Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article Special Issues

Enterprise financialization and R&D innovation: A case study of listed companies in China

  • Received: 19 January 2023 Revised: 14 February 2023 Accepted: 16 February 2023 Published: 02 March 2023
  • In financial asset allocation, enterprises adjust their investment in R&D innovation according to their motives and the external environment. Based on a review of the literature related to enterprise financialization and R&D innovation, this paper proposes research hypotheses through theoretical analysis first; then, taking China's A-share non-financial listed companies from 2010 to 2019 as research objects, this paper explores the relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation with a quantile panel data model; further, the heterogeneous relationship between the two under different business cycle phases is empirically analyzed. The following conclusions are drawn. First, there is a dynamic relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation, varying with different financing constraints. Second, the dynamic relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation stems from the motivation difference in enterprise asset allocation. Third, there are significant differences in the dynamic relationship at different business cycle phases.

    Citation: Yue Liu, Jinzhi Liu, Lichang Zhang. Enterprise financialization and R&D innovation: A case study of listed companies in China[J]. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(5): 2447-2471. doi: 10.3934/era.2023124

    Related Papers:

    [1] Baishuai Zuo, Chuancun Yin . Stein’s lemma for truncated generalized skew-elliptical random vectors. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(4): 3423-3433. doi: 10.3934/math.2020221
    [2] Guangshuai Zhou, Chuancun Yin . Family of extended mean mixtures of multivariate normal distributions: Properties, inference and applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(7): 12390-12414. doi: 10.3934/math.2022688
    [3] Remigijus Leipus, Jonas Šiaulys, Dimitrios Konstantinides . Minimum of heavy-tailed random variables is not heavy tailed. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(6): 13066-13072. doi: 10.3934/math.2023658
    [4] Naif Alotaibi, A. S. Al-Moisheer, Ibrahim Elbatal, Salem A. Alyami, Ahmed M. Gemeay, Ehab M. Almetwally . Bivariate step-stress accelerated life test for a new three-parameter model under progressive censored schemes with application in medical. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(2): 3521-3558. doi: 10.3934/math.2024173
    [5] Huifang Yuan, Tao Jiang, Min Xiao . The ruin probability of a discrete risk model with unilateral linear dependent claims. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(4): 9785-9807. doi: 10.3934/math.2024479
    [6] Weiwei Ni, Chenghao Xu, Kaiyong Wang . Estimations for aggregate amount of claims in a risk model with arbitrary dependence between claim sizes and inter-arrival times. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(10): 17737-17746. doi: 10.3934/math.2022976
    [7] Khaled M. Alqahtani, Mahmoud El-Morshedy, Hend S. Shahen, Mohamed S. Eliwa . A discrete extension of the Burr-Hatke distribution: Generalized hypergeometric functions, different inference techniques, simulation ranking with modeling and analysis of sustainable count data. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(4): 9394-9418. doi: 10.3934/math.2024458
    [8] Gunduz Caginalp . Fat tails arise endogenously from supply/demand, with or without jump processes. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(5): 4811-4846. doi: 10.3934/math.2021283
    [9] Hamid Reza Safaeyan, Karim Zare, Mohamadreza Mahmoudi, Mohsen Maleki, Amir Mosavi . A Bayesian approach on asymmetric heavy tailed mixture of factor analyzer. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 15837-15856. doi: 10.3934/math.2024765
    [10] Yanfang Zhang, Fuchang Wang, Yibin Zhao . Statistical characteristics of earthquake magnitude based on the composite model. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 607-624. doi: 10.3934/math.2024032
  • In financial asset allocation, enterprises adjust their investment in R&D innovation according to their motives and the external environment. Based on a review of the literature related to enterprise financialization and R&D innovation, this paper proposes research hypotheses through theoretical analysis first; then, taking China's A-share non-financial listed companies from 2010 to 2019 as research objects, this paper explores the relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation with a quantile panel data model; further, the heterogeneous relationship between the two under different business cycle phases is empirically analyzed. The following conclusions are drawn. First, there is a dynamic relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation, varying with different financing constraints. Second, the dynamic relationship between enterprise financialization and R&D innovation stems from the motivation difference in enterprise asset allocation. Third, there are significant differences in the dynamic relationship at different business cycle phases.



    One of the main challenges faced by financial companies is to evaluate market risks in a set of changes of the basic variables such as stock prices, interest rates or exchange rates. In this regard the Value-at-Risk (VaR) introduced by J. P. Morgan in the mid 1990s has become a standard risk measure of financial market risk. Despite its extensive use, the VaR is not a coherent risk measure because it fails to satisfy subadditivity property (see [1]). The VaR can not determine the expected loss of portfolio in q worst case, but it defines the minimum loss. Furthermore, the computation of the VaR is based on the assumption that financial data returns follow the normal distribution. However, as shown in the literatures, the underlying distributions of many financial data exhibit skewness, non-symmetric, heavy tails and excess kurtosis (see [10]). They suggest in particular that large losses occur with much higher probability than the normal distribution would suggest.

    The tail conditional expectation (TCE) risk measure shares properties that are considered desirable in all cases. For instance, due to the additivity of expectations, TCE allows venture capital to decompose naturally among its various components.

    Consider X to be a loss random variable whose cumulative distribution function (cdf) is denoted by FX(x). The TCE is defined as

    TCEp(X)=E(X|X>xp),p(0,1),

    where xp=inf{xR:FX(x)p}=VaRp(X). The TCE has been discussed in many literatures (see e.g., [11,12,15,17]).

    The tail conditional expectation risk measure shares properties that are considered desirable in a variety of situations. For instance, due to the additivity of expectations, TCE allows for a natural decomposition of risk capital among its various constituents. The conception of capital allocation principle has long been introduced, in which the capital allocated to each risk unit can be expressed as its contribution to the tail conditional expectation of total risk. Risk allocation can not only help to evaluate and compare the performance of individual risk units, but also help to understand the risk contribution of each unit towards the total risk of the portfolio. Landsman and Valdez [17] derived the portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the multivariate elliptical distribution. In [18], authors derived the portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the exponential dispersion model, and Kim [14] for the exponential family class. The allocation for the class of exponential marginal was developed in []. The portfolio risk decomposition with TCE was further considered in [19] for the skew-normal distribution. Furman and Landsman [16] for the multivariate Gamma distribution. Cai and Li [2] for the phase-type distribution. Goovaerts et al. [9] and Chiragiev and Landsman [4] have provided the TCE-capital allocation for the multivariate Pareto distribution while Cossette et al. [5] have considered multivariate compound distribution. Ignatieva and Landsman [12] for generalized hyperbolic distribution. Recently, Kim and Kim [15] and Ignatieva and Landsman [12] investigated the TCE allocation for the family of multivariate normal mean-variance mixture distributions and skewed generalized hyperbolic, respectively. The univariate TCE and risk allocation formula for the generalized hyper-elliptical class were available in [13].

    Furman and Landsman [8] observed that in many cases the TCE does not provide adequate information about the risks on the right tail. This point can be confirmed by the fact that the TCE does not include the information that the risk deviates from the upper tail expectation. Furman and Landsman [8] introduced the tail variance measure. The tail variance is defined as

    TVp(X)=Var(X|X>xp)=E((XTCEp(X))2|X>xp),

    and it has been discussed in many literatures (see e.g., [8,15]).

    In this paper we consider a class of multivariate location-scale mixtures of elliptical (LSME) distributions which is known to be extremely flexible and contains many special cases as its members. Examples include the generalized hyper-elliptical distribution and generalized hyperbolic distribution.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the definition and properties of the multivariate LSME class, and introduces the generalized hyper-elliptical distribution as a representative subclass. Section 3 presents a theorem and proves the proposed TCE formula for the LSME and in Section 4, the development is extended to the portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the multivariate LSME. In Section 5, we develop TV formula for univariate LSME. Section 6 deals with the special case of generalized hyperbolic distribution. Numercial illustration is presented in Section 7. Finally, concluding remarks are presented in Section 8.

    In this section, we introduce the class of location-scale mixtures of elliptical distributions and some of its properties.

    Let Ψn be a class of functions ψ(t):[0,)R such that function ψ(ni=1t2i) is an n-dimensional characteristic function.

    A random vector Y is said to have a multivariate elliptical distribution, denoted by YEn(μ,Σ,ψ), if its characteristic function can be expressed as

    φY(t)=exp(itTμ)ψ(12tTΣt), (2.1)

    for column-vector vector μ, n×n positive definite scale matrix Σ, and for function ψ(t)Ψn, which is called the characteristic generator.

    In general, a multivariate elliptical distribution may not have a probability density function (pdf), but if its pdf exists then the form will be

    fY(y)=cn|Σ|gn[12(yμ)TΣ1(yμ)], (2.2)

    for function gn(), which is called the density generator. The condition

    0un21gn(u)du< (2.3)

    guarantees gn(u) to be the density generator ([7]). In addition, the normalizing constant cn is

    cn=Γ(n2)(2π)n2(0un21gn(u)du)1.

    Similarly, the elliptical distribution can also be introduced by the density generator and then written YEn(μ,Σ,gn).

    From (2.1), it follows that, if YEn(μ,Σ,gn) and A is m×n matrix of rank mn and b is m-dimensional column-vector, then

    AY+bEm(Aμ+b,AΣAT,gm).

    The following condition:

    0g1(u)du<

    guarantees the existence of the mean. If, in addition, |ψ(0)|<, the covariance matrix exists and is equal to

    Cov(Y)=ψ(0)Σ,

    (see [3]).

    From (2.2) and (2.3), g1(x) can be a density generator of univariate elliptical distribution of the random variable YE1(μ,σ2,g1) whose pdf can be expressed as

    fY(y)=cσg1(12(yμσ)2),

    where c is the normalizing constant. In this paper, we assume

    Var(Z)=σ2Z<, (2.4)

    where Z=Yμσ is the spherical random variable. The cdf of the random variable Z can be written as the following integration form:

    FZ(z)=czg1(12u2)du.

    We can obtain the mean and variance of Z:

    μZ=0

    and

    σ2Z=2c0u2g1(12u2)du=ψ(0).

    Landsman and Valdez [17] showed that

    fZ(z)=1σ2Z¯G(12z2) (2.5)

    is the density of another spherical random variable Z associated with Z, where

    ¯G(z)=zg1(u)du.

    The random vector X LSME n(μ,Σ,γ,gn;Π) has an n-dimensional LSME distribution with location parameter μ, positive definite scale matrix Σ, if

    X=m(Θ)+Θ12Σ12Y, (2.6)

    in distribution, where

    (1) YEn(0,In,gn), the n-dimensional multivariate elliptical variable;

    (2) Non-negative scalar random variable Θ is independent of Y, whose pdf and cdf are π(θ) and Π(θ) respectively;

    (3) m(Θ)=μ+Θγ, where μ=(μ1,,μn)Tandγ=(γ1,,γn)T are constant vectors in Rn.

    The pdf of the LSME can be written as the following integration form:

    fX(x)=cn|Σ|01θgn(12θ(xμθγ)TΣ1(xμθγ))π(θ)dθ,xRn.

    We find that the conditional distribution of X|θ is elliptical, that is

    X|Θ=θEn(m(θ),θΣ,gn). (2.7)

    We can obtain the mean and covariance of X:

    E(X)=E[E(X|Θ)]=E(m(Θ))=μ+E(Θ)γ

    and

    Cov(X)=E[Var(X|Θ)]+Var[E(X|Θ)]=E(ΘΣ)+Var(m(Θ))=E(Θ)Σ+Var(Θ)γγT.

    The characteristic function of X|Θ=θ exists and equals to

    φX(t|Θ=θ)=exp(itTμ)exp(iθtTγ)ψ(12θtTΣt).

    Then the characteristic function of the LSME-distributed random vector X can be written as

    φX(t)=exp(itTμ)E[exp(iθtTγ)ψ(12θtTΣt)]=exp(itTμ)0exp(iθtTγ)ψ(12θtTΣt)π(θ)dθ. (2.8)

    Under the condition (2.2) and from (2.5), we can conclude ¯G(z) is the density generator of the associated elliptical variable Z, then

    X=m(Θ)+ΘσZ (2.9)

    is said to have a univariate LSME distributions, denoted by XLSME1(μ,σ2,γ,Θ,¯G;Π).

    Proposition 1. If XLSMEn(μ,Σ,γ,gn;Π) and Y=BX+b where B is m×n (mn) matrix and b is m-dimensional column-vector, then it holds that YLSMEm(Bμ+b,BΣBT,Bγ,gm;Π).

    Proof. Using the characteristic function (2.8), we write

    φY(t)=E(eitT(BX+b))=exp(itTb)φX(BTt)=exp(itTb)exp(i(BTt)Tμ)0exp(iθ(BTt)Tγ)ψ(12θ(BTt)TΣ(BTt))π(θ)dθ=exp(itT(Bμ+b))0exp(iθtTBγ)ψ(12θtTBΣBTt)π(θ)dθ, (2.10)

    i.e., YLSMEm(Bμ+b,BΣBT,Bγ,gm;Π).

    Example2.1 (Generalized hyper-elliptical distribution). The GHE distribution is constructed by mixing a generalized inverse Gaussian distribution with elliptical distribution. A positive random variable Θ is said to have a generalized inverse Gaussian distribution, denoted by ΘGIG(λ,a,b), if its pdf is given by

    π(θ;λ,a,b)=aλ(ab)λ2Kλ(ab)θλ1exp(12(aθ1+bθ)),θ>0, (2.11)

    where parameters follow

    {a0andb>0,ifλ>0,a>0andb0,ifλ<0,a>0andb>0,ifλ=0

    and Kλ() denotes the modified Bessel function of the second kind with index λR. A random vector XGHEn(μ,Σ,γ,gn,λ,a,b) has an n-dimensional GHE distribution, if there exists a random vector Y follows (2.6) such that

    X=m(Θ)+Θ12Σ12Y, (2.12)

    where ΘGIG(λ,a,b).

    The univariate LSME variable is given by n=1 in the multivariate definition. That is, the univariate LSME variable XLSME1(μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π) satisfies

    X=m(Θ)+ΘσZ,

    where ZE1(0,1,g1) is the standard elliptical variable, and non-negative scalar random variable Θ with pdf π(θ) is independent of Z. From (2.7), we have

    X|θE1(m(θ),θσ2,g1). (3.1)

    Assuming that both the conditional distribution and the mixed distribution are continuous, the pdf of X produced by the mixed distribution can be written as

    fX(x)=Ωθf(x|θ)π(θ)dθ, (3.2)

    where f(x|θ) is the pdf of X|θ and Ωθ is the support of π(θ). Now let xp be the quantile of the LSME variable X. Then the TCE of X can be expressed as

    E(X|X>xp)=11pxpxfX(x)dx=11pΩθxpxf(x|θ)dxπ(θ)dθ=11pΩθEX|θ(X|X>xp)¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ. (3.3)

    The TCE formula for a univariate elliptical distribution is introduced by [17], and equals to

    TCEp(X|θ)=EX|θ(X|X>xp)=m(θ)+1θσfZ(κ(xp;θ))¯FZ(κ(xp;θ))σ2Zθσ2=m(θ)+1θσfZ(κ(xp;θ))¯FZ(κ(xp;θ))Var(X|θ), (3.4)

    where

    κ(x;θ)=xm(θ)θσ.

    We now give a general TCE formula for the univariate LSME distributions.

    Theorem 1. Let XLSME1(μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π) and π(θ)=(c)1θπ(θ) be a mixing pdf with c=E(Θ)<. Then the TCE of X can be computed by:

    E(X|X>xp)=μ+γc1p¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+cσ2σ2Z1pfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π), (3.5)

    where Π is the cdf corresponding to the pdf π.

    Proof. From (3.3) and (3.4), we have

    E(X|X>xp)=11p0[m(θ)+1θσfZ(κ(xp;θ))¯FZ(κ(xp;θ))Var(X|θ)]¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ=11pxp0m(θ)θσfZ(κ(x;θ))π(θ)dθdx+σ2σ2Z1p0fZ(κ(xp;θ))θσθπ(θ)dθ=11pxpμf(x)dx+γ1pxp0f(x|θ)θπ(θ)dθdx+σ2σ2Z1p0fZ(κ(xp;θ))θσθπ(θ)dθ. (3.6)

    From the definition of LSME distributions and (3.2), we have

    0f(x|θ)θπ(θ)dθ=c0f(x|θ)π(θ)dθ=cfLSME,1(x;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π).

    As a result, (3.6) can be further simplified

    E(X|X>xp)=μ+γc1pxp0f(x|θ)π(θ)dθdx+cσ2σ2Z1p0fZ(κ(xp;θ))θσπ(θ)dθ=μ+γc1pxpfLSME,1(x;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)dx+cσ2σ2Z1p0fZ(κ(xp;θ))θσπ(θ)dθ=μ+γc1p¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+cσ2σ2Z1pfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π).

    Corollary 1. Let XGHE1(μ,σ2,γ,g1,λ,a,b). Assume the conditions in Theorem 1 are satisfied, then the TCE of GHE can be computed by:

    TCEp(X)=μ+γ1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1,λ+1,a,b)+σ2σ2Z1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G,λ+1,a,b). (3.7)

    Proof. From the GIG density in (2.11), we conclude

    θπ(θ;λ,a,b)=abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)π(θ;λ+1,a,b),

    by setting

    c=abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab),

    then

    π(θ)=(c)1θπ(θ)=π(θ;λ+1,a,b),

    which also is the GIG density. Using (3.5) we can directly obtain (3.7).

    Consider a risk vector Y=(Y1,,Yn)T and S=Y1++Yn. We denote sp as the p-quantile of S, then

    E(S|S>sp)=ni=1E(Yi|S>sp),

    where E(Yi|S>sp) is the contribution of the i-th risk to the aggregated risks.

    Let Y=(Y1,,Yn)En(μ,Σ,gn) and S=Y1++Yn, then ([6])

    E(Yi|S=s)=yif(yi|s)dyi=E(Yi)+Cov(Yi,S)Var(S)(sE(S)).

    The contribution of risk Yi,1in, to the total TCE can be expressed as

    E(Yi|S>sp)=spE(Yi|S=s)dFS(s|S>sp)=spE(Yi|S=s)fS(s)1FS(sp)ds=11pspE(Yi|S=s)fS(s)ds.

    We now exploit this formulation to the multivariate LSME to obtain its portfolio risk decomposition with TCE.

    Let us assume X=(X1,,Xn)TLSMEn(μ,Σ,γ,gn;Π). Denote the (i,j) element of Σ by σij, define

    S=X1++Xn.

    Then, E(Xi|S=s) can be further expanded by conditioning on θ as follows:

    E(Xi|S=s)=xif(xi|s)dxi=xif(xis)dxifS(s)=1fS(s)xi0f(xi,s|θ)dπ(θ)dxi=1fS(s)xi0f(xi|s,θ)f(s|θ)π(θ)dθdxi=1fS(s)0[xif(xi|s,θ)dxi]f(s|θ)π(θ)dθ. (4.1)

    To deal with the inner integral, we define a matrix Bi of size 2×n:

    Bi=[000100111]. (4.2)

    The first row vector has 1 in the ith position. If we keep the general form

    m(θ)=(m1(θ),,mn(θ))T,

    we have

    BiX|θ=(Xi,S|θ)T=Bim(θ)+θ12BiΣ12Y,

    here (Xi,S|θ)T stands for a random column vector of size 2×1, with each element being Xi|θ and S|θ, respectively. Thus, the joint distribution of (Xi,S) under the condition of Θ=θ is a bivariate elliptical distribution

    (Xi,S|θ)TE2(Bim(θ),θBiΣBTi,g2),

    where the mean vector and convariance matrix of (Xi,S|θ) are given by

    E(BiX|θ)=Bim(θ)=(E(Xi|θ),E(S|θ))T=[mi(θ)nj=1mj(θ)],
    Cov(BiX|θ)=ψ(0)θBiΣBTi=ψ(0)[θσiiθnj=1σijθnj=1σijθσ2S],

    where

    σ2S=1TΣ1=ni=1nj=1σij.

    Therefore, if we impose another condition on S, we see that f(xi|s,θ) is an elliptical density. In particular

    xif(xi|s,θ)dxi=E(Xi|S=s,Θ=θ)=E(Xi|θ)+Cov(Xi,S|θ)Var(S|θ)(sE(S|θ))=mi(θ)+ψ(0)nj=1σijψ(0)σ2S(snj=1mj(θ))=mi(θ)+dj=1σijσ2S(snj=1mj(θ)).

    Consequently

    E(Xi|S=s)=1fS(s)0[xif(xi|s,θ)dxi]f(s|θ)π(θ)dθ=1fS(s)0[mi(θ)+nj=1σijσ2S(snj=1mj(θ))]×1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθ. (4.3)

    Eventually

    E(Xi|S>sp)=11pspE(Xi|S=s)fS(s)ds=11psp0[mi(θ)+nj=1σijσ2S(snj=1mj(θ))]×1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθds. (4.4)

    This expression, though complex, can produce a closed-form quantity to properly select π(θ) and mj(θ).

    The portfolio risk decomposition with TCE is additive, that is, the sum of all portfolio risk decomposition must amount to the TCE for S. We can verify this

    ni=1E(Xi|S>sp)=11pni=1sp0[mi(θ)+nj=1σijσ2S(snj=1mj(θ))]1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθds=11psp0[ni=1mi(θ)+ni=1nj=1σijσ2S(snj=1mj(θ))]1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθds=11psp0[ni=1mi(θ)+(snj=1mj(θ))]1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθds=11psp0s1θσSfZ(snj=1mj(θ)θσS)π(θ)dθds=E(S|S>sp),

    as required. Now the general portfolio risk decomposition with TCE formula for the multivariate LSME distributions class in presented is a more concrete and compact manner when m(θ) is linear in θ.

    Theorem 2. Let X=(X1,X2,,Xn)TLSMEn(μ,Σ,γ,gn;Π) and denote the pdf of S=1TX by fS(s). Let π(θ)=(c)1θπ(θ) be a mixing pdf with c=E(Θ)<.

    Then the portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the i-th marginal variable is given by

    E(Xi|S>sp)=b0,i+b1,iE(S|S>sp)+b2,i1pc¯FLSME,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1;Π), (4.5)

    where Π is the cdf corresponding to the pdf π, the coefficients b0,i,b1,i, and b2,i are defined as

    b0,i=μib1,inj=1μj;b1,i=nj=1σijσ2S;b2,i=γib1,inj=1γj,

    and sp is the p-quantile of S.

    Proof. Let mi(θ)=μi+θγi, and from (4.3) we have

    E(Xi|S=s)=1fS(s)0[μi+nj=1σijσ2S(snj=1μj)+(γinj=1γjnj=1σijσ2S)θ]×1θσSfZ(snj=1μjθnj=1γjθσS)π(θ)dθ=1fS(s)0[b0,i+b1,is+b2,iθ]1θσSfZ(snj=1μjθnj=1γjθσS)π(θ)dθ=1fS(s)[b0,ifS(s)+b1,isfS(s)+b2,icfLSME,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1;Π)]=b0,i+b1,is+b2,icfLSME,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1;Π)fS(s).

    By inserting this into the portfolio risk decomposition with TCE formulation (4.4), we complete the proof as

    E(Xi|S>sp)=spE(Xi|S=s)f(s|S>sp)ds=spE(Xi|S=s)fS(s)1pds=11psp(b0,i+b1,is)fS(s)ds+11pb2,icspfLSME,1(s;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1;Π)ds=b0,i+b1,iE(S|S>sp)+b2,i1pc¯FLSME,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1;Π). (4.6)

    Notice that ni=1b0,i=0,ni=1b1,i=1, and ni=1b2,i=0, which can be used to verify that the sum of these portfolio risk decomposition amounts to E(S|S>sp).

    Corollary 2. Let X=(X1,X2,,Xn)TGHEn(μ,Σ,γ,gn,λ,a,b). The portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the i-th marginal variable is given by

    E(Xi|S>sp)=μi+σ2Znj=1σij1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,¯G;λ+1,a,b)+γi1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1,λ+1,a,b). (4.7)

    Proof. We can know SGHE1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1,λ+1,a,b) by using Proposition 1. Using (4.5), we see that TCE of S is given by

    E(S|S>sp)=μi+σ2Znj=1σij1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,¯G,λ+1,a,b)+γi1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1,λ+1,a,b).

    Therefore

    E(Xi|S>sp)=μi+b1,iσ2Sσ2Z1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,¯G,λ+1,a,b)+γi1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1,λ+1,a,b)=μi+σ2Znj=1σij1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,¯G,λ+1,a,b)+γi1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,g1,λ+1,a,b).

    The TV of the univariate elliptical distribution is introduced by [8]. From (3.1), We can write the TV for X|θ as

    TVp(X|θ)=Var(X|θ)[r(κ(xp;θ))+hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))(κ(xp;θ)hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))σ2Z)],

    where κ(x;θ) is the same as in (3.4),

    r(z)=¯FZ(z)¯FZ(z)

    is the distorted ratio function, and

    hZ,Z(z)=fZ(z)¯FZ(z)

    is the distorted hazard function.

    TV can be rewritten as:

    TVp(X)=Var(X|X>xp)=E[(XTCEp(X))2|X>xp]=E(X2|X>xp)[TCEp(X)]2. (5.1)

    Consequently, we need to derive the second order conditional tail moment E(X2|X>xp). We now provide its analytic expression in the following result.

    Proposition 2. Assume a random variable XLSME1(μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π). Let π(θ)=(c)1θπ(θ) and π(θ)=(c)1θ2π(θ) be two different mixing pdfs with c=E(Θ)< and c=E(Θ2)< respectively. Then

    E(X2|X>xp)=σ2σ2Z1p[(xp+μ)cfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+γcfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+c¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)]+γ1p[2μc¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+γc¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)]+μ2, (5.2)

    where Π and Π are two cdfs corresponding to the two different pdfs π and π, respectively.

    Proof. From observing

    E(X2|X>xp)=11pxpx2fX(x)dx=11p0xpx2fX|θ(x)π(θ)dxdθ=11p0EX|θ(X2|X>xp)¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ.

    To deal with the second order conditional tail moment in the integration, we write it as

    EX|θ(X2|X>xp)=TVp(X|θ)+[TCEp(X|θ)]2. (5.3)

    From [17], we know

    TCEp(X|θ)=m(θ)+hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))Var(X|θ)θσ,

    taking Var(X|θ)=θσ2σ2Z into consideration, then (5.3) becomes

    EX|θ(X2|X>xp)=Var(X|θ)[r(κ(xp;θ))+hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))(κ(xp;θ)hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))σ2Z)]+(m(θ)+hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))Var(X|θ)θσ)2=Var(X|θ)r(κ(xp;θ))+Var(X|θ)hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))xpm(θ)θσVar(X|θ)(hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ)))2σ2Z+m2(θ)+2m(θ)hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))Var(X|θ)θσ+(hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ)))2θσ2σ2ZVar(X|θ)θσ2=m2(θ)+Var(X|θ)(r(κ(xp;θ))+hZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))xp+m(θ)θσ).

    As a result

    E(X2|X>xp)=11p0EX|θ(X2|X>xp)¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ=11p0Var(X|θ)[xp+m(θ)θσhZ,Z(κ(xp;θ))+r(κ(xp;θ))]ׯFX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ+11p0m2(θ)¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)dθ=11p0Var(X|θ)[xp+m(θ)θσfZ(κ(xp;θ))+¯FZ(κ(xp;θ))]×π(θ)dθ+11p0¯FX|θ(xp)π(θ)(μ2+2μθγ+θ2γ2)dθ=σ2σ2Z1p[(xp+μ)cfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+γcfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+c¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)]+γ1p[2μc¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+γc¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)]+μ2.

    Theorem 3. Under assumptions of Proposition 2, the TV of X is given by

    TVp(X)=σ2σ2Z1p[(xpμ)cfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+γcfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)+c¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)]+γ21pc¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)(c1p)2[γ¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+σ2σ2ZfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π)]2, (5.4)

    where Π and Π are two cdfs corresponding to the two different pdfs π and π, respectively.

    Proof. From the Theorem 1, the TCE formula is

    E(X|X>xp)=μ+γc1p¯FLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1;Π)+cσ2σ2Z1pfLSME,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;Π).

    Hence, the result can be derived by using Proposition 2 and (5.1).

    Corollary 3. Let XGHE1(μ,σ2,γ,g1,λ,a,b). Assume the conditions in Theorem 3 are satisfied, then the TV for GHE can be computed by:

    TVp(X)=σ2σ2Z1p[(xpμ)abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;λ+1,a,b)+γabKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab)fGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;λ+2,a,b)+abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;λ+1,a,b)]+γ21pabKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1,λ+2,a,b)(11pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab))2[γ¯FGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,g1,λ+1,a,b)+σ2σ2ZfGHE,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,¯G;λ+1,a,b)]2. (5.5)

    Proof. From the GIG density in (2.11), we conclude

    θπ(θ;λ,a,b)=abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)π(θ;λ+1,a,b)

    and

    θ2π(θ;λ,a,b)=abKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab)π(θ;λ+2,a,b).

    By setting

    c=abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab),c=abKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab),

    the two pdfs can be presented as

    π(θ)=(c)1θπ(θ)=π(θ;λ+1,a,b)

    and

    π(θ)=(c)1θ2π(θ)=π(θ;λ+2,a,b),

    which also are two GIG pdfs. Using (5.4) we can directly obtain (5.5).

    Example6.1 (Generalized hyperbolic distribution). If μ=0, Σ=In and density generator g(u)=eu in (2.2), then the elliptical vector Y is said to have a multivariate normal distribution, denoted by YNn(0,In). Letting YNn(0,In) in (2.6), then the random vector XGHn(μ,Σ,γ,λ,a,b) is an n-dimensional generalized hyperbolic (GH) distribution. Therefore, the pdf of the GH distribution is (see [15])

    fGHn(x,μ,Σ,γ,λ,a,b)=cKλ(n/2)((a+(xμ)TΣ1(xμ))(b+γTΣ1γ))e(xμ)TΣ1γ(a+(xμ)TΣ1(xμ))(b+γTΣ1γ))n4λ2,

    where the normalizing constant is

    c=(ab)λ2bλ(b+γTΣ1γ)(n/2)λ(2π)n/2|Σ|1/2Kλab.

    From Corollary 1, TCE of GH distribution is given by

    TCEp(X)=μ+γ1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b)+σ21pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b).

    From Corollary 2, portfolio risk decomposition with TCE for the i-th marginal of GH distribution is given by

    E(Xi|S>sp)=μi+nj=1σij1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGH,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,λ+1,a,b)+γi1pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGH,1(sp;1Tμ,1TΣ1,1Tγ,λ+1,a,b).

    From Corollary 3, TV of GH distribution is given by

    TVp(X)=σ21p[(xpμ)abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)fGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b)+γabKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab)fGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+2,a,b)+abKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b)]+γ21pabKλ+2(ab)Kλ(ab)¯FGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+2,a,b)(11pabKλ+1(ab)Kλ(ab))2[γ¯FGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b)+σ2fGH,1(xp;μ,σ2,γ,λ+1,a,b)]2.

    In this section we discuss the TV of five stocks (Amazon, Goldman Sachs, IBM, Google, and Apple) and aggregate portfolio covering a time frame from the 1st of January 2015 to the 1st of January 2017. Ignatieva and Landsman [12] fitted a GH model to five stocks and aggregate portfolio, and obtained the following parameter set based on the maximum likelihood technique.

    λ=1.18336,a=1.272016,ψ=0.348483,μ=(0.099770.045550.093550.036690.10367),γ=(0.086260.008030.079280.052300.08534),
    Σ=(3.3871.4071.1031.8281.3541.4073.0141.2881.2091.4341.1031.2881.8701.0611.1551.8281.2091.0612.1711.2201.3541.4341.1551.2202.891).

    For the risk analysis, we denote five stocks as X1,,X5. We also consider aggregate portfolio S where each stock has equal weight for simplicity, so that the aggregate portfolio is defined as S=X1++X5. Figure 1 shows the densities for five stocks Xi,i=1,,5 and aggregate portfolio S. The pdf of S has the largest variance, and Amazon has the largest dispersion among five stocks. IBM has the smallest dispersion. Figure 2 presents the TV for five stocks Xi,i=1,,5 and aggregate portfolio S. All the risk measures increase over the quantile with the TV. Also Figure 2 shows the differences in the TV measure along with five stocks and aggregate portfolio. For the same quantile, the TV of Apple is the largest one and the TV of IBM is the smallest one among the five stocks.

    Figure 1.  Densities for Xi, i=1,,5 and S for GH.
    Figure 2.  TV for Xi, i=1,,5 and S for GH.

    In this paper we generalize the tail risk measure and portfolio risk decomposition with TCE formula derived by [15] for the class of multivariate normal mean-variance mixture distributions to the larger class of multivariate elliptical location-scale mixtures distributions. A prominent member in the normal mean-variance mixture class is the generalized hyperbolic (GH) distribution, which itself can construct a Lˊevy process. The GH is a special case of normal mean-variance mixture random variable with XNn(0,In) and the distribution of Θ given by a generalized inverse Gaussian (GIG) distribution with three parameters (see [12,15] for details). Prominent member in the elliptical location-scale mixtures class is the generalized hyper-elliptical (GHE) distribution. The GHE distribution provides excellent fit to univariate and multivariate data, allowing to capture a long right tail in the distribution of losses even more effectively than the GH distribution considered in [12]. And GHE is a special case of elliptical location-scale mixtures random variable with XNn(0,In) and the distribution of Θ given by a generalized inverse Gaussian (GIG) distribution with three parameters. Although the univariate TCE and portfolio risk decomposition with TCE formula for the GHE class was available in [13], it can be derived more efficiently and seen as a special case of TCE for the unified location-scale mixtures of elliptical distributions and risk allocation formula in Theorems 1 and 2, respectively. And the univariate TV formula for the GHE class can be derived efficiently and seen as a special case of TV for the unified location-scale mixtures of elliptical distributions in Theorem 3.

    The research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 12071251).

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.



    [1] J. M. Keynes, The General Theory of Interest, Employment and Money, (2018), 152–180. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-70344-2
    [2] Z. Y. Xiao, L. Lin, Financialization, life cycle and persistent innovation: an empirical research based on the industrial difference, J. Finance Econ., 45 (2019), 43–57. https://doi.org/10.16538/j.cnki.jfe.2019.08.003 doi: 10.16538/j.cnki.jfe.2019.08.003
    [3] H. B. Huang, S. P. Zhai, J. N. Chen, Corporate life cycle, financing methods and financing constraints—based on the moderating effect research of investor sentiment, J. Financ. Res., 07 (2016), 96–112.
    [4] M. Yan, The modern corporation and private property, in Encyclopedia of Sustainable Management, Springer, Cham, 2020. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-02006-4_428-1
    [5] Z. Li, F. Zou, B. Mo, Does mandatory CSR disclosure affect enterprise total factor productivity, Economic Res.-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 35 (2022), 4902–4921. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2021.2019596 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2021.2019596
    [6] Y. Liu, P. Failler, L. M. Chen, Can mandatory disclosure policies promote corporate environmental responsibility?—Quasi-natural experimental research on China, Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health, 18 (2021), 6033. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18116033 doi: 10.3390/ijerph18116033
    [7] Y. Liu, P. Failler, Y. Ding, Enterprise financialization and technological innovation: Mechanism and heterogeneity, PLoS ONE, 17 (2022), e0275461. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0275461 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0275461
    [8] Y. Z. Wang, M. Song, Macroeconomic uncertainty, demand for financing and corporate investment, Econ. Res. J., 49 (2014), 4–17.
    [9] Z. Li, J. Zhong, Impact of economic policy uncertainty shocks on China's financial conditions, Financ. Res. Lett., 35 (2020), 101303. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2019.101303 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.101303
    [10] Z. Li, G. Liao, K. Albitar, Does corporate environmental responsibility engagement affect firm value? The mediating role of corporate innovation, Bus. Strategy Environ., 29 (2020), 1045–1055. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.2416 doi: 10.1002/bse.2416
    [11] R. U. Khan, H. Arif, N. E. Sahar, A. Ali, M. A. Abbasi, The role of financial resources in SMEs' financial and environmental performance; the mediating role of green innovation, Green Finance, 4 (2022), 36–53. https://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2022002 doi: 10.3934/GF.2022002
    [12] Z. Yang, F. Liu, H. J. Wang, Are corporate financial assets allocated for capital reserve or speculative purpose, Manage. Rev., 29 (2017), 13–25+34. https://doi.org/10.14120/j.cnki.cn11-5057/f.2017.02.002 doi: 10.14120/j.cnki.cn11-5057/f.2017.02.002
    [13] Z. H. Huang, X. Li, S. L. Chen, Financial speculation or capital investment? Evidence from relationship between corporate financialization and green technology innovation, Front. Environ. Sci-Switz., 8 (2021). https://doi.org/10.3389/FENVS.2020.614101 doi: 10.3389/FENVS.2020.614101
    [14] R. Duchin, T. Gilbert, J. Harford, C. Hrdlicka, Precautionary savings with risky assets: When cash is not cash, J. Finance, 72 (2017), 793–852. https://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12490 doi: 10.1111/jofi.12490
    [15] Y. M. Hu, X. T. Wang, J. Zhang, The Motivation for financial asset allocation: Reservoir or substitution?—Evidence from Chinese listed companies, Econ. Res. J., 52 (2017), 181–194.
    [16] W. F. Xu, Q. S. Ruan, G. D. Wang, External environmental risk perception of private entrepreneurs and innovation investment of enterprises, Sci. Res. Manage., 42 (2021), 160–171. https://doi.org/10.19571/j.cnki.1000-2995.2021.03.016 doi: 10.19571/j.cnki.1000-2995.2021.03.016
    [17] O. Sukharev, E. Voronchikhina, Financial and non-financial investments: Comparative econometric analysis of the impact on economic dynamics, Quant. Finance Econ., 4 (2020), 382–411. https://doi.org/10.3934/qfe.2020018 doi: 10.3934/qfe.2020018
    [18] M. X. Wang, L. Li, H. Y. Lan, The measurement and analysis of technological innovation diffusion in China's manufacturing industry, Natl. Account. Rev., 3 (2021), 452–471. https://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2021024 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021024
    [19] M. Q. Sheng, S. Wang, Y. P. Shang, Financial assets allocation and entity enterprises' total factor productivity: "integration of industrial—finance capital" or "removing reality to virtual", Finance Trade Res., 10 (2018), 87–97. https://doi.org/10.19337/j.cnki.34-1093/f.2018.10.008 doi: 10.19337/j.cnki.34-1093/f.2018.10.008
    [20] Z. Liu, X. Li, X. Peng, Green or nongreen innovation? Different strategic preferences among subsidized enterprises with different ownership types, J. Clean Prod., 245 (2020), 118786. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.118786 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.118786
    [21] L. W. Cheng, X. Y. Dai, The distribution of R&D investment and influence factors of R&D intensity based on 300,000 industrial enterprises' panel data in China, China Soft Sci., 8 (2012), 152–165.
    [22] Y. Liu, C. Ma, Z. Huang, Can the digital economy improve green total factor productivity? An empirical study based on Chinese urban data, Math. Biosci. Eng., 20 (2023), 6866–6893. https://doi.org/10.3934/mbe.2023296 doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023296
    [23] H. F. Gu, H. H. Zhang, Enterprise financialization, financing constraints and corporate innovation mediating effect of monetary policy, Mod. Econ. Sci., 42 (2020), 74–89.
    [24] G. Desalegn, A. Tangl, Forecasting green financial innovation and its implications for financial performance in Ethiopian Financial Institutions: Evidence from ARIMA and ARDL model, Natl. Account. Rev., 4 (2022), 95–111. https://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2022006 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022006
    [25] P. Z. Liu, Y. M. Zhao, J. N. Zhu, C. Y. Yang. Technological industry agglomeration, green innovation efficiency, and development quality of city cluster, Green Finance, 4 (2022), 411–435. https://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2022020 doi: 10.3934/GF.2022020
    [26] Z. Li, C. Yang, Z. Huang, How does the fintech sector react to signals from central bank digital currencies? Finance Res. Lett., 50 (2022), 103308. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103308 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2022.103308
    [27] J. Atta-Mensah, Commodity-linked bonds as an innovative financing instrument for African countries to build back better, Quant. Finance Econ., 5 (2021), 516–541. https://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2021023 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021023
    [28] T. I. Palley, Financialization: What It Is and Why It Matters, Levy Economics Institute Working Paper No. 525. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1077923
    [29] Y. Su, Z. Li, C. Yang, Spatial interaction spillover effects between digital financial technology and urban ecological efficiency in China: An empirical study based on spatial simultaneous equations, Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health, 18 (2021), 8535. https://doi.org/10.3390/IJERPH18168535 doi: 10.3390/IJERPH18168535
    [30] Z. Li, H. Chen, B. Mo, Can digital finance promote urban innovation? Evidence from China, Borsa Istanbul Rev., 11 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2022.10.006 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2022.10.006
    [31] Y. Liu, P. Failler, Z. Liu, Impact of environmental regulations on energy efficiency: A case study of China's air pollution prevention and control action plan, Sustainability, 14 (2022), 3168. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063168 doi: 10.3390/su14063168
    [32] Z. Huang, H. Dong, S. Jia, Equilibrium pricing for carbon emission in response to the target of carbon emission peaking, Energy Econ. 112 (2022), 106160. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2022.106160 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2022.106160
    [33] F. Demir, Financial liberalization, private investment and portfolio choice: Financialization of real sectors in emerging markets, J. Dev. Econ., 88 (2009), 314–324. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.04.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.04.002
    [34] J. Song, Y. Lu, U-shape relationship between non-currency financial assets and operating profit: Evidence from financialization of Chinese listed non-financial corporates, J. Financ. Res., 6 (2015), 111–127.
    [35] G. C. Liu, Financial asset allocations and the firms' R&D activity in China: Crowding-out or crowding-in, Stat. Res., 34 (2017), 49–61. https://doi.org/10.19343/j.cnki.11-1302/c.2017.07.005 doi: 10.19343/j.cnki.11-1302/c.2017.07.005
    [36] H. J. Wang, Y. Q. Cao, Q. Yang, Z. Yang, Does the financialization of non-financial enterprises promote or inhibit corporate innovation, Nankai Bus. Rev., 20 (2017), 155–166. https://doi.org/10.3969/j.issn.1008-3448.2017.01.014 doi: 10.3969/j.issn.1008-3448.2017.01.014
    [37] M. Xu, K. Albitar, Z. Li, Does corporate financialization affect EVA? Early evidence from China, Green Finance, 2 (2020), 392–408. https://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2020021 doi: 10.3934/GF.2020021
    [38] M. Hong, B. Drakeford, K. Zhang, The impact of mandatory CSR disclosure on green innovation: evidence from China, Green Finance, 2 (2020), 302–322. https://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2020017 doi: 10.3934/GF.2020017
    [39] Z. Li, F. Zou, B. Mo, Does mandatory CSR disclosure affect enterprise total factor productivity, Econ. Res-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 35 (2021), 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2021.2019596 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2021.2019596
    [40] A. F. Burns, W. C. Mitchell, Measuring Business Cycles, NBER, 1946.
    [41] F. Q. Shi, Empirical analysis of China's business cycle, Stat. Res., 7 (2000), 59–62.
    [42] Y. Liu, Z. Li, M. Xu, The influential factors of financial cycle spillover: Evidence from China, Emerging Mark. Finance Trade, 56 (2020), 1336–1350. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496x.2019.1658076 doi: 10.1080/1540496x.2019.1658076
    [43] Z. Du, Y. Li, G. Lv, Evaluating the nonlinear relationship between nonfinancial corporate sector leverage and financial stability in the post crisis era, AIMS Math., 7 (2022), 20178–20198. https://10.3934/math.20221104 doi: 10.3934/math.20221104
    [44] B. Bernanke, M. Gertler, Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations, Am. Econ. Rev., 79 (1989), 14–31.
    [45] T. Li, X. Li, G. Liao, Business cycles and energy intensity. Evidence from emerging economies, Borsa Istanbul Rev., 22 (2022), 560–570. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2021.07.005 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2021.07.005
    [46] X. Chang, The impact of corporate tax outcomes on forced CEO turnover, Natl. Account. Rev., 4 (2022), 218–236. https://10.3934/NAR.2022013 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022013
    [47] J. A. Schumpeter, The Theory of Economic Development, Translated from the German by REDVERS OPIE, Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 1934.
    [48] L. Chen, Z. Du, Z. Hu, Impact of economic policy uncertainty on exchange rate volatility of China, Finance Res. Lett., 32 (2020), 101266. https://10.1016/j.frl.2019.08.014 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.08.014
    [49] G. Liao, P. Hou, X. Shen, K. Albitar, The impact of economic policy uncertainty on stock returns: The role of corporate environmental responsibility engagement, Int. J. Finance Econ., 26 (2020), 4386–4389. https://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.2020 doi: 10.1002/ijfe.2020
    [50] Y. Liu, L. Chen, L. Lv, P. Failler. The impact of population aging on economic growth: a case study on China, AIMS Math, 8 (2023), 10468–10485. https://doi.org/10.3934/math.2023531 doi: 10.3934/math.2023531
    [51] C. W. J. Granger, T. Teräsvirta, Modelling Non-Linear Economic Relationships, OUP Catalogue, Oxford University Press, 1993. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.3950090412
    [52] A. Gonzalez, T. Teräsvirta, D. Dijk, Y. Yang, Panel smooth transition regression models, No. 604, SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance, Stockholm School of Economics, 2017.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Mengxin He, Zhong Li, Dynamic behaviors of a Leslie-Gower predator-prey model with Smith growth and constant-yield harvesting, 2024, 32, 2688-1594, 6424, 10.3934/era.2024299
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2468) PDF downloads(148) Cited by(19)

Figures and Tables

Tables(7)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog