; Unel and Zebregs, 2009).5 These studies usually identify resource accumulation as the predominant source of labor productivity growth. They also report divergence among Chinese regions. Regressional analyses using industry data often show a greater role of total factor productivity (TFP) than factor accumulation in explaining industrial output growth (Brandt et al., 2012; Chen et al., 2011). These studies also show convergence of TFP among ownership types or across regions (Berkowitz et al., 2017; Deng and Jefferson, 2011; Jefferson et al., 2008; Lemoine et al., 2015). By applying the growth decomposition method to analyzing China's manufacturing industry, we fill the gap in the literature and we are able to synthesize the seemingly conflicting results from a new perspective.
5Walheer (2019b) is an exception, but this study is restricted to a limited number of industrial parks.
Methodologically, we follow Kumar and Russell (2002) and decompose labor productivity growth into efficiency change, technology change, and input change (capital deepening) effects. We employ data envelopment analysis (DEA) to estimate the potential outputs of a given technology. DEA, first presented by Charnes et al. (1978) and Banker et al. (1984), is an attractive modeling technique because, contrary to parametric methods, it does not assume a priori any functional form for the technology. These assumptions are usually restrictive and not always innocuous.6 As another desirable feature, DEA enables us to easily decompose TFP growth into efficiency change and technology change (Bos et al., 2010a). Such a treatment is critical for the various growth decompositions seen in the literature, including Färe et al.(1994), Kumar and Russell (2002), Henderson and Russell (2005), Badunenko and Romero-Ávila (2013), Walheer (2018c), and Walheer (2019b).
6 See, for example, discussions in Hsieh and Klenow (2009) about the impact of the Cobb-Douglas assumption on their results.
As the second contribution of our study, we incorporate two levels of technology heterogeneity into the DEA model: one between technology groups and another between ownership types. This is done by employing the concept of metafrontier developed by Battese and Rao (2002).7 Our treatment is similar to those of He and Walheer (2019) and Walheer and He (2018). In growth decomposition, the introduction of the metafrontier implies a further decomposition of each component into a group effect and heterogeneity component(s). The application of metafrontier techniques in growth decomposition has received increasing attention in recent years. Examples include Fei and Lin (2016), Filippetti and Peyrache (2015), Molinos-Senante et al. (2017), Walheer (2019a), and Zhang and Choi (2013). However, none of these applications considers more than one level of heterogeneity as we do.
Our analyses reveal strong labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry over 1998– 2007. Controlling for technology heterogeneity, we find that most of the productivity growth was driven by capital deepening (125.60%), followed by technology progress (62.47%). The contribution of efficiency change was moderate (11.23%) because the room for efficiency improvement was already small in 1998. We find strong convergence of labor productivity across ownership types and among medium- and high-tech groups. We show that convergence was driven by technology change and capital deepening. We demonstrate the importance of heterogeneity components in explaining variations in the decomposition when using different reference technologies. We then link our study to the recent literature on China's productivity growth and synthesize these findings. Finally, we discuss the policy implications of our results.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the methodology. The data and summary statistics are shown in Section 3. In Section 4, we present our empirical findings, make interpretations, and discuss their implications. Section 5 concludes the study.
2.
Methodology
Our aim is to suggest a new decomposition of labor productivity growth when technology heterogeneity between entities (e.g., firms, regions, sectors) is taken into consideration. We first define the groups and the technologies and introduce our concepts of technical efficiency and technology gap. Next, we explain how to decompose labor productivity into several parts when entities belong to different technologies. Finally, we show how our different indicators can be computed by means of linear programs.
2.1. Groups and technologies
We assume that we observe decision making units (DMUs) from I groups where each group is composed of Ki types, for i=1,…,I during T time periods.8 Also, we consider that DMUs use P production factors, captured by xt∈RP+, to produce one output, captured by yt∈R+, at time t=1,…,T.
8 In our empirical study, a DMU comprises all firms of a certain ownership type within an industrial sector. These DMUs are first categorized into three technology groups, and then divided into three ownership types.
We define the technology in terms of output requirement sets. Given our setting, we distinguish between three levels: a type within a group, a group, and all groups. The output requirement sets are given as follows:
Ptik(x)={y∣x can produce y in type k of group i at time t},
(1)
Pti(x)={y∣x can produce y in group i at time t},
(2)
Pt(x)={y∣x can produce y at time t}.
(3)
We label Ptik(x) the group-type output requirement set, Pti(x) the group-specific output requirement set, and Pt(x) the overall output requirement set. These sets contain the output quantities that can be produced by the inputs x at time t at different levels. They are related as follows:
Pti(x)=Pti1(x)∪⋯∪PtiKi(x), for i=1,…,I,
(4)
Pt(x)=Pt1(x)∪⋯∪PtI(x).
(5)
A first implication is the following: Ptik(x)⊆Pti(x)⊆Pt(x), for all i, k, and t. Next, Pti(x) can be viewed as the envelopment of Ptik(x), and Pt(x) as the envelopment of Pti(x). At this point, we remark that the envelopment is, generally, non-convex (Afsharian and Podinovski, 2008; Huang et al., 2013; Kerstens et al., 2019; Walheer, 2018a). This will directly impact the computation (see Section 2.5). This also implies the following:
Thus, Pt(x) represents the meta technology set, i.e., when considering all groups (and thus all types) at time t.
2.2. Inefficiency and technology gap
We define inefficiency as the ability of DMUs to increase their output when keeping their inputs constant. To formally define (in)efficiency, we introduce the concept of potential outputs. Intuitively, potential outputs refer to the maximal output expansion with respect to the frontier of the chosen output requirement set. Given our technology heterogeneity context, we have three different potential outputs:
ytik(x)=max{y∣y∈Ptik(x)},
(7)
yti(x)=max{y∣y∈Pti(x)},
(8)
yt(x)=max{y∣y∈Pt(x)}.
(9)
Intuitively, actual output cannot exceed the potential values, which implies that ytik(x)≥y, yti(x)≥y, and yt(x)≥y for any DMU of type k in group i whose input-output mix is (x,y) at time t. If the actual output coincides with the potential output, the output is at its optimal value (with respect to the reference technology). Moreover, we have, by construction, that yt(x)≥yti(x)≥ytik(x) for any x. In words, potential output with respect to the group-type technology cannot exceed the potential output with respect to the group-specific technology, which cannot exceed the potential output with respect to the overall technology. Intuitively, this inequality reflects that the group-type technology sets are included in the group-specific technology sets, which are themselves included in the overall technology set.
A well-established indicator to capture the extent to which output can be raised is the Debreu–Farrell technical efficiency ratio (Debreu, 1951; Farrell, 1957). For any DMU of type k in group i whose input-output mix is (x,y) at time t, we define:
etik(x,y)=yytik(x),
(10)
eti(x,y)=yyti(x),
(11)
et(x,y)=yyt(x).
(12)
Depending on the reference technology, these three ratios provide three different levels of technical efficiency: etik(x,y) is the group-type technical efficiency, which measures the gap between the actual output y and the potential output of the technology that is available to type k in group i at time t; eti(x,y) is the group-specific technical efficiency, which is relative to the potential output of the group-specific technology; and et(x,y) is the overall technical efficiency, which is with reference to the potential output of the overall technology. As discussed previously, the actual output cannot exceed potential outputs, so the technical efficiency ratios are no greater than unity. When the ratio equals one, the output is at its maximal value with respect to the reference technology set. When the ratio is smaller than one, output can, in principle, be increased without increasing the production factors. Moreover, given the ranking between the potential outputs discussed previously, we also have etik(x,y)≥eti(x,y)≥et(x,y).
Next, we construct two measurements for the technology difference between the hierarchy levels. For any input mix x, we define:
gtik(x)=ytik(x)yti(x),
(13)
gti(x)=yti(x)yt(x).
(14)
gtik(x) is the group-type technology gap and gti(x) is the group-specific technology gap at time t. That is, gtik(x) captures the technology gap between the technology that is specific to type k and the technology that is available to group i, whereas gti(x) captures the technology gap between the technology that is specific to group i and the overall technology. Both ratios are smaller than one, which can be seen from the relationship between the potential outputs, i.e., yt(x)≥yti(x)≥ytik(x). A value of one reveals no technology gap, while a smaller value implies more gaps.
Using our two gap indicators, we can obtain a useful decomposition of potential output with respect to the group-type technology as follows:
ytik(x)=gtik(x)×gti(x)×yt(x).
(15)
Intuitively, there are two gaps between the potential output of the group-type technology ytik(x) and that of the overall technology yt(x): the group-type and the group-specific technology gaps. This is a direct implication of the three hierarchy levels.
Finally, we notice that the previous equation can be rewritten in terms of efficiency measurements. It suffices to evaluate (15) at x, then divide both sides by the actual output y:
et(x,y)=gtik(x)×gti(x)×etik(x,y).
(16)
That is, for any observed DMU, the overall technical efficiency is generally lower than the group-type technical efficiency, because of the two technology gaps between the hierarchy levels.
2.3. Productivity growth decomposition
Kumar and Russell (2002) suggest a useful decomposition for productivity growth that assumes a unified technology. To start with, suppose that the input-output mix of a DMU is (xb,yb) at time b and (xc,yc) at time c. The ratio of the actual outputs can be expressed as the product of two ratios: that of technical efficiency ratios and that of potential outputs. That is, we have:9
9 The subscripts i and k disappear because we assume a unified technology for the moment.
ycyb=ec(xc,yc)eb(xb,yb)yc(xc)yb(xb).
(17)
The next step is to introduce the counterfactual potential output yc(xb), which is the maximum output for the input mix xb given the technology of time c. Multiplying the right hand side of (17) by yc(xb)yc(xb), we get
Of the three terms on the right hand side, EFF is the efficiency change when the DMU changes its input-output mix from (xb,yb) to (xc,yc). TECHb measures the extent to which the production frontier shifts outward or inward when evaluated at xb. It captures technology change: TECHb>1 means technology progression and TECHb<1 means technology regression. KACCc measures the change of the potential output due to the change of the input mix if the technology is fixed at time c. If x is capital per worker and y is output per worker, as in our case, KACCc captures the effect of capital deepening. Obviously, both TECHb and KACCc depend on the chosen reference counterfactual yc(xb). If we use the other counterfactual yb(xc), the decomposition becomes
where TECHc is the technology change effect evaluated at xc and KACCb is the input change effect if the technology is fixed at time b.
To avoid arbitrary selection of the counterfactual, Kumar and Russell (2002) adopt the "Fisher ideal index, " which is the geometric mean of (18) and (18'). That is,
ycyb=EFF×√TECHb×TECHc×√KACCb×KACCc=EFF×TECH×KACC.
(19)
2.4. Heterogeneity components
In light of the technology heterogeneity between groups and types, the conventional growth decomposition (19) is incomplete. In general, the efficiency change, or technology change, or input change effect will be different when they are evaluated using the group-type concepts. The discrepancy arises because the technology gaps in (15) and (16) will also change following the change of the production sets and the change of the input-output mix. Consequently, each of these effects can be further decomposed into a group-type counterpart and two heterogeneity components that capture the change of technology gaps (Filippetti and Peyrache, 2015; Walheer, 2019a).
Suppose we observe a DMU of type k in group i. Let's denote its input-output mix by (xt,yt), where t∈{b,c}. Using (16), we can decompose EFF in (18) as follows:
The first term, EFFik, is the true efficiency change that is based on the group-type technical efficiency. The second term, GEFFik, is the measured change of the technology gap between the group-type frontier and the group-specific frontier, whereas GEFFi is the measured change of the technology gap between the group-specific frontier and the metafrontier. The latter two terms summarize the change of the overall efficiency due to varying technology gaps between the hierarchy levels. We call them heterogeneity components.
Next, we disentangle the overall technology change, represented by TECHb in (18), into the group-type technology change and heterogeneity components. Using (15), we have
The first term, TECHbik, is the change of the group-type technology evaluated at the input mix observed at time b. The next two terms measure the changes of the technology gaps between the hierarchy levels: GTECHbik for the gap between the group-type frontier and the group-specific frontier whereas GTECHbi for the gap between the group-specific frontier and the metafrontier, both evaluated at xb. The caveat is: the superscripts are in opposite orders in the expressions of the group-type technology change and the heterogeneity components. Intuitively, there are two ways to achieve overall technology progress (TECHb>1): Either there is technology progress at the group-type level (TECHbik>1), or the gaps between the production frontiers in period c are larger than those in period b, i.e., gcik(xb)<gbik(xb) or gci(xb)<gbi(xb). The latter statement is equivalent to GTECHbik>1 or GTECHbi>1.
In a similar manner, the overall input change effect KACCb in (18') can be decomposed into the input change effect of the group-type technology and two heterogeneity components. That is,
The first term, KACCbik, is the input change effect evaluated with the group-type technology at time b. The next two terms capture the changes of the technology gaps between the hierarchy levels due to the change of the input mix, when the technologies are all fixed at time b. Conceptually, if input change (e.g., capital deepening) increases the overall potential output (KACCb>1), this can be achieved via two separate channels. First, the potential output is increased at the group-type level (KACCbik>1). Second, even if the group-type potential output remains unchanged, as far as the technology gaps are larger (smaller value) when evaluated at the new input mix (xc), the overall potential output increases. This explains why xb and xc are placed in different positions in the expressions of KACCbik and the two heterogeneity components.
If we evaluate (21) at xc instead of xb, we end up with the decomposition of TECHc. Similarly, if we use the technologies at time c to evaluate the potential outputs and technology gaps in (22), we obtain the decomposition of KACCc. They are
TECHc=TECHcik×GTECHcik×GTECHci,
(21')
KACCc=KACCcik×GKACCcik×GKACCci.
(22')
With (20–22'), we obtain the following new decomposition:
Decompositions (20–22') consider two layers of heterogeneity. If we only consider the heterogeneity between technology groups, we can define the group-specific efficiency change, technology change, and input change effects as:
Assume that for two time periods b and c, we observe Nik DMUs of type k in group i, where k=1,…,Ki and i=1,…,I. For these data, it suffices to estimate the following potential output values to define all our technical efficiency and technology gap ratios: yt2ik(xt1), yt2i(xt1), and yt2(xt1), where t1,t2∈{b,c} and xt1 is the input mix of one of the Nik DMUs at time t1. Different methods could be used at this stage. We prefer, given our context, to make use of a nonparametric estimation method. Indeed, there is no guideline to define the technology (captured by output requirement sets) in the multi-group and multi-type context. Moreover, assuming a specific technology structure could bias the results of our study.
As such, we estimate the potential outputs using a Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA)-based methodology. DEA, introduced by Charnes et al. (1978), does not assume any functional form for the technology, but rather reconstructs the technology using the data. Nevertheless, to avoid a trivial reconstruction and to comply with the common practice, we impose some regularity conditions on the technology.10 Clearly, stochastic methods could be used as an alternative at this stage, when a parametric form is specified (Amsler et al., 2017).
10 In particular, we assume that the output-requirement sets satisfy free disposal of outputs, and are compact (Färe and Primont, 1995). Also, refer to O’Donnell et al. (2008) and Huang et al. (2013) for more detail about the estimation of technology gap ratios. Finally, we
point out that imposing regularity conditions is weaker than relying on a parametric specification for the technology/production function.
With DEA, the three potential outputs can be obtained by means of linear programs. Let us start with the group-type potential output. For each firm n of type k in group i, let's denote its input-ouput mix at time t by (xtikn,ytikn). For any input mix x, the group-type potential output ytik(x) is obtained using the following linear program:
The other two potential outputs are iteratively estimated as
yti(x)=maxk∈{1,…,Ki}ytik(x),
(32)
yt(x)=maxi∈{1,…,I}yti(x).
(33)
We notice that the production frontiers constructed from yti(x) and yt(x) are non-convex in general (Afsharian and Podinovski, 2008). These estimators have to be interpreted as their theoretical counterparts.
As a final remark, we point out that, in general, linear programs are very sensitive to the presence of outliers. Indeed, all the peers are used when computing potential outputs. Fortunately, it is possible to make the linear programs robust to this issue. Well-established methods, discussed, for example, in Daraio and Simar (2007), are the order-m (where m can be viewed as a trimming parameter), and the order-α (analogous to traditional quantile functions) procedures. In words, these procedures use sub-samples of the observations to compute the potential outputs in the linear programs. As a result, the estimates are less sensitive to potential issues, i.e., more robust.
3.
Data and descriptive statistics
Our study uses the China Industry Survey (CIS) dataset, which is a firm-level dataset prepared by the National Bureau of Statistics of China. It comprises more than 555, 000 distinct firms and spans the years 1998–2007, providing over two million observations. The CIS dataset provides rich information about each firm, including industrial classification, ownership structure, and inputs and outputs. Because of its comprehensiveness and wide coverage, the CIS dataset is highly visible among recent studies on China's industry (Brandt et al., 2012; Chen and Guariglia, 2013; Hsieh and Klenow, 2009; Yu, 2015).
Considering technology heterogeneity, we divide the sample into industrial sectors and then by ownership types. In compliance with the national standard of economic classification (GB/T 4754), each firm in the CIS dataset receives a four-digit industry classification code, with which we define 30 sectors. On the basis of the classification of technology intensities made by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), we re-group the sectors into three technology groups: low-tech, medium-tech, and high-tech.11 The industrial sectors and their technology classification are presented in Table S1 of the supplementary material. The CIS dataset defines 29 registration types based on ownership and organization structure. To focus on the ownership structure, we summarize them into three types: state-owned, private-owned, and foreign-owned.12 Because the registration information is often ambiguous about control rights and sometimes misleading (Hsieh and Song, 2015), we adopt a two-step procedure to determine a firm's ownership type. In step one, a firm is defined as state-
(private-, or foreign-) owned if the majority of the registered capital is owned by the state and collective organization (private persons, or foreigners). If step one is indeterminate, the registration type is used to determine the ownership type as far as it is unambiguous about control rights.13
11 The OECD classification can be found at http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/48350231.pdf. We remove art ware and other manufacturing (code range 4211-4290) from the sample because the technology intensity of this sector is undefined. We also remove tobacco manufacturing (code range 1610-1690) because this sector is dominated by state-owned firms. Both sectors are small compared to others.
12 Many studies also define a fourth ownership type: collective ownership. Firms are collective-owned if they are under control of collective organizations, such as government bureaus and communes. Therefore, collective ownership is conceptually similar to state ownership. Empirically, collective- and state-owned firms are found to be similar in many aspects (Chen and Guariglia, 2013; Guariglia et al., 2011; Walheer and He, 2018). To simplify our hierarchy structure, we merge collective ownership into state ownership.
13 Firms registered as state-owned enterprises, state-owned partnerships, state-owned limited liability companies, collective enterprises, and collective partnerships are defined as state-owned; firms registered as sole proprietorships, private partnerships, private limited liability companies, and private joint-stock companies are defined as private-owned; firms registered as (wholly) foreign-owned are defined as foreign-owned.
We consider a very simple setting with two production factors: capital and labor. The corresponding output variable is industrial value added. This simple setting, which dates to Solow (1956), is highly visible in empirical studies (Brandt et al., 2012; Chen and Guariglia, 2013; Kumar and Russell, 2002). Although the CIS dataset provides information on labor input, capital input and value add are reported in nominal values. We follow the procedure of Brandt et al. (2012) to convert capital stock from original purchasing prices to real values. We also use their sector-specific output deflator to convert value added into real terms.14
After removing incomplete firm-level observations, we end up with 496, 642 distinct firms and a total of 1, 862, 703 observations. In Table 1, we present the summary statistics of the three ownership types and the three technology groups for years 1998, 2003, and 2007.
Table 1.
Descriptive statistics by ownership type and technology intensity.
Year
State
Private
Foreign
Low-tech
Medium-tech
High-tech
Aggregate
Firm number (percentages for sub categories)
1998
58.42
27.57
14.01
38.54
55.08
6.37
130668
2003
26.30
55.24
18.46
37.51
55.74
6.75
167461
2007
10.20
70.69
19.12
36.06
57.17
6.77
287312
Employment (percentages for sub categories)
1998
68.81
18.53
12.66
32.82
60.03
7.15
45789757
2003
38.72
37.54
23.74
35.70
54.85
9.46
45708566
2007
20.07
47.96
31.97
35.20
52.47
12.33
63599564
Capital per worker
1998
80.75
46.77
107.90
55.42
90.07
78.76
77.89
2003
132.96
63.00
108.31
65.18
122.97
107.14
100.84
2007
202.91
86.39
123.09
76.78
152.85
115.86
121.51
Value added per worker
1998
25.96
32.05
56.64
27.66
30.08
53.65
30.97
2003
64.04
60.04
92.41
48.94
74.53
115.57
69.27
2007
136.52
111.09
127.16
86.23
135.46
161.43
121.33
Units: persons for total employment and 1, 000 RMB per person for capital per worker and value added per worker. We report sample means for capital per worker and value added per worker.
The total firm numbers are 79.2–85.3% of those reported by the China Statistical Yearbook, whereas the agammaegate employment numbers are 73.9–80.8% of the yearbook values. These indicate good coverage of our dataset despite the fact that we dropped two sectors. Judging by employment, the share of state-owned firms declined rapidly from 68.8% to 20.1%, whereas that of private firms and foreign-owned firms increased sharply. This dramatic change can be explained by China's FDI-friendly industrial policy after 1992 and the massive enterprise reform launched in 1997 (Hsieh and Song, 2015; Zhang and Song, 2001). Although the majority of the firms are found in the low-tech and medium-tech sectors, there has been a dramatic increase in the employment share of the high-tech group.
Overall, we observe substantial capital deepening in China's manufacturing industry. The average capital-labor ratio increased from 77, 890 RMB per person to 121, 510 RMB per person, i.e., a 56% increase, yet this is not comparable to the increase in labor productivity, which is 292%. Capital intensity and labor productivity are markedly different between ownership types and technology groups. Foreign ownership, which was the most capital intensive in 1998, was overtaken by state ownership in 2007. Similarly, the productivity advantage of foreign ownership vanished in 2007. Capital deepening was strong among medium- and high-tech firms, but to a much less extent for low-tech firms. The productivity gap was reduced between low- and high-tech firms but increased for low-tech firms. Thus, we observe productivity convergence across ownership types but mixed result between technology groups.
Our formal analysis is based on agammaegate data at the sector-ownership level. That is, all firms belonging to an ownership type in a two-digit sector is agammaegated into a single production unit. This agammaegation strategy is based on two considerations. First, DEA is sensitive to outliers and extreme values. Because we observe very large and very small firms at the same time, a firm-level analysis will impair the reliability of the entire set of estimates. Second, growth decomposition investigates the performance change of DMUs over time, which requires a balanced panel. However, the CIS dataset is highly unbalanced, with unusually high entry/exit rates in certain years (Brandt et al., 2014). Therefore, agammaegation is a necessary strategy to overcome this data problem. As we have 27 two-digit sectors and three ownership types, we end up with a total of 81 production units.
4.
Application
We investigate the sources of labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry, while distinguishing between different technology groups and ownership types. In Section 4.1, we first report the labor productivity growth for different technology groups and ownership types and demonstrate unconditional convergence. Then, we present the tripartite decomposition with reference to different technology concepts and highlight the role of heterogeneity components in synthesizing these results. It is shown that whether we consider technology heterogeneity or not has a large impact on the estimated effects and may change the convergence patterns of the individual effects. These results serve as the basis for the discussion in Section 4.2, where we link our results to the findings in the literature and discuss policy implications.
4.1. Results
Productivity convergence To take a first look at the growth pattern, we report the average labor productivity in 1998 and 2007 as well as the average labor productivity growth rate in Table 2.15
Table 2.
Labor productivity growth per ownership and technology group.
Technology intensity
Ownership
Labor productivity 1998
Labor productivity 2007
Labor productivity growth
low
state
25.41
104.48
309.69
private
31.32
93.96
197.93
foreign
52.87
106.91
91.43
all
36.53
101.78
199.68
medium
state
29.34
134.81
387.67
private
35.37
127.13
270.50
foreign
66.39
190.30
179.22
all
43.70
150.75
279.13
high
state
34.03
124.13
326.86
private
49.74
153.02
236.81
foreign
80.78
184.99
126.06
all
54.85
154.05
229.91
all
state
28.26
121.27
349.14
private
35.32
116.49
237.19
foreign
62.48
155.74
137.55
all
42.02
131.17
241.29
Units: 1, 000 RMB per person for labor productivity and percent for productivity growth. We report the cumulative growth rates over 1998-2007, i .e., (y2007/y1998−1)×100%. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
15 The values for all 81 production units are reported in Table S2 of the supplementary material.
Judging by the overall average, the labor productivity of China's manufacturing industry grew 241.29% over the 1998–2007 period. We observe a clear pattern of labor productivity catching up between ownership types. In 1998, within each technology group and on average, foreign ownership had the absolute advantage in labor productivity, whereas state ownership was the least productive. Although all three ownership types experienced phenomenal productivity growth, state ownership was the clear winner in terms of speed, followed by private ownership. Eventually, the productivity gap almost vanished within the low-tech group, and dwindled substantially for the other two technology groups. Remarkably in 2007, with the exception of the high-tech group, state ownership outperformed private ownership on all grounds. By then, foreign ownership was still the leader, but the productivity advantage had been substantially reduced.
In 1998, according to the average numbers, the high-tech group was the most productive and the low-tech group the least. Over 1998–2007, labor productivity growth was much higher for the medium-tech group than the high-tech group. As a result, the productivity gap between the medium- and high-tech groups virtually disappeared in 2007, although the latter maintained their leading position. The productivity growth of the low-tech group, however, was the lowest among the three technology groups.
The above comments reveal convergence of labor productivity between ownership types. They also suggest convergence between the medium- and high-tech groups, but divergence between the low-tech group and the rest of the industry. There remains to establish the overall growth pattern when pooling the data together. Following Kumar and Russell (2002), Henderson and Russell (2005), and Walheer (2018c), we plot the cumulative growth rate of labor productivity (in percent) against labor productivity in 1998 (in 1, 000 RMB per person) along with the GLS regression line for all 81 production units in Figure 1. The t-value for the slope coefficient is also displayed.
Figure 1.
Labor productivity growth versus labor productivity in 1998.
Figure 1 clearly indicates convergence of labor productivity in China's manufacturing industry. That is, in addition to convergence among ownership types, we demonstrate that convergence also holds when the industry is further divided into sectors within ownership types, i.e., when considering heterogeneity in the sectoral dimension. The latter result has never been documented in the literature. In light of the sluggish productivity growth in the low-tech group, our result also shows that the converging force between ownership types dominated the divergent force of the low-tech group.
Efficiency change Our next step is to identify the driving force of the convergence pattern. In Table 3, we present the efficiency change effect with reference to different technology concepts: the meta technology (EFF), which assumes the same technology for all production units; the group-specific technologies (EFFi), which assume heterogeneity across technology groups but not over ownership types; and the group-type technologies (EFFik), which assume full heterogeneity. We also present the heterogeneity components in (20), which are GEFFi and GEFFik.16 Next, in Figure 2 we plot the three efficiency change effects (in percent) against labor productivity in 1998 (in 1, 000 RMB per person) for all 81 production units and report the GLS t-values for the slope coefficients.
Table 3.
Growth decomposition: the efficiency change effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
EFF
EFFi
EFFik
GEFFi
GEFFik
low
state
25.41
36.48
26.01
-3.89
8.09
32.64
private
31.32
42.53
21.57
13.73
16.83
7.58
foreign
52.87
12.51
11.51
7.54
2.48
4.88
all
36.53
30.51
19.69
5.79
9.13
15.03
medium
state
29.34
15.27
9.13
0.84
4.45
8.08
private
35.37
53.83
21.56
10.28
28.41
13.01
foreign
66.39
33.45
31.52
30.41
2.57
1.44
all
43.70
34.18
20.73
13.84
11.81
7.51
high
state
34.03
77.01
55.62
39.61
9.13
17.58
private
49.74
26.54
20.00
20.00
4.96
0.00
foreign
80.78
10.92
9.61
0.00
1.01
9.61
all
54.85
38.15
28.41
19.87
5.03
9.06
all
state
28.26
30.77
21.17
3.22
6.45
19.14
private
35.32
46.19
21.39
12.76
21.09
9.35
foreign
62.48
22.42
20.93
17.72
2.36
3.75
all
42.02
33.13
21.16
11.23
9.97
10.75
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). EFF and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, EFF=(e2007(x2007,y2007)e1998(x1998,y1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Judging by EFFik, the overall efficiency change is quite small (11.23%), indicating sluggish efficiency improvement when the production units are benchmarked against the group-type frontiers. Private firms improved their technical efficiency in all three technology groups. Foreign-owned firms improved their efficiency strongly in the medium-tech group but to a less extent in the low-tech group. Overall, the efficiency improvement by these two ownership types were moderate. For state ownership, efficiency improvement is only seen in the high-tech group and very weak in average.
At this stage, we want to investigate why efficiency change was generally weak, and especially so for state ownership. We offer two explanations. First, if the efficiency levels were already high in 1998, then we cannot expect any strong improvement afterwards. Second, poor initial efficiency level could coexist with weak efficiency change. To find out which argument is true, we present the efficiency levels in Table 4.
Table 4.
Technical efficiency in 1998 and 2007.
Technology intensity
Ownership
e1998ik
e2007ik
low
state
0.893
0.861
private
0.839
0.942
foreign
0.874
0.923
all
0.869
0.909
medium
state
0.950
0.951
private
0.914
0.991
foreign
0.764
0.942
all
0.876
0.961
high
state
0.818
0.997
private
0.827
0.975
foreign
1.000
1.000
all
0.882
0.991
all
state
0.912
0.919
private
0.874
0.969
foreign
0.835
0.940
all
0.874
0.943
Note: We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
The figures clearly support the first explanation. In almost all categories, EFFik is large in Table 3 only if e1998ik is relatively low in Table 4. Note that the average efficiency level for state ownership was already 0.912 in 1998, which leaves little room for further improvement. This explains why efficiency change was particularly low for state ownership. It is also clear that the efficiency levels of most categories were quite close to unity in 2007. Thus, future efficiency improvement is even more difficult. The second explanation only works for state ownership in the low-tech group, for which the efficiency level was low in 1998, and the subsequent efficiency change negative.
The three measures of efficiency change are linked by the heterogeneity components GEFFik and GEFFi through (20). As we explained there, GEFFik measures the extent to which the observed technology gap between the production frontiers of the ownership (lower level) and the technology group (upper level) has closed up, whereas GEFFi measures the gap-closing rate between the group frontier (low level) and the meta frontier (upper level). Stronger technology progress at the lower level or favorable input change is needed to reduce these gaps.
The positive numbers of the heterogeneity components indicate industry wide gap-closing between the production frontiers at different hierarchy levels. Consequently, the efficiency change effect becomes much stronger when the production units are benchmarked against the group frontier (EFFi) or the meta frontier (EFF). If measured by EFF, the average efficiency change (33.13%) is three times as large as the average EFFik. We point out that the difference between these estimates should not be interpreted as a bias. Instead, it reflects a difference in interpretation: If we use the meta frontier as the reference, then technology gaps become part of the efficiency measure.
The result for GEFFik shows that state-ownership was able to substantially close up their technology gaps with respect to the low- and high-tech group frontiers (large GEFFik). Thus, they receive much higher scores in EFFi than EFFik in these groups and in general. The same is true for private ownership of the medium-tech group. Next, when we consider GEFFi, we find that private ownership successfully reduced the gap between the group frontier and the meta frontier in low- and medium-tech groups. Consequently they score much higher in EFF than EFFi. The same is true of state ownership in the high-tech group. Remarkably, the heterogeneity components are almost always the smallest for foreign ownership.
When we contrast EFFik with y1998, a negative correlation is only seen in the high-tech group but not in the others. Actually, they show a positive correlation when the figures are averaged at the group level or by ownership. These observations explain Figure 2c: Efficiency change measured by EFFik does not contribute to labor productivity convergence at all. The previous discussion shows that categories with lower labor productivity in 1998 (i.e., state-low-tech, state-high-tech, private-low-tech, and private-medium-tech) receive higher scores in the heterogeneity components, which boosts up their efficiency change when the latter is measured by EFFi or EFF. Thus, the heterogeneity components generate a permutation effect on EFFi and EFF: In almost all cases, private ownership beats foreign ownership in efficiency change, and in three cases, state ownership also beats private ownership. These explain why we observe significant convergence of efficiency change in Figures 2a and 2b. Clearly, the reduced technology gaps of the low-productivity categories contribute to these convergence patterns.
In conclusion, when benchmarked against the group-type production frontiers, the efficiency change was quite small in magnitude and barely contributed to labor productivity convergence. This happened because the efficiency levels were already high in 1998. In reference to group frontiers or the meta frontier, efficiency change becomes much larger and exhibits convergence. These are due to the shrinking technology gaps between the hierarchy levels, which prevailed all categories but were unbalanced.
Technology change Next, we examine the role played by technology change. As above, in Table 5, we first present our three measures of the technology change effect. They are the overall technology change effect (TECH), which is benchmarked against the meta technology and ignores technology heterogeneity, the group-specific technology change effect (TECHi), which is benchmarked against the group-specific technologies and assumes heterogeneity between technology groups only, and the group-type technology change effect (TECHik), which is benchmarked against the group-type technologies and assumes full heterogeneity. There, we also report the heterogeneity components, which are GTECHi and GTECHik. 17 To assess the impact of technology change on labor productivity convergence, in Figure 3 we generate the scatter plots for the technology change measures (in percent) versus labor productivity in 1998 (in 1, 000 RMB per person) for all 81 production units. GLS regression lines and t-values are shown therein.
Table 5.
Growth decomposition: the technology change effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
TECH
TECHi
TECHik
GTECHi
GTECHik
low
state
25.41
82.53
92.94
130.94
-3.36
-9.70
private
31.32
46.14
45.73
52.09
-0.24
-3.99
foreign
52.87
76.17
67.64
42.75
8.87
18.94
all
36.53
68.28
68.77
75.26
1.76
1.75
medium
state
29.34
61.23
45.18
66.91
8.56
-0.80
private
35.37
41.66
35.65
38.41
5.11
-0.24
foreign
66.39
89.25
77.93
66.11
5.73
7.42
all
43.70
64.05
52.92
57.14
6.46
2.13
high
state
34.03
51.82
57.39
48.70
-4.27
8.34
private
49.74
41.08
44.13
36.22
-2.05
6.24
foreign
80.78
30.41
30.77
30.88
-0.23
-0.09
all
54.85
41.10
44.10
38.60
-2.18
4.83
all
state
28.26
68.86
65.99
90.97
2.28
-3.41
private
35.32
43.42
40.70
43.74
2.13
-1.05
foreign
62.48
77.38
68.50
52.68
6.35
11.28
all
42.02
63.22
58.40
62.47
3.59
2.27
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). TECH and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, TECH=(√y2007(x1998)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y1998(x2007)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
The numbers reported for TECHik indicate strong technology progress in all technology groups and for all ownership types. According to the average in the last row, labor productivity grew 62.47% as a result of pure technology progress, which originated from the "bottom" of the technology hierarchy. Note that this effect is 4.5 times stronger than that of efficiency change identified in Table 3, when both concepts are defined with reference to the group-type production frontiers. Distinguishing between ownerships, we find that technology progress was much stronger for state ownership, which is true within technology groups and on average. Private ownership outperformed foreign ownership in the low- and high-tech groups. According to the group averages, technology progress was strongest in the low-tech group and weakest in the high-tech group. In conjugation with the rankings of y1998, the observations made here suggest convergence in technology progress, i.e., less productive categories in 1998 achieved higher rates of technology growth afterwards. This conjecture is readily justified by Figure 3c. Thus, when considering the group-type technologies, technology progress contributed to labor productivity growth and the convergence of labor productivity at the same time.
The two heterogeneity components GTECHik and GTECHi capture gap closing/widening between production frontiers at different hierarchy levels. These effects are generated by the movement of the production frontiers, whereas the impact of input change has been purged out. A positive value indicates expansion of the technology gap with respect to the upper-level production frontier and a negative value represents closing up of the gap. Judging by the average values, which are 2.27% for GTECHik and 3.59% for GTECHi, the technology gaps widened out only slightly. That is, on average, the group-type frontiers, the group frontiers, and the meta frontier shifted out almost uniformly. This explains why the three measures of the technology change effect are highly similar.
According to the values of GTECHik and GTECHi, state ownership closed (expanded) their technology gaps with respect to the upper-level production frontier more (less) than private ownership, and private ownership closed (expanded) their technology gaps more (less) than foreign ownership. These relationships are true in most cases. Thus, GTECHik and GTECHi tend to drive down (raise) TECHi and TECH more (less) for state ownership than for private ownership. The same is true when we compare private ownership and foreign ownership. Thus, the heterogeneity components generate a permutation effect on TECHi and TECH: They often reduce the technology change effect for categories that were less productive in 1998. Consequently, in Figures 3a and 3b, the negative relationship between the technology change effect and labor productivity in 1998 virtually disappears.
To sum up, we observe unbalanced change in the technology gaps between the hierarchical technology frontiers. State ownership reduced their technology gaps with respect to the group frontiers and the meta frontier, but the opposite is true of foreign ownership. Although the average technology change effect is insensitive to the choice of the reference technology, the latter does affect the convergence pattern of the former.
Capital deepening Finally, we present the results for the capital deepening effect. As above, we present the three measures of the capital deepening effect along with the heterogeneity components in Table 6. The overall capital deepening effect, KACC, is based on the meta technology and assumes the same technology for all production units. The group-specific capital deepening effect, KACCi, is based on group-specific technologies and assumes heterogeneity between technology groups only. The group-type capital deepening effect, KACCik, is based on group-type technologies and assumes full heterogeneity. The heterogeneity components are GKACCi and GKACCik.18 We also investigate the convergence of capital deepening in Figure 4, where we plot the three capital deepening effects (in percent) against labor productivity in 1998 (in 1, 000 RMB per person) along with the GLS regression lines for all 81 production units.
Table 6.
Growth decomposition: the capital deepening effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
KACC
KACCi
KACCik
GKACCi
GKACCik
low
state
25.41
102.26
106.97
132.92
-0.84
-10.12
private
31.32
50.96
72.05
74.83
-9.93
-1.84
foreign
52.87
4.66
10.55
36.79
-3.78
-16.90
all
36.53
52.63
63.19
81.51
-4.85
-9.62
medium
state
29.34
264.85
280.54
310.66
-7.86
0.83
private
35.37
79.10
132.05
147.94
-20.78
-6.75
foreign
66.39
26.64
33.61
46.05
-6.63
-7.41
all
43.70
123.53
148.73
168.22
-11.76
-4.44
high
state
34.03
87.93
79.69
130.96
0.94
-17.53
private
49.74
86.34
91.49
102.01
-2.42
-5.56
foreign
80.78
63.48
64.54
74.86
-0.76
-7.29
all
54.85
79.25
78.57
102.61
-0.75
-10.13
all
state
28.26
178.95
187.51
218.28
-4.02
-5.67
private
35.32
68.44
103.10
113.05
-14.32
-4.62
foreign
62.48
21.78
27.65
45.48
-4.82
-11.26
all
42.02
89.72
106.09
125.60
-7.72
-7.18
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). KACC and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, KACC=(√y1998(x2007)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y2007(x1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
As above, we start our analysis with KACCik, the measure for the capital deepening effect based on the group-type technology. Judging by the overall average, which is 125.60%, this effect is twice as large as the efficiency change effect. According to this figure, China's manufacturing would be able to increase its labor productivity by 125.60% times through capital deepening alone, even if there had been zero efficiency or technology improvement. Clearly, capital deepening was the main driver for productivity growth. The magnitude of this effect is quite large for state ownership, usually twice as large as that of private ownership, and almost four times larger than that of foreign ownership. This pattern reminds us of Table 1. There we find much more rapid growth in the capital-labor ratio among domestic firms, which explains the stronger effects observed here.
Because the capital deepening effect is always the strongest for state ownership and the weakest for foreign ownership, if we relate this to the productivity rankings, a negative correlation between KACCik and y1998 emerges. Thus, we do observe convergence of the capital deepening effect across ownership types. At the group level, however, the low-tech group not only had the lowest labor productivity in 1998, but also the smallest KACCik value, which suggests divergence. This pattern looks highly similar to what we saw in Table 2. It turns out that the converging force is stronger than the divergence force when pooling all production units together: Figure 4c depicts a negative relationship between KACCik and y1998 that is highly significant.
The heterogeneity components GKACCik and GKACCi capture the change in technology gaps when the upper- and lower-level production frontiers are held constant but the input mix is allowed to change. A positive value means a widening gap with reference to the upper-level production frontier, whereas a negative value implies that the gap has narrowed. Table 6 shows that the technology gaps between the hierarchy levels have been closing up for almost all categories. Judging by the average values, which are −7.18% for GKACCik and −7.72% for GKACCi, the average technology gap between the hierarchy levels were narrowed as a result of capital deepening. This explains why the capital deepening effect becomes smaller when the group or meta technology is used as benchmark. We point out that the heterogeneity components are not negligible in the current case. The average capital deepening effect along the meta frontier (KACC) is almost 30% smaller than that along the group-type frontiers (125.60% versus 89.72%).
Between technology groups or ownership types, the heterogeneity components GKACCik and GKACCi do not display any particular pattern similar to what was observed in Tables 3 and 5. Consequently, the permutation effect on KACCi and KACC is generally missing.19 This explains why the convergence pattern portrayed by Figure 4c is barely altered when we switch to KACCi and KACC (Figures 4a and 4b).
19 We point out that GKACCik is quite large in size for state ownership in the high-tech group and foreign ownership in the low-tech group, which reduces KACCi substantively for these categories. The same is true of GKACCi on private ownership in the medium-tech group.
To conclude, the capital deepening effect played the dominant role in labor productivity growth. It also strongly contributed to labor productivity convergence. Capital deepening resulted in smaller technology gaps between the hierarchy levels for almost all categories. Although the heterogeneity components are moderately large, they do not alter the qualitative results.
4.2. Summary and discussion
We summarize our findings as follows:
First, China's manufacturing industry experienced vigorous labor productivity growth over the 1998–2007 period. On average, the growth rate was 241.29%. Productivity growth was highly unbalanced across technology groups or ownership types. It exhibited a strong convergence pattern between ownership types and between the medium- and high-tech groups. However, the productivity gap between the low-tech group and the rest of the industry widened out. Overall, we observe strong convergence in labor productivity in China's manufacturing industry between sectors and ownership types.
Second, depending on the reference production frontier, productivity growth due to efficiency change was 11.23–33.13%. The measured effect is stronger when benchmarked against the group frontiers or the meta frontier because the observed technology gaps between the hierarchical levels shrank over time. With reference to the group-type technologies, there was little efficiency change among state-owned firms and the low-tech group, but less productive categories usually benefited more from the gap-closing effects. Efficiency change contributed to productivity convergence only if measured by the group technologies or the meta technology.
Third, the measured technology change effect, which ranges between 58.40–63.22%, is less sensitive to the choice of the reference technology. On average, the technology gaps between the hierarchy levels expanded very little (2.27% and 3.59%). At the group-type level, the technology change effect was stronger among less productive categories (e.g., 90.97% for state ownership and 75.26% for the low-tech group). At higher levels, however, the more productive categories often benefited more from the expansion of technology gaps. The technology change effect exhibits convergence only at the group-type level.
Fourth, capital deepening was the major driver of productivity growth and convergence. With reference to the group-type technologies, productivity growth due to capital deepening was 125.60%. Because capital deepening also narrowed down the technology gaps between the hierarchy levels, it is smaller when measured by the group technologies (106.09%) or the meta technology (89.72%). Capital deepening narrowed down technology gaps on almost all fronts and this effect outweighs the gap expansion effect brought by technology change. Convergence is seen in all three measures of the capital deepening effect.
At this stage, we want to contrast our results with the relevant findings in the literature. First, our DEA-based tripartite decomposition highlights capital deepening as the most important single factor for labor productivity growth. This finding is consistent with Henderson et al. (2007) and Badunenko and Tochkov (2010), although they study Chinese regions. Regressional analysis of China's industry, however, emphasizes the importance of TFP in explaining output growth (Brandt et al., 2012; Chen et al., 2011). We think the difference can be reconciled on the following grounds. One, the growth mode of the overall economy may differ from that of the manufacturing sector. In fact, our decomposition assigns far more importance to efficiency change and technology change than studies on regional economies.20 Second, if we interpret TFP change as the composite effect of efficiency change and technology change (Bos et al., 2010a; Henderson and Russell, 2005), our estimates suggest a TFP growth rate similar to what has been estimated for China's industry using regressional methods.21 Third, following the previous interpretation, our results do show that TFP contributed more than capital accumulation to labor productivity growth.22
20 If we ignore technology heterogeneity, as most studies do, then our efficiency change, technology progress, and capital deepening effects are 33.13%, 63.22%, and 89.72%, respectively. These numbers are 17.2%, 6.0%, and 101.5% in Henderson et al. (2007) and −8.18%, 6.82%, and 55.56% in Badunenko and Tochkov (2010).
21 Ignoring technology heterogeneity again, our estimates suggest that cumulative TFP growth was 117.29% during 1998–2007, or 9.00% per annum. In comparison, Brandt et al. (2012) estimate that the annual TFP growth rate was 7.96% during the same period, whereas Jefferson et al.'s (2008) estimate is 9.39%. These numbers are much higher than the TFP growth rates estimated for Chinese regions (Chen et al., 2009; Brandt and Zhu, 2010), which provides further evidence that the growth mode of the overall economy differs from that of the manufacturing sector.
22 That is, cumulative TFP growth was 117.29% whereas the capital deepening effect was 89.72% when we ignore technology heterogeneity. In comparison, Brandt et al. (2012) estimate that TFP growth contributed to 57% of the output growth in China's manufacturing industry, and the remaining 43% was due to factor accumulation. Nevertheless, we remark that our decomposition is not directly comparable to theirs.
Second, our analyses reveal strong convergence of labor productivity, which is quite clear across ownership types. Similarly, Berkowitz et al. (2017), Hsieh and Song (2015), and Jefferson et al. (2008) all find TFP convergence across ownership types. In a broader sense, our findings are also consistent with those of Deng and Jefferson (2011) and Lemoine et al. (2015), who show convergence of industrial labor productivity across regions. These findings, however, are at odds with studies of China's regional economic development. Badunenko and Tochkov (2010) and Henderson et al. (2007) study per capita GDP growth among Chinese provinces using decomposition methods that are very similar to ours. Their results show divergence over 1998–2003 and 1990–2000, which was mainly driven by efficiency change and technology change.23 In a similar study, Chen et al. (2009) study TFP growth among Chinese provinces. Their decomposition also demonstrates a divergence pattern driven by efficiency change and technology change. This apparent conflict is solved by Rodrik (2013), who argues that the manufacturing industry should exhibit unconditional convergence because this industry produces tradable goods and faces fierce competition domestically and abroad. Consequently, firms are under constant pressure to upgrade their operations and remain competitive. It follows that resource reallocation and technology transfer are easier to take place, resulting in productivity convergence. In contrast, the rest of the economy (agriculture and service) is locked to the local market, which means the mechanisms for convergence do not function properly. This explains why the economy as a whole usually fails to exhibit convergence.
23Unel and Zebregs (2009) perform a similar analysis using much earlier data (1978–1998), their analysis produces a convergence pattern only after the much stronger growth in coastal provinces and the effect of foreign direct investment have been controlled.
These findings have rich policy implications. First, the convergence patterns identified in this article suggest that the market forces were functioning properly in China's manufacturing industry. That is, capital intensity increased in low-productivity sectors and ownership types, where the marginal return was higher (Figure 4c), and technology spillover took place between high-tech and low-tech categories (Figure 3c). We remark that other researchers also provide concrete evidence on improved resource allocation and technology spillover.24 Overall, China's marketization reforms has successfully boosted labor productivity and reduced disparity in the manufacturing industry.
24 Regarding resource reallocation, both Brandt et al. (2012) and Ding et al. (2016) emphasize firm turnover, which is especially true of state ownership (Jefferson et al., 2008). In addition, Hsieh and Song (2015) point out that state-owned firms successfully reduced redundant labor. For channels of technology spillover, Xu and Sheng (2012) highlight the role of foreign-owned firms, whereas He and Walheer (2019) identify additional sources: high-tech sectors, private ownership, and exporting firms.
Nevertheless, we believe resource allocation between the ownership types can be further improved. Domestic firms were far more reliant on capital accumulation than foreign-owned firms, whereas state-owned firms were far more capital-thirsty than indigenous private firms (Table 6). The fast capital accumulation among private firms is justifiable, because their capital intensity has been the lowest (Table 1). However, capital accumulation among state-owned firms seems to contradict the principle of optimal resource allocation, because they were already the most capital intensive in 2003, and they further increased their advantage in 2007. Thus, mechanisms that channel more capital to indigenous private firms may generate an additional boost to the overall performance of China's manufacturing industry.
Second, the main driver of productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry is capital deepening. Badunenko and Tochkov (2010) and Henderson et al. (2007) question the sustainability of this growth mode.25 We point out that although the capital intensity of China's manufacturing industry almost quadrupled during 1998–2007 (Table 1), it was only 8.3–15% of those of the developed economies.26 On the basis of these figures, China's manufacturing industry can maintain another fifteen years' high growth by means of capital deepening alone.
26 As of 2007, the manufacturing capital intensity was 210, 566 USD per person in the United States, 22 million Yen per person in Japan, and 106, 779 Euro per person in EU12. Source: OECD Stan Dataset and authors' own calculations. Values are in 2010 prices. EU12 does not include Spain and Portugal because of missing data in capital stock.
Third, technology change played a far more important role in productivity growth than efficiency change.27 This, though, does not mean that China's manufacturing did a poor job in improving technical efficiency or efficiency change could be a potential source of future labor productivity growth. Overall, efficiency growth was weak simply because there was little room for improvement. Our result suggests that the ultimate source of labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry must be technology progress. The only exception seems to be state ownership in the low-tech group, for which efficiency change could play a more important role than in other categories.
27 This conclusion is based on comparing EFFik in Table 3 to TECHik in Table 5. According to our previous discussions, they are appropriate measure for pure efficiency change and technology progress, because each production unit is contrasted with the potential output of the technology group it belongs to. In comparison, EFFi and EFF contains the technology progress of the lower-level technology relative to the upper-level technology, whereas TECHi and TECH reflect the technology progress of the upper-level frontiers.
Finally, we express our concerns about the low-tech group. Initial labor productivity and subsequent productivity growth were both the lowest among this group, suggesting divergence (Table 2). According to the tripartite decomposition, the low productivity growth was mainly caused by the efficiency regression of state ownership (Table 3) and the low level of capital accumulation among all three ownership types (Table 6). Remarkably, the low-tech group also features the lowest capital intensity throughout the study period (Table 1). In the language of Bos et al. (2010a), the low-tech group may belong to a different technology club. Measures to improve technical efficiency, especially among state-owned firms, and policies that encourage capital accumulation may help the low-tech group to achieve higher labor productivity growth and narrow the gap with the rest of the manufacturing industry.
5.
Conclusion
In this article, we employ DEA to analyze labor productivity growth in China's manufacturing industry during 1998–2007. Methodologically, we employ the concept of metafrontier to control for technology heterogeneity across technology groups and ownership types when performing the tripartite decomposition. We highlight the importance of controlling for heterogeneity when making interpretations and explain how different decomposition results can be linked by the heterogeneity components.
Our main finding is twofold. First, capital deepening was the most important single factor for labor productivity growth, followed by technology progress, but the contribution from efficiency change was moderate. Second, labor productivity exhibited strong unconditional convergence during the study period, which was driven by capital deepening and technology change. However, we also observe increasing disparity between the low-tech group and the rest of the industry.
The results fill two gaps in the empirical literature. We point out that researchers have different views about the relative importance of technology progress and factor accumulation in explaining China's productivity growth because they use different data and technology measures. We also emphasize that the intrinsic difference between the manufacturing industry and the agammaegate economy is the key to understanding the convergence and divergence patterns found in the literature.
Our policy recommendations are as follows: First, although market forces seem to be effective in allocating resources and creating technology spillovers in China's manufacturing industry, further improvements are possible. Second and third, we point out that China's industry can rely on capital accumulation in the short run, but the source of long-term productivity growth must be technology progress. Finally, we call for policy intervention in the low-tech sectors.
Before concluding, we would like to point out a few limitations of the study. First, due to data limitation, our decomposition does not consider human capital, which has been found to be an important source of productivity growth (Badunenko and Romero-Ávila, 2013; Henderson and Russell, 2005; Walheer, 2016a). Thus, our estimates could be biased.28 Second, our categorization of technology groups is based on an exogenous criterion which is time-invariant. Endogenously determined dynamic regimes, as modeled by Bos et al. (2010a) and Bos et al. (2010b), may more accurately model the technology differences between industrial sectors and bring new insights to the analysis. Finally, we must acknowledge that the Kumar-Russell style decomposition has its own limitations. That is, it cannot separate the effect of entry and exit from agammaegate productivity growth, or study the effect of resource reallocation within sectors. Regressional methods are advantageous in answering these questions (Brandt et al., 2012; Ding et al., 2016).
Conflict of interest
All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.
References
[1]
Afsharian M, Podinovski VV (2018) A linear programming approach to efficiency evaluation in nonconvex metatechnologies. Eur J Oper Res 268: 268-280. doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.01.013
Atkinson AB, Stiglitz JE (1969) A new view of technological change. Econ J 79: 573-578. doi: 10.2307/2230384
[4]
Badunenko O, Kumbhakar SC (2017) Economies of scale, technical change and persistent and time-varying cost efficiency in Indian banking: Do ownership, regulation and heterogeneity matter? Eur J Oper Res 260: 789-803. doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2017.01.025
[5]
Badunenko O, Romero-Ávila D (2013) Financial development and the sources of growth and convergence. Int Econ Rev 54: 629-663. doi: 10.1111/iere.12009
[6]
Badunenko O, Tochkov K (2010) Soaring dragons, roaring tigers, growling bears: Determinants of regional growth and convergence in China, India and Russia. Econ Transition 18: 539-570. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2009.00387.x
[7]
Banker RD, Charnes A, Cooper WW (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Manage Sci 30: 1078-1092. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.30.9.1078
[8]
Barro R, Sala-i-Martin X (1991) Convergence across states and regions. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1991:107-182. doi: 10.2307/2534639
[9]
Basu S, Weil DN (1998) Appropriate technology and growth. Q J Econ 113: 1025-1054. doi: 10.1162/003355398555829
[10]
Battese GE, Rao DSP (2002) Technology gap, efficiency, and a stochastic metafrontier function. Int J Bus Econ 1: 87-93.
[11]
Battese GE, Rao DSP, O'Donnell CJ (2004) A metafrontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies. J Prod Anal 21: 91-103. doi: 10.1023/B:PROD.0000012454.06094.29
[12]
Baumol WJ (1986) Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: What the long-run data show. Am Econ Rev 76: 1072-1085.
[13]
Berkowitz D, Ma H, Nishioka S (2017) Recasting the iron rice bowl: The reform of China's state-owned enterprises. Rev Econ Stat 99: 735-747. doi: 10.1162/REST_a_00637
[14]
Bos JWB, Economidou C, Koetter M (2010a) Technology clubs, R&D and growth patterns: Evidence from EU manufacturing. Eur Econ Rev 54: 60-79.
[15]
Bos JWB, Economidou C, Koetter M, et al. (2010b) Do all countries grow alike? J Dev Econ 91:113-127.
[16]
Brandt L, Van Biesebroeck J, Zhang Y (2012) Creative accounting or creative destruction? Firm-level productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing. J Dev Econ 97: 339-351.
[17]
Brandt L, Van Biesebroeck J, Zhang Y (2014) Challenges of working with the Chinese NBS firm-level data. China Econ Rev 30: 339-352. doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2014.04.008
[18]
Brandt L, Zhu X (2010) Accounting for China's growth Working Paper 394. Department of Economics, University of Toronto.
[19]
Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur J Oper Res 2: 429-444. doi: 10.1016/0377-2217(78)90138-8
[20]
Chen KH, Huang YJ, Yang CH (2009) Analysis of regional productivity growth in China: A generalized metafrontier MPI approach. China Econ Rev 20: 777-792. doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2009.05.003
[21]
Chen M, Guariglia A (2013) Internal financial constraints and firm productivity in China: Do liquidity and export behavior make a difference? J Comp Econ 41: 1123-1140. doi: 10.1016/j.jce.2013.05.003
[22]
Chen S, Jefferson GH, Zhang J (2011) Structural change, productivity growth and industrial transformation in China. China Econ Rev 22: 133-150. doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2010.10.003
[23]
Daraio C, Simar L (2007) Advanced robust and nonparametric methods in efficiency analysis: Methodology and applications, New York, NYSpringer.
[24]
Debreu G (1951) The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19: 273-292. doi: 10.2307/1906814
[25]
Deng PD, Jefferson GH (2011) Explaining spatial convergence of China's industrial productivity. Oxford Bulletin Econ Stati 73: 818-832. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0084.2011.00675.x
[26]
Ding S, Guariglia A, Harris R (2016) The determinants of productivity in Chinese large and medium-sized industrial firms, 1998-2007. J Prod Anal 45: 131-155. doi: 10.1007/s11123-015-0460-0
[27]
Elyasiani E, Rezvanian R (2002) A comparative multiproduct cost study of foreign-owned and domestic-owned US banks. Appl Financ Econ 12: 271-284. doi: 10.1080/09603100110090136
[28]
Färe R, Grosskopf S, Norris M, et al. (1994) Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am Econ Rev 84: 66-83.
[29]
Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality: Theory and applications, Kluwer, Boston, MA.
[30]
Farrell MJ (1957) The measurement of productive efficiency The measurement of productive efficiency. J Royal Stat Society Series A (General) 120: 253-281. doi: 10.2307/2343100
[31]
Fei R, Lin B (2016) Energy efficiency and production technology heterogeneity in China's agricultural sector: A meta-frontier approach. Technol Forecasting Social Change 109: 25-34. doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2016.05.012
[32]
Filippetti A, Peyrache A (2015) Labour productivity and technology gap in European regions: A conditional frontier approach. Reg Stud 49: 532-554. doi: 10.1080/00343404.2013.799768
[33]
Guariglia A, Liu X, Song L (2011) Internal finance and growth: Microeconometric evidence on Chinese firms. J Dev Econ 96: 79-94. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.07.003
[34]
Hayami Y, Ruttan VW (1970) Agricultural productivity differences among countries Agricultural productivity differences among countries. Am Econ Rev 60: 895-911.
[35]
He M, Walheer B (2019) Spillovers and path dependences in the Chinese manufacturing industry: A firm-level analysis. J Dev Stud.
[36]
Henderson DJ, Russell RR (2005) Human capital and convergence: A production-frontier approach. Int Econ Rev 46: 1167-1205. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2354.2005.00364.x
[37]
Henderson DJ, Tochkov K, Badunenko O (2007) A drive up the capital coast? Contributions to post-reform growth across Chinese provinces. J Macroecon 29: 569-594.
[38]
Hsieh CT, Klenow PJ (2009) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. Q J Econo 124: 1403-1448. doi: 10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1403
[39]
Hsieh CT, Song ZM (2015) Grasp the large, let go of the small: The transformation of the state sector in China. Brookings Pap Econ Act 2015: 295-346.
[40]
Huang CW, Ting CT, Lin CH, et al. (2013) Measuring non-convex metafrontier efficiency in international tourist hotels. J Oper Res Society 64:250-259. doi: 10.1057/jors.2012.52
[41]
Jefferson GH, Rawski TG, Zhang Y (2008) Productivity growth and convergence across China's industrial economy. J Chinese Econo Bus Stud 6: 121-140. doi: 10.1080/14765280802028237
[42]
Kerstens K, O'Donnell C, Van de Woestyne I (2019) Metatechnology frontier and convexity: A restatement. Eur J Oper Res 275: 780-792. doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.11.064
[43]
Kumar S, Russell RR (2002) Technological change, technological catch-up, and capital deepening:Relative contributions to growth and convergence. Am Econ Rev 92: 527-548.
[44]
Lemoine F, Poncet S, Ünal D (2015) Spatial rebalancing and industrial convergence in China. China Econ Rev 34: 39-63. doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2015.03.007
[45]
Molinos-Senante M, Maziotis A, Sala-Garrido R (2017) Assessing the productivity change of water companies in England and Wales: A dynamic metafrontier approach. J Environ Manage 197: 1-9. doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2017.03.023
[46]
O'Donnell CJ, Rao DSP, Battese GE (2008). Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empirical Econ 34: 231-255. doi: 10.1007/s00181-007-0119-4
[47]
Rodrik D (2013) Unconditional convergence in manufacturing. Q J Econ 128: 165-204. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjs047
[48]
Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70: 65-94. doi: 10.2307/1884513
[49]
Unel B, Zebregs H (2009) The dynamics of provincial growth in China: A nonparametric approach. IMF Staff Pap 56: 239-262. doi: 10.1057/imfsp.2008.1
[50]
Walheer B (2016a) Growth and convergence of the OECD countries: A multi-sector production-frontier approach. Eur Jo Oper Rese 252: 665-675.
[51]
Walheer B (2016b) Multi-sector nonparametric production-frontier analysis of the economic growth and the convergence of the European countries. Pac Econ Rev 21: 498-524.
[52]
Walheer B (2018a) Aggregation of metafrontier technology gap ratios: The case of European sectors in 1995-2015. Eur J Oper Res 269: 1013-1026.
[53]
Walheer B (2018b) Economic growth and greenhouse gases in Europe: A non-radial multi-sector nonparametric production-frontier analysis. Energy Econ 74: 51-62.
[54]
Walheer B (2018c) Labour productivity growth and energy in Europe: A production-frontier approach. Energy 152: 129-143.
[55]
Walheer B (2019a) Disentangling heterogeneity gaps and pure performance differences in composite indexes over time: The case of the Europe 2020 strategy. Social Indicators Res 143: 25-45.
[56]
Walheer B (2019b) How foreign investments contribute to economic growth of industrial parks in China: A production-frontier decomposition approach. Appl Econ Lett 26: 281-285.
[57]
Walheer B (2019c) Scale, congestion, and technical efficiency of European countries: A sector-based nonparametric approach. Empirical Econ 56: 2025-2078.
[58]
Walheer B, He M (2018) Technical efficiency and technology gap of the manufacturing industry in china: Does firm ownership matter? World Dev.
[59]
Xu X, Sheng Y (2012) Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment: Firm-level evidence from China. World Dev 40: 62-74. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.05.006
[60]
Yu M (2015) Processing trade, tariff reductions and firm productivity: Evidence from Chinese firms. Econ J 125: 943-988. doi: 10.1111/ecoj.12127
[61]
Zhang KH, Song S (2001) Promoting exports: The role of inward FDI in China. China Econ Rev 11:385-396. doi: 10.1016/S1043-951X(01)00033-5
[62]
Zhang N, Choi Y (2013) Total-factor carbon emission performance of fossil fuel power plants in China:A metafrontier non-radial Malmquist index analysis. Energy Econ 40: 549-559. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2013.08.012
This article has been cited by:
1.
Xueyin Ou, Penghao Ye, Pierre Failler, Antaya March,
Planning the R&D of Marine Renewable Energy Resources: Avoiding Bottlenecks and Ensuring Sustainable Development in Developing Marine Economies,
2021,
9,
2296-665X,
10.3389/fenvs.2021.654566
2.
Jinhui Zhu, Zhenghui Li,
Can digital financial inclusion effectively stimulate technological Innovation of agricultural enterprises?—A case study on China,
2021,
3,
2689-3010,
398,
10.3934/NAR.2021021
3.
Shiwen Fu, Jianguo Yuan, Deyun Xiao, Zhiqiang Chen, Gaorong Yang,
Research on environmental regulation, environmental protection tax, and earnings management,
2023,
11,
2296-665X,
10.3389/fenvs.2023.1085144
4.
Zhenghui Li, Yan Wang, László Vasa,
Is there a moderate range of impact of financialization on corporate R&D?,
2021,
16,
1932-6203,
e0253380,
10.1371/journal.pone.0253380
5.
D. Klynovskyi,
ANALYZING THE IMPACT OF AIR POLLUTION ON LABOR PRODUCTIVITY IN MANUFACTURING,
2020,
18179290,
212,
10.21272/1817-9215.2020.3-23
6.
Giorgio Garau,
Total factor productivity and relative prices: the case of Italy,
2022,
4,
2689-3010,
16,
10.3934/NAR.2022002
7.
Li Xu, Ping Guo, Guoqin Pan,
Effects of inter-industry agglomeration on environmental pollution: Evidence from China,
2023,
20,
1551-0018,
7113,
10.3934/mbe.2023307
Ming He, Barnabé Walheer. Technology intensity and ownership in the Chinese manufacturing industry: A labor productivity decomposition approach[J]. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 110-137. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020007
Ming He, Barnabé Walheer. Technology intensity and ownership in the Chinese manufacturing industry: A labor productivity decomposition approach[J]. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 110-137. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020007
Table 1.
Descriptive statistics by ownership type and technology intensity.
Year
State
Private
Foreign
Low-tech
Medium-tech
High-tech
Aggregate
Firm number (percentages for sub categories)
1998
58.42
27.57
14.01
38.54
55.08
6.37
130668
2003
26.30
55.24
18.46
37.51
55.74
6.75
167461
2007
10.20
70.69
19.12
36.06
57.17
6.77
287312
Employment (percentages for sub categories)
1998
68.81
18.53
12.66
32.82
60.03
7.15
45789757
2003
38.72
37.54
23.74
35.70
54.85
9.46
45708566
2007
20.07
47.96
31.97
35.20
52.47
12.33
63599564
Capital per worker
1998
80.75
46.77
107.90
55.42
90.07
78.76
77.89
2003
132.96
63.00
108.31
65.18
122.97
107.14
100.84
2007
202.91
86.39
123.09
76.78
152.85
115.86
121.51
Value added per worker
1998
25.96
32.05
56.64
27.66
30.08
53.65
30.97
2003
64.04
60.04
92.41
48.94
74.53
115.57
69.27
2007
136.52
111.09
127.16
86.23
135.46
161.43
121.33
Units: persons for total employment and 1, 000 RMB per person for capital per worker and value added per worker. We report sample means for capital per worker and value added per worker.
Table 2.
Labor productivity growth per ownership and technology group.
Technology intensity
Ownership
Labor productivity 1998
Labor productivity 2007
Labor productivity growth
low
state
25.41
104.48
309.69
private
31.32
93.96
197.93
foreign
52.87
106.91
91.43
all
36.53
101.78
199.68
medium
state
29.34
134.81
387.67
private
35.37
127.13
270.50
foreign
66.39
190.30
179.22
all
43.70
150.75
279.13
high
state
34.03
124.13
326.86
private
49.74
153.02
236.81
foreign
80.78
184.99
126.06
all
54.85
154.05
229.91
all
state
28.26
121.27
349.14
private
35.32
116.49
237.19
foreign
62.48
155.74
137.55
all
42.02
131.17
241.29
Units: 1, 000 RMB per person for labor productivity and percent for productivity growth. We report the cumulative growth rates over 1998-2007, i .e., (y2007/y1998−1)×100%. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Table 3.
Growth decomposition: the efficiency change effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
EFF
EFFi
EFFik
GEFFi
GEFFik
low
state
25.41
36.48
26.01
-3.89
8.09
32.64
private
31.32
42.53
21.57
13.73
16.83
7.58
foreign
52.87
12.51
11.51
7.54
2.48
4.88
all
36.53
30.51
19.69
5.79
9.13
15.03
medium
state
29.34
15.27
9.13
0.84
4.45
8.08
private
35.37
53.83
21.56
10.28
28.41
13.01
foreign
66.39
33.45
31.52
30.41
2.57
1.44
all
43.70
34.18
20.73
13.84
11.81
7.51
high
state
34.03
77.01
55.62
39.61
9.13
17.58
private
49.74
26.54
20.00
20.00
4.96
0.00
foreign
80.78
10.92
9.61
0.00
1.01
9.61
all
54.85
38.15
28.41
19.87
5.03
9.06
all
state
28.26
30.77
21.17
3.22
6.45
19.14
private
35.32
46.19
21.39
12.76
21.09
9.35
foreign
62.48
22.42
20.93
17.72
2.36
3.75
all
42.02
33.13
21.16
11.23
9.97
10.75
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). EFF and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, EFF=(e2007(x2007,y2007)e1998(x1998,y1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Table 5.
Growth decomposition: the technology change effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
TECH
TECHi
TECHik
GTECHi
GTECHik
low
state
25.41
82.53
92.94
130.94
-3.36
-9.70
private
31.32
46.14
45.73
52.09
-0.24
-3.99
foreign
52.87
76.17
67.64
42.75
8.87
18.94
all
36.53
68.28
68.77
75.26
1.76
1.75
medium
state
29.34
61.23
45.18
66.91
8.56
-0.80
private
35.37
41.66
35.65
38.41
5.11
-0.24
foreign
66.39
89.25
77.93
66.11
5.73
7.42
all
43.70
64.05
52.92
57.14
6.46
2.13
high
state
34.03
51.82
57.39
48.70
-4.27
8.34
private
49.74
41.08
44.13
36.22
-2.05
6.24
foreign
80.78
30.41
30.77
30.88
-0.23
-0.09
all
54.85
41.10
44.10
38.60
-2.18
4.83
all
state
28.26
68.86
65.99
90.97
2.28
-3.41
private
35.32
43.42
40.70
43.74
2.13
-1.05
foreign
62.48
77.38
68.50
52.68
6.35
11.28
all
42.02
63.22
58.40
62.47
3.59
2.27
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). TECH and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, TECH=(√y2007(x1998)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y1998(x2007)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Table 6.
Growth decomposition: the capital deepening effect.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
KACC
KACCi
KACCik
GKACCi
GKACCik
low
state
25.41
102.26
106.97
132.92
-0.84
-10.12
private
31.32
50.96
72.05
74.83
-9.93
-1.84
foreign
52.87
4.66
10.55
36.79
-3.78
-16.90
all
36.53
52.63
63.19
81.51
-4.85
-9.62
medium
state
29.34
264.85
280.54
310.66
-7.86
0.83
private
35.37
79.10
132.05
147.94
-20.78
-6.75
foreign
66.39
26.64
33.61
46.05
-6.63
-7.41
all
43.70
123.53
148.73
168.22
-11.76
-4.44
high
state
34.03
87.93
79.69
130.96
0.94
-17.53
private
49.74
86.34
91.49
102.01
-2.42
-5.56
foreign
80.78
63.48
64.54
74.86
-0.76
-7.29
all
54.85
79.25
78.57
102.61
-0.75
-10.13
all
state
28.26
178.95
187.51
218.28
-4.02
-5.67
private
35.32
68.44
103.10
113.05
-14.32
-4.62
foreign
62.48
21.78
27.65
45.48
-4.82
-11.26
all
42.02
89.72
106.09
125.60
-7.72
-7.18
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). KACC and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, KACC=(√y1998(x2007)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y2007(x1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Units: persons for total employment and 1, 000 RMB per person for capital per worker and value added per worker. We report sample means for capital per worker and value added per worker.
Technology intensity
Ownership
Labor productivity 1998
Labor productivity 2007
Labor productivity growth
low
state
25.41
104.48
309.69
private
31.32
93.96
197.93
foreign
52.87
106.91
91.43
all
36.53
101.78
199.68
medium
state
29.34
134.81
387.67
private
35.37
127.13
270.50
foreign
66.39
190.30
179.22
all
43.70
150.75
279.13
high
state
34.03
124.13
326.86
private
49.74
153.02
236.81
foreign
80.78
184.99
126.06
all
54.85
154.05
229.91
all
state
28.26
121.27
349.14
private
35.32
116.49
237.19
foreign
62.48
155.74
137.55
all
42.02
131.17
241.29
Units: 1, 000 RMB per person for labor productivity and percent for productivity growth. We report the cumulative growth rates over 1998-2007, i .e., (y2007/y1998−1)×100%. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
EFF
EFFi
EFFik
GEFFi
GEFFik
low
state
25.41
36.48
26.01
-3.89
8.09
32.64
private
31.32
42.53
21.57
13.73
16.83
7.58
foreign
52.87
12.51
11.51
7.54
2.48
4.88
all
36.53
30.51
19.69
5.79
9.13
15.03
medium
state
29.34
15.27
9.13
0.84
4.45
8.08
private
35.37
53.83
21.56
10.28
28.41
13.01
foreign
66.39
33.45
31.52
30.41
2.57
1.44
all
43.70
34.18
20.73
13.84
11.81
7.51
high
state
34.03
77.01
55.62
39.61
9.13
17.58
private
49.74
26.54
20.00
20.00
4.96
0.00
foreign
80.78
10.92
9.61
0.00
1.01
9.61
all
54.85
38.15
28.41
19.87
5.03
9.06
all
state
28.26
30.77
21.17
3.22
6.45
19.14
private
35.32
46.19
21.39
12.76
21.09
9.35
foreign
62.48
22.42
20.93
17.72
2.36
3.75
all
42.02
33.13
21.16
11.23
9.97
10.75
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). EFF and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, EFF=(e2007(x2007,y2007)e1998(x1998,y1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Technology intensity
Ownership
e1998ik
e2007ik
low
state
0.893
0.861
private
0.839
0.942
foreign
0.874
0.923
all
0.869
0.909
medium
state
0.950
0.951
private
0.914
0.991
foreign
0.764
0.942
all
0.876
0.961
high
state
0.818
0.997
private
0.827
0.975
foreign
1.000
1.000
all
0.882
0.991
all
state
0.912
0.919
private
0.874
0.969
foreign
0.835
0.940
all
0.874
0.943
Note: We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
TECH
TECHi
TECHik
GTECHi
GTECHik
low
state
25.41
82.53
92.94
130.94
-3.36
-9.70
private
31.32
46.14
45.73
52.09
-0.24
-3.99
foreign
52.87
76.17
67.64
42.75
8.87
18.94
all
36.53
68.28
68.77
75.26
1.76
1.75
medium
state
29.34
61.23
45.18
66.91
8.56
-0.80
private
35.37
41.66
35.65
38.41
5.11
-0.24
foreign
66.39
89.25
77.93
66.11
5.73
7.42
all
43.70
64.05
52.92
57.14
6.46
2.13
high
state
34.03
51.82
57.39
48.70
-4.27
8.34
private
49.74
41.08
44.13
36.22
-2.05
6.24
foreign
80.78
30.41
30.77
30.88
-0.23
-0.09
all
54.85
41.10
44.10
38.60
-2.18
4.83
all
state
28.26
68.86
65.99
90.97
2.28
-3.41
private
35.32
43.42
40.70
43.74
2.13
-1.05
foreign
62.48
77.38
68.50
52.68
6.35
11.28
all
42.02
63.22
58.40
62.47
3.59
2.27
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). TECH and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, TECH=(√y2007(x1998)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y1998(x2007)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Technology intensity
Ownership
y1998
KACC
KACCi
KACCik
GKACCi
GKACCik
low
state
25.41
102.26
106.97
132.92
-0.84
-10.12
private
31.32
50.96
72.05
74.83
-9.93
-1.84
foreign
52.87
4.66
10.55
36.79
-3.78
-16.90
all
36.53
52.63
63.19
81.51
-4.85
-9.62
medium
state
29.34
264.85
280.54
310.66
-7.86
0.83
private
35.37
79.10
132.05
147.94
-20.78
-6.75
foreign
66.39
26.64
33.61
46.05
-6.63
-7.41
all
43.70
123.53
148.73
168.22
-11.76
-4.44
high
state
34.03
87.93
79.69
130.96
0.94
-17.53
private
49.74
86.34
91.49
102.01
-2.42
-5.56
foreign
80.78
63.48
64.54
74.86
-0.76
-7.29
all
54.85
79.25
78.57
102.61
-0.75
-10.13
all
state
28.26
178.95
187.51
218.28
-4.02
-5.67
private
35.32
68.44
103.10
113.05
-14.32
-4.62
foreign
62.48
21.78
27.65
45.48
-4.82
-11.26
all
42.02
89.72
106.09
125.60
-7.72
-7.18
Note: y1998 represents output per worker in 1998 (unit: 1, 000 RMB per person). KACC and related variables are evaluated over the 1998-2007 period and converted into cumulative growth rates (unit: percent). That is, KACC=(√y1998(x2007)y1998(x1998)y2007(x2007)y2007(x1998)−1)×100%, and similarly for the others. We average over all production units in the corresponding category to obtain these values.
Figure 1. Labor productivity growth versus labor productivity in 1998
Figure 2. Efficiency change versus labor productivity in 1998
Figure 3. Technology change versus labor productivity in 1998
Figure 4. Capital deepening versus labor productivity in 1998