Research article

Insider trading with dynamic asset under market makers' partial observations

  • Received: 16 June 2023 Revised: 22 July 2023 Accepted: 09 August 2023 Published: 28 August 2023
  • MSC : 60G35, 60H10, 91G80, 93E11

  • This paper studies an extended continuous-time insider trading model of Calentey and Stacchetti (2010, Econometrica), which allows market makers to observe some partial information about a dynamic risky asset. For each of the two cases with trading until either a fixed time or a random time, we establish the existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibrium, consisting of insider trading intensity, price pressure on market orders and price pressure on asset observations. It shows that at each of the two equilibria, all information on the risky asset is incorporated in the market price and when the volatility of observation noise keeps constant, the more information observed by market makers, the smaller price pressure on market orders but the greater price pressure on asset observations such that the insider earns less profit and vice versa. It suggests that the partial observation of market makers weakens the information advantage of the insider, which prevents the insider from monopolizing the market to make excessive profit, then reduces the losses of noise traders, thus improving the fairness and effectiveness in the insider trading market.

    Citation: Jixiu Qiu, Yonghui Zhou. Insider trading with dynamic asset under market makers' partial observations[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(10): 25017-25036. doi: 10.3934/math.20231277

    Related Papers:

    [1] Kai Xiao . Risk-seeking insider trading with partial observation in continuous time. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 28143-28152. doi: 10.3934/math.20231440
    [2] Kai Xiao, Yonghui Zhou . Linear Bayesian equilibrium in insider trading with a random time under partial observations. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(12): 13347-13357. doi: 10.3934/math.2021772
    [3] Liyuan Zhang, Limian Ci, Yonghong Wu, Benchawan Wiwatanapataphee . Blockchain asset portfolio optimization with proportional and fixed transaction fees. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(3): 6694-6718. doi: 10.3934/math.2025306
    [4] Dennis Llemit, Jose Maria Escaner IV . Value functions in a regime switching jump diffusion with delay market model. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(10): 11595-11609. doi: 10.3934/math.2021673
    [5] Jiuchao Ban, Yiran Wang, Bingjie Liu, Hongjun Li . Optimization of venture portfolio based on LSTM and dynamic programming. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(3): 5462-5483. doi: 10.3934/math.2023275
    [6] Hui Sun, Zhongyang Sun, Ya Huang . Equilibrium investment and risk control for an insurer with non-Markovian regime-switching and no-shorting constraints. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(6): 6996-7013. doi: 10.3934/math.2020449
    [7] Xian Wen, Haifeng Huo, Jinhua Cui . The optimal probability of the risk for finite horizon partially observable Markov decision processes. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28435-28449. doi: 10.3934/math.20231455
    [8] Andrey Borisov . Filtering of hidden Markov renewal processes by continuous and counting observations. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 30073-30099. doi: 10.3934/math.20241453
    [9] Abdulhakim A. Al-Babtain, Amal S. Hassan, Ahmed N. Zaky, Ibrahim Elbatal, Mohammed Elgarhy . Dynamic cumulative residual Rényi entropy for Lomax distribution: Bayesian and non-Bayesian methods. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(4): 3889-3914. doi: 10.3934/math.2021231
    [10] Tomás Caraballo, Javier López-de-la-Cruz . Bounded random fluctuations on the input flow in chemostat models with wall growth and non-monotonic kinetics. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(4): 4025-4052. doi: 10.3934/math.2021239
  • This paper studies an extended continuous-time insider trading model of Calentey and Stacchetti (2010, Econometrica), which allows market makers to observe some partial information about a dynamic risky asset. For each of the two cases with trading until either a fixed time or a random time, we establish the existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibrium, consisting of insider trading intensity, price pressure on market orders and price pressure on asset observations. It shows that at each of the two equilibria, all information on the risky asset is incorporated in the market price and when the volatility of observation noise keeps constant, the more information observed by market makers, the smaller price pressure on market orders but the greater price pressure on asset observations such that the insider earns less profit and vice versa. It suggests that the partial observation of market makers weakens the information advantage of the insider, which prevents the insider from monopolizing the market to make excessive profit, then reduces the losses of noise traders, thus improving the fairness and effectiveness in the insider trading market.



    In recent years, the studying of financial micro-structures and characteristics for risky asset markets has become a hot topic. In a setting of semi-strong effective pricing rule, Kyle [1] first proposed an insider trading model of multi-stage auction with asymmetric information on a static risky asset and proved the existence and uniqueness of its linear sequential equilibrium, consisting of insider trading intensity and market liquidity. It showed that as the time step approaching zero, the equilibrium converges to a continuous-time limit version in which market liquidity is a time-independent constant and all information is incorporated in the market price. Later, Back [2] extended Kyle's model [1] to continuous-time version and also obtained a unique market equilibrium when the risky asset value follows more general distributions, where market liquidity is also independent of time. Collins-Dufresne and Fos [3] generalized Back's model by assuming that the liquidity trading volatility follows a general stochastic process and proved that market depth, market liquidity and price dynamics are characterized by a martingale, submartingale and stochastic Brown Bridge process, respectively. Yang, He and Huang [4] pointed out that even if noise traders have their own trading memories, the properties of equilibrium are similar to those of equilibrium in [3]. Real financial phenomena remind us that the value of risky asset often varies with time. Caldentey and Stacchetti [5] studied an insider trading model, where the risky asset value follows an arithmetic Brownian motion and the trade ends at a random time with life-time distributed. It indicates that in equilibrium both the market liquidity and the insider's value function are exponential functions with respect to time. In the market for defaultable claims, Campi, Çetin and Danilova [6] found that from the market's perspective, the information released by the insider while trading optimally makes the default time predictable in equilibrium. Furthermore, Ma, Sun and Zhou [7] considered the setting that the value of a risky is driven by a conditional mean-field Ornstein-Uhlenback-type dynamic and obtained a closed form of optimal trading intensity. There is much literature on continuous-time insider trading, see [8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16] and so on.

    Note that all the above work on insider trading focuses on an insider with perfect information. However, insiders often acquire only partial information on the underlying risky asset. Back, Cao and Willard [17] took the lead in establishing a continuous-time insider trading model of imperfect competition among informed traders. Then, Back, Crotty and Li [18] investigated the case that an insider acquires partial information about a risky asset in a high or low probability way. Under the framework of Collins-Dufresne and Fos [3], Banerjee and Breon-Drish [19,20] assumed that the insider may need to pay a certain cost to acquire the dynamic information flow of asset and demonstrated that the market depth is a semimartingale. Recently, Han, Li, Ma and Kennedy [21] continued to explore insider trading behaviors that noise traders have their own memories of historical trading and found that in a transparent market, to prevent the private information from rapid information leakage, the insider should adopt a mixed insider trading strategy. Qiu and Zhou [22] solved the problem of insider trading that an insider possesses some memory about the on-going observation of the underlying asset. Moreover, Crane, Crotty and Umar [23] illustrated that hedge funds which acquire public information earn higher annualized abnormal returns than nonacquirers. In the study of a new economic benefit of common institutional ownership, Chen, Ma, Wu and Zhang [24] pointed out that there is a significant negative relation between common ownership and insider trading profitability. For a fuzzy model to consider the robust portfolio selection problem of an agent with limited attention, Ma and Li [25] established an explicit solution of robust optimal strategy, which shows that more attention leads to smaller variance in estimated return.

    In fact, in real financial markets, market makers can also observe some information on the underlying risky asset. Nishide [26] added the correlation of liquidity trading and the public signal to the Back's model [2] and revealed that market liquidity in equilibrium is not necessarily monotonous with time and the public signal does not necessarily make the market more efficient. Zhou [27] showed that when market makers observe some partial observations on a risky asset at the very beginning, the market liquidity in equilibrium remains a constant and the partial observation makes more information on the risky asset to be incorporated into the market price, thus improving the informativeness of the market. Xiao and Zhou [28] verified this economic intuition further.

    In this paper, we study an extension of Caldentey and Stacchetti's [5] continuous-time insider trading model, in which market makers can observe some on-going partial information on a dynamic risky asset. Since market makers observe not only the total market orders, but also some partial information about the dynamic asset, then when pricing they must consider impacts of the two kinds of information. Therefore, we introduce a linear Bayesian equilibrium, which consists of insider trading intensity, price pressure on market orders (market liquidity) and price pressure on asset observations. Then, we establish the existence and uniqueness of equilibrium for insider trading until a fixed time T or a random time τ respectively. There are several findings in our study. First, when trading until at the fixed time T price pressure on market orders is constant as in literature [1,2,8,15,27], while it is an exponential function of time when trading until the random τ as in [5]. Second, at the end of the transaction in both cases, the insider's private information is completely released. Third, the more information observed by market makers, the smaller the weight that market makers give to price pressure on market orders, while the greater the weight to price pressure on asset observations and vice versa. Finally, the more information the market makers observe, the weaker the information advantage of the insider and the lower the expected profit earned by the insider as in [27]. These results show that the partial observations of market makers can prevent effectively the insider from profiteering by monopolizing information.

    It is mentioned that our research is based on pure models, that is, only considering that all agents will process and respond to the information they have in the same way. However, empirically and theoretically it is not the case. For example, in a statistical method, Dang, Foerster, Li and Tang[29] found that financial analysts with high ability can produce firmer specific information through more accurate forecasts, which can effectively reduce the critical information asymmetry between insiders and external investors. In the future research, we will check some famous insider trading events in history and link those to information and market conditions, especially when agents process their information in different ways.

    This article consists of six sections. A model of continuous-time insider trading with partial observations is described in Section 2. In Section 3, some necessary conditions on market efficiency are given. The existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibria for insider trading until a fixed time or a random time is established in Section 4. Some comparative static analyses on properties of equilibria in some special markets are given in Section 5. Conclusions are drawn in Section 6.

    We here consider an extension model of continuous-time insider trading in [5], which allows market makers to observe some partial information about a dynamic risky asset trading until either a deterministic time T or a random time τ. Since there could be many equilibria in a continuous-time insider trading market [2,15], then for simplification, only linear strategies for the insider and market makers are considered in our model. All of random variables or processes are assumed to be defined on a complete and filtered probability space (Ω,F,{Ft}t0,P) satisfying the usual condition [30].

    In a financial market, there is a risky asset traded in continuous-time whose value vt evolves as

    vt=v0+t0σvsdWvs, (2.1)

    where v0 is normally distributed as N(0,σ2v0), σvt is a deterministic, differentiable and positive function, and Wvt is a standard Brownian motion [5,16]. There are three types of agents in the market:

    (i) liquidity traders: who can not observe any information about the value of the risky asset and submit their trading volume zt randomly [8,10], which satisfies

    zt=t0σzsdWzs, (2.2)

    where σzt is a deterministic, differentiable and positive function and Wzt is a standard Brownian motion

    (ii) an insider: who is risk-neutral and knows the realization of the risky asset value vt and the current price pt of the risky asset, then submits her/his trading volume xt, evolving as in [1,3,5,8,15,20]

    dxt=βt(vtpt)dt, (2.3)

    where β is a trading strategy of the insider, called insider trading intensity, which is a deterministic, differentiable and positive function

    (iii) market makers: who observe the aggregate trading volume

    yt=xt+zt, (2.4)

    (but can not observe xt and zt separately, otherwise the market maker can infer the perfect information of risky asset through the trading volume submitted by the insider and there is no insider trading) and some partial information of the risky asset as

    ut=vt+εt, (2.5)

    where εt=ε0+t0σεsdWεs with ε0 normally distributed as N(0,σ2ε0), σεt is a deterministic, differentiable and positive function, Wεt is a standard Brownian motion and set for the risky asset a market price pt, whose dynamic is

    dpt=λ1tdyt+λ2tdut, (2.6)

    where p0=0, λ1 and λ2 are two deterministic, differentiable and positive functions, called price pressure on market orders and price pressure on asset observations respectively.

    Here, v0, ε0, {Wzt}, {Wvt} and {Wεt} are supposed mutually independent. Denote the insider's information and market makers' information by FIt=σ{ps;0st}σ{vs;0st} and FMt=σ{ys;0st}σ{us;0st}, respectively. Then,

    Case I: If the trading continues to a fixed time T, the insider's profit of self-financing [2] is

    E{T0βs(vsps)2ds|FIt}. (2.7)

    Case II: If the trading continues until a random time τ, which is exponentially distributed with rate η>0 and is independent of the history of transactions and prices, the insider's profit of self-financing [5] is

    E{τ0βs(vsps)2ds|FIt}=E{0eηsβs(vsps)2ds|FIt}. (2.8)

    For well-postness in each of the two cases, given any insider trading intensity β of the insider, any price pressure on market orders λ1 and any price pressure on asset observations λ2, there must be ET0|βs|(vsps)2ds< in Case I and E0eηs|βs|(vsps)2ds< in Case II. (S,P) denotes the choice space where S is the set of insider's strategies β and P is the set of pricing rules (λ1,λ2).

    Assume that market makers are all risk-neutral and have a Bertrand competition. Then, similar to those in [1,7,10], for any market trade volume yt, the total profit of market makers should be 0, that is,

    E[(yt(vtpt)|FMt]=0

    or

    pt=E[vt|FMt], (2.9)

    which implies that the price pt satisfies semi-strong market efficiency.

    Now a concept of linear Bayesian equilibrium in our model is given below.

    Definition 2.1. A linear Bayesian equilibrium in the market is a triple (β,(λ1,λ2))(S,P) such that for any time t,

    (i) (maximization of profit) for the given (λ1,λ2), function β in Case I (Case II) maximizes

    E[T0βs(vsps)2ds|FIt],  (E[0eηsβs(vsps)2ds|FIt]),  for βS (2.10)

    (ii) (market efficiency) for the given β, (λ1,λ2) such that pricing p satisfies

    pt=t0λ1sdys+λ2sdus=E[vt|FMt]. (2.11)

    Before to establish the existence of linear equilibrium, we first discuss some necessary conditions of market efficiency.

    Proposition 3.1. Let a strategy profile (β,(λ1,λ2))(S,P). If (λ1,λ2) such that the corresponding market price pt satisfies the market efficiency (2.11). Then,

    λ1t=Σtβtσ2zt,   λ2t=σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εt, (3.1)

    where the residual information Σt=E(vtpt)2 satisfies the following dynamic

    dΣtdt=[(1λ2t)σ2vtλ21tσ2zt] (3.2)

    with Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0.

    Proof. According to Eqs (2.1)–(2.6), for market makers there is a signal-observation system of (vt, ξt) satisfying

    {dvt=σvtdWvt,dξt=(A0+A1vt)dt+B1dW1t+B2dW2t, (3.3)

    where

    v0N(0,σ2v0), ξt=(ytut), ξ0=(0v0+ε0), b1=(σv), A0=(ptβt0), A1=(βt0), B1=(0σvt), B2=(σzt00σεt), W1t=(Wvt), and W2t=(WztWεt).

    Denote BB=B1B1+B2B2, bB=b1B1+b2B2 and bb=b1b1+b2b2. Then,

    BB=(σ2z00σ2v+σ2ε), bB=(0,σ2v), bb=σ2v.

    Since pt satisfies the market efficiency (2.9), that is,

    pt=E[vt|FMt]=E[vt|Fξt].

    Then, Theorem 12.7 in [31] (or see Lemma 3.3 in [27]) tells us that

    dpt=(Σtβtσ2zt,σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εt)dξt=Σtβtσ2ztdyt+σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εtdut, (3.4)

    where the residual information Σt satisfies

    dΣtdt=(σ2vtσ2εtσ2vt+σ2εtΣ2tβ2tσ2zt) (3.5)

    with Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0 by Theorem 13.1 in [31].

    Since (λ1,λ2) satisfies the market efficiency (2.11), that is,

    pt=t0λ1tdyt+λ2tdut=E[vt|FMt],

    the results follow from (3.4) and (3.5), and the proof is complete.

    Let the pricing profile (λ1,λ2)P be given. Then, for any (t,m)[0,T)×R, for any βS[t,T)={β:β(r)=β(r),tr<T,βS}, there is a gap process

    ms=vsps, s[t,T).

    which by Eqs (2.1)–(2.6), satisfies the stochastic differential equation

    dms=λ1sβsmsdt+[(1λ2s)σvs,λ2sσεs,λ1sσzs][dWvsdWεsdWzs] (4.1)

    with mt=m. Then, we have the conditional value function

    J1(t,m)=supβS[t,T)E[Ttβsm2s(β)ds|FIt]. (4.2)

    Clearly this is a classical stochastic control problem, and by employing Proposition 3.5 of dynamic programming principle in [32], we can easily get Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation below with its proof omitted.

    Proposition 4.1. The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation of insider's value function (4.2) (if it exists in C1,2([0,T)×R)) is driven by

    supθR{J1t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]2J1m2+[λ1tmJ1m+m2]θ}=0. (4.3)

    Now the existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibrium can be given below.

    Theorem 4.2. Let for any time t[0,T)

    Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0, Γzt=Ttσ2zsds, Γvεt=Ttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds.

    Then, if the following inequality holds for any time t>0,

    ΓztΣ0+ΓztΓvε0Γz0Γvεt>0, (4.4)

    there is a unique linear Bayesian equilibrium (β,(λ1,λ2))(P,S) satisfying

    βt=λ1tσ2ztΣt, λ1tλ, λ2t=σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εt (4.5)

    with

    λ=Σ0+Γvε0Γz0, Σt=ΓztΣ0+ΓztΓvε0Γz0ΓvεtΓz0. (4.6)

    Also, the residual information Σt satisfies

    limtTΣt=0,

    the value function is

    J1(t,mt)=m2t2λ+Γvεt2λ+λΓzt2, (4.7)

    and the expected total profit of insider is

    E(J1(0,m0))=Γz0(Σ0+Γvε0).

    Proof. The proof is broken down into three steps:

    Step I: Find a solution J1 to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (4.3).

    According to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (4.3), the following system follows

    {λ1tJ1m+m=0,J1t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]2J1m2=0. (4.8)

    By the first equation in the above system, we have

    J1m=mλ1t,   2J1m2=1λ1t,   2J1tm=mddt(1λ1t). (4.9)

    So, the second equation in (4.8) implies that

    J1t+12λ1t[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]=0. (4.10)

    Then, by differentiating with respect to m,

    2J1tm=0.

    So,

    ddt(1λ1t)=0,

    which reveals that λ1t is a constant, denoted by λ, that is, λ1tλ.

    Equation (4.9) shows that

    J1(t,m)=m22λ1t+g(t), (4.11)

    for some determinate, continuous, differentiable function g(t). Now plugging Eq (4.11) into Eq (4.10), we have

    m22d(1λ1t)dt+dg(t)dt+12λ1t[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]=0. (4.12)

    Since ddt(1λ1t)=0, then (4.12) degenerates to

    dg(t)dt+12λ1t[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]=0. (4.13)

    Thus,

    g(t)=Ttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds2λ+λTtσ2zsds2.

    So,

    J1(t,m)=m22λ+Ttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds2λ+λTtσ2zsds2, (4.14)

    which can be expressed as (4.7).

    Step II: Find a necessary condition for the optimal insider trading intensity:

    limtTΣt=0,

    which means that

    λ=Σ0+T0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsdsT0σ2zsds,

    and

    E[J1(0,m0)]=Γz0(Σ0+Γvε0).

    In fact, for any βS, since stochastic process mt follows (4.1), then using Itô formula to J1(t,mt), we observe that

    J1(t,mt(β))=J1(0,m0)+t0{J1t+12[(1λ2s)2σ2vs+λ22sσ2εs+λ21sσ2zs]2J1m2}ds  t0λ1sβsmsJ1mds+t0J1m(1λ2s)σvsdWvst0J1mλ2sσεsdWεs  t0J1mλ1sσzsdWzs.

    According to the properties of the value function J1 in Step I,

    J1t+12[(1λ2s)2σ2vs+λ22sσ2εs+λ21sσ2zs]2J1m2=0,

    and

    J1m=mtλ1t.

    Then, taking conditional expectation on both sides of the above equation, we see that

    E[J1(T,mT(β))]=E[J1(0,m0)]E[T0βsm2sds], (4.15)

    that is,

    E[J1(0,m0)]=E[J1(T,mT(β))]+E[T0βsm2sds]. (4.16)

    Note that J1(T,mT)0, which implies that

    E[J1(0,m0)]E[T0βsm2sds], (4.17)

    and the equality in (4.17) holds if and only if E[J1(T,mT)]=0.,

    Indeed

    E[J1(t,mt)]=Σt2λ+Ttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds2λ+λTtσ2zsds2, (4.18)

    which tells that limtTE[J(t,mt)]=0 if and only if limtTΣt=0.

    On the other hand, by market efficiency (3.2) and the inequality condition (4.4), we get

    Σt=Σ0+t0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds(λ)2t0σ2zsds. (4.19)

    So, using the requirement limtTΣt=0, we observe that

    λ=Σ0+T0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsdsT0σ2zsds. (4.20)

    From this it follows that (4.19) satisfies the second equation in (4.6). Plugging (4.20) into (4.18) yields

    E[J1(0,m0)]=Γz0(Σ0+Γvε0).

    Step III: By Proposition 3.1, taking (β,(λ1,λ2)) as the forms in (4.5), respectively. Thus, it is a market equilibrium:

    (i) Given the pricing rule with (λ1,λ2), by computing directly, the insider trading intensity β is such that

    ET0βs(vsps)2ds=ET0βs(vsps)2ds=T0βsΣsds=Γz0(Σ0+Γvε0)=E[J1(0,m0)]<,

    that is, βS is optimal.

    (ii) Given the insider trading intensity β, the local linear pricing rule pt with dynamics dpt=λ1(t)dyt+λ2(t)dut must satisfy the market efficiency pt=E[vt|FMt]. In fact, there exists one signal-observation system in terms of (vt,ξt) following

    {dvt=σvtdWvt,dξt=(A0+A1vt)dt+B1dW1t+B2dW2t, (4.21)

    where

    v0N(0,σ2v0), ξt=(ytut), ξ0=(0v0+ε0), b1=(σv), A0=(ptβt0), A1=(βt0), B1=(0σvt), B2=(σzt00σεt), W1t=(Wvt) and W2t=(WztWεt).

    Let

    ~pt=E[vt|FMt]=E[vt|Fξt],

    with ~p0=0. Then, applying Theorem 12.7 in [31] (or see Lemma 3.3 in [27]) again, we know that

    d~pt=(Σtβtσ2zt,σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εt)[dξt((~ptpt)βt0)]. (4.22)

    Now taking Eq (4.22) minus Eq (3.4) gives

    d(~ptpt)=λ1tβt(~ptpt)dt,

    with ~p0p0=0, which leads to ~ptpt=0 a.s., that is ~pt=pt a.s. The proof is complete.

    In this subsection, we further consider the case when the risky asset is traded until a random time τ, life-time distributed with parameter η>0.

    Let the pricing profile (λ1,λ2)P be given. Then, for any (t,m)[0,)×R, for any βS[t,)={β:β(r)=β(r),tr<,βS}, the gap process ms=vsps, s[t,) satisfies (4.1). Then, it follows from (2.8) that the conditional value function is

    J2(t,m)=supβS[t,)E[teη(st)βsm2s(β)ds|FIt]. (4.23)

    Again we can easily obtain the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation below.

    Proposition 4.3. The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation of insider's value function (4.23) (if it exists in C1,2([0,T)×R)) is driven by

    supθR{J2t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]2J2m2ηJ2+[λ1tmtJ2m+m2t]θ}=0. (4.24)

    Proof. By the value function (4.23), it can be written as

    eηtJ2(t,m)=supβtSE[teηsβsm2sds|FIt].

    Let ˜J(t,m)=eηtJ2(t,m). Then,

    ˜J(t,m)=supβtSE[teηsβsm2sds|FIt].

    Hence, by employing Proposition 3.5 of dynamic programming principle in[32], ˜J(t,m) satisfies the following Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation

    supθR{˜Jt+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]2˜Jm2+[λ1tmt˜Jm+m2teηt]θ}=0.

    It follows that

    supθR{(J2t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]2J2m2ηJ2+[λ1tmtJ2m+m2t]θ)eηt}=0,

    which directly leads to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (4.24). This proof is complete.

    As in the previous subsection, the existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibrium can be given below.

    Theorem 4.4. Let for any time t0,

    Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0,   Υzt=tσ2zse2ηsds,   Υvεt=tσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds.

    Then, if the following inequalities hold

    Υz0<,  Υvε0<,  ΥztΣ0+ΥztΥvε0Υz0Υvεt>0,

    there is a unique linear Bayesian equilibrium (β,(λ1,λ2))(P,S) satisfying

    βt=λ1tσ2ztΣt, λ1t=λ1eηt, λ2t=σ2vtσ2vt+σ2εt (4.25)

    with

    λ1=Σ0+Υvε0Υz0

    and

    Σt=ΥztΣ0+ΥztΥvε0Υz0ΥvεtΥz0. (4.26)

    The residual information Σt satisfies

    limtΣt=0,

    the value function is

    J2(t,mt)=m2teηt2λ1+Υvεteηt2λ1+λ1Υzteηt2 (4.27)

    and the expected total profit of insider is

    E(J2(0,m0))=Υz0(Σ0+Υvε0). (4.28)

    Proof. Similar to the proof of Theorem 4.2. The proof is divided into three steps:

    Step I: Find a solution J2 to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (4.24).

    The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (4.24) states that

    {λ1tJ2m+m=0,J2t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2εt]2J2m2ηJ2=0. (4.29)

    By the first equation in (4.29), we have

    J2(t,m)=αtm2+δt, (4.30)

    where αt and δt are two determinate, continuous, differentiable and positive functions with αt=12λ1t.

    Accordingly, it follows from the second equation in (4.29) that

    {dαtdtηαt=0,dδtdtηδt+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2zt]1λ1t=0. (4.31)

    So, similar to the proof as in [5], we can prove that

    λ1t=λ1eηt,

    for some constant λ1>0 and that

    αt=12λ1eηt, δt=αttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds+λ12tσ2zse2ηsds, (4.32)

    that is,

    J2(t,m)=m2eηt2λ1+eηttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds2λ1+λ1eηttσ2zse2ηsds2.

    Then, the value function J2(t,mt) can be written as (4.27).

    Step II: Find a necessary condition for the optimal trading intensity:

    limtΣt=0,

    which implies that

    λ1=(σ2vσ2εσ2v+σ2ε++0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds)(+0σ2zse2ηsds),

    and

    E(J2(0,m0))=Υz0(Σ0+Υvε0).

    Let ˜J(t,m)=eηtJ2(t,m). Then, from the value function (4.23), we see that

    ˜J(t,m)=supβtSE[teηsβsm2sds|FIt].

    Indeed, for any βS, by the Eq (4.1), applying Itô formula to ˜J(t,mt) yields

    d˜J(s,ms(β))={˜Jt+12[(1λ2s)2σ2vs+λ22sσ2εs+λ21sσ2zs]2˜Jm2}ds  λ1sβsms˜Jmds+˜Jm(1λ2s)σvsdWvs˜Jmλ2sσεsdWεs  ˜Jmλ1sσzsdWzs,

    that is,

    dJ2(s,ms(β))={J2t+12[(1λ2s)2σ2vs+λ22sσ2εs+λ21sσ2εs]2J2m2ηJ2}ds  λ1sβsmsJ2mds+J2m(1λ2s)σvsdWvsJ2mλ2sσεsdWεs  J2mλ1sσzsdWzs+ηJ2(s,ms(β))ds.

    Note that,

    J2t+12[(1λ2t)2σ2vt+λ22tσ2εt+λ21tσ2εt]2J2m2ηJ2=0,  J2m=mλ1t.

    So,

    dJ2(s,ms(β))=ηJ2(s,ms(β))dsβsm2sds+msλ1s(1λ2s)σvsdWvs  msλ1sλ2sσεsdWεsmsλ1sλ1sσzsdWzs,

    which follows that

    J2(t,mt(β))=J2(0,m0)eηteηtt0eηsβsm2sds+eηtt0eηsmsλ1s(1λ2s)σvsdWvs  eηtt0eηsmsλ1sλ2sσεsdWεseηtt0eηsmsλ1sλ1sσzsdWzs.

    Multiplying both sides of the above equation by eηt gives

    eηtJ2(t,mt(β))=J2(0,m0)t0eηsβsm2sds+t0eηsmsλ1s(1λ2s)σvsdWvs  t0eηsmsλ1sλ2sσεsdWεst0eηsmsλ1sλ1sσzsdWzs.

    Hence,

    E[J2(0,m0)]=eηtE[J2(t,mt(β))]+E[t0eηsβsm2sds],

    for any βS. Since limteηtJ2(t,mt(β))0, for any t[0,), then

    E[J2(0,m0)]E[0eηsβsm2sds]

    and the above equality hold if and only if limteηtJ2(t,mt(β))=0.

    Since

    E[J2(t,mt)]=eηtΣt2λ1+eηttσ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds2λ1+λ1eηttσ2zse2ηsds2, (4.33)

    then limteηtE[J2(t,mt(β))]=0 if and only if limtΣt=0.

    According to market efficiency (3.2), it shows that

    Σt=Σ0+t0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds(λ1)2t0σ2zse2ηsds. (4.34)

    Together with limtΣt=0, we get

    λ1=(σ2vσ2εσ2v+σ2ε++0σ2vsσ2εsσ2vs+σ2εsds)(+0σ2zse2ηsds).

    Thus, (4.2) holds. Taking λ1 back into (4.33) deduces E(J2(0,m0))=Υz0(Σ0+Υvε0).

    Step III: From Proposition 3.1, taking (β,(λ1,λ2) as the forms in (4.25) respectively, we now verify that it is a market equilibrium:

    (i) For the given pricing rule with (λ1,λ2), the insider trading intensity β satisfies

    E0eηs|βs|(vsps)2ds=0eηsβsΣsds=Υz0(Σ0+Υvε0)<,

    which means that β in S is optimal.

    (ii) For the given insider trading intensity β, the local linear pricing pt with (λ1,λ2) must satisfy the market efficiency by repeating the procedure of (ii) in Step 3 of the proof for Theorem 4.2. This proof is complete.

    In this section we will investigate some influences of market makers' partial observation on insider trading in our model. Note that from Theorems 4.2 or 4.5, the corresponding price pressures and the insider's expected total profit depend on the volatility function σ2εt of market makers' observation intricately. To explain the economic implication better, we only consider some special cases, especially when the volatility function σ2εt keeps constant.

    Now recalling from Theorem 4.2, we can obtain the following proposition.

    Proposition 5.1. Let (β,(λ1,λ2))(S,P) be the linear Bayesian equilibrium in Case I

    σvtσv>0, σztσz>0, σεtσε>0.

    Then

     λ1tσ2ε>0, λ2tσ2ε<0, E(J1(β))σ2ε>0. (5.1)

    In particular,

    (i) if σ2ε0, σ2ε, then

       λ1tσ2v0+Tσ2vTσ2z,   λ2t0,   βtT(Tt)2σ2z(σ2v0+Tσ2v)σ4v0, (5.2)
        E(J1(β))Tσ2z(σ2v0+Tσ2v); (5.3)

    (ii) if σ2ε00, σ2ε0, then

      λ2t1,  λ1t0,  βt,   E(J1(β))0; (5.4)

    (iii) E(J1(σ2ε0,σ2ε))<E(J1(,)).

    Proof. Let σvt, σzt and σεt be the corresponding constants in the assumption. Then, by Theorem 4.2, it follows that

    λ1t=1Tσ2zσ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0+Tσ2vσ2εσ2v+σ2ε, λ2t=σ2vσ2v+σ2ε,
    βt=Tσ2z(Tt)2(σ2v0+σ2ε0σ2v0σ2ε0+Tσ2vσ2εσ2v+σ2ε(σ2v0+σ2ε0)2(σ2v0σ2ε0)2), (5.5)

    where the residual information Σt and the expected total profit E(J1(β)) satisfy respectively

    Σt=TtTσ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0, E(J1(β))=Tσ2z(σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0+Tσ2vσ2εσ2v+σ2ε). (5.6)

    Finally, it is easy to obtain our results above from Eqs (5.5) and (5.6). This proof is complete.

    Beyond that, some propositions for several special cases when the value of risky asset is static, that is, σvt0, will be listed below one by one:

    1) In the case when market makers only observe the total market order yt=xt+zt, which means σ2ε0, it follows from Theorem 4.2 that

    λ1tσv0Tσz, βtTσz(Tt)σv0, Σ0σ2v0, Σt(Tt)σ2v0T, E[J1(β)]σ2v0σ2zT,

    which are the same as those results in[1,2,8,15].

    2) In the case when market makers can observe two signals yt=xt+zt and ut=v0+ε0+t0σεtdWεt in the market, it is easy to see from Theorem 4.2 that

    λ1t=Σ0Γz0, βt=σ2ztΣ0Γz0Σ0Γzt, Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0, Σt=Σ0ΓztΓz0, E[J1(β)]=Σ0Γz0,

    which are consistent with those results in [27].

    Similarly, some properties about linear Bayesian equilibrium for special markets in Case II will be presented below with their proofs omitted.

    Proposition 5.2. Let (β,(λ1,λ2))(S,P) be the linear Bayesian equilibrium in Case II when

    σztσz>0, σεtσε>0.

    Then,

    λ1tσ2ε>0, λ2tσ2ε<0, E(J2(β))σ2ε>0. (5.7)

    In particular,

    (i) if σ2ε0, σ2ε, then

    λ1t2η(Σ0+Υv0)σ2zeηt, λ2t0, βt2η(Σ0+Υv0)σzeηt(Σ0+Υv0)e2ηtΥvt, (5.8)
    E(J2(β))σ2z(Σ0+Υv0)2η (5.9)

    and

    Σ0σ2v0, Σt(Σ0+Υv0)e2ηtΥvt, ΥvεtΥvt=+tσ2vsds;  (5.10)

    (ii) if σ2ε00, σ2ε0, then

     λ2t1, λ1t0, βt, E(J2(β))0; (5.11)

    (iii) E(J2(σ2ε0,σ2ε))<E(J2(,)).

    We remark that our results (5.8), (5.9) and (5.10) in Proposition 5.2 show that the model in our setting degenerates into the case of Caldentey and Stacchetti [5].

    As in the previous subsection, from Theorem 4.5 some propositions for two more special cases if the asset value is static, that is, σvt0, are stated as follows:

    1) When σεt=0 and σzt=σz>0,

     λ1t=2ηΣ0σ2zeηt, βt=2ηΣ0σzeηt, Σ0=σ2v0σ2ε0σ2v0+σ2ε0, Σt=Σ0e2ηt, E(J2(β))=σ2zΣ02η.

    2) In the above case when market makers only observe the total market order yt=xt+zt, which means σ2ε0,

     λ1tσv02ησzeηt, βtσz2ηeηtσv0, Σ0σ2v0, Σtσ2v0e2ηt, E(J2(β))σzσv02η.

    Based on the Caldentey-Stacchetti's model [5], this article investigates a new insider trading model, in which all information about a dynamic risky asset is known to an insider, while some partial information are observed by market makers. By applying filtering theory and dynamic programming principle, we establish the existence and uniqueness of linear Bayesian equilibrium trading either until a fixed maturity time T or a random time τ, respectively, which consists of insider trading intensity, price pressure on market orders and price pressure on asset observations. It shows that in equilibrium, limtTΣt=0 which means that all information on the risky asset is incorporated in the market price (see Theorems 4.2 and 4.5). Our results cover some classical results in literature [1,2,5,8,15,27].

    To explain the economic implication better, we further study our insider trading model for some special settings especially when the volatility function σ2εt keeps constant. According to Proposition 5.1 for Case I or Proposition 5.2 for Case II, it shows that the larger the noise σ2ε, the greater the weight that market makers give to price pressure on market orders, but the smaller the weight to price pressure on asset observations such that the insider earns more profit. Particularly, when σ2ε0 and σ2ε (which means market makers observe fewer information on the asset), the price pressure on asset observations tends to 0, which reveals that the weight that market makers give to asset observations in pricing tends to 0. In addition, the expected aggregate profit of the insider reaches the maximum. When σ2ε00 and σ2ε0 (which means market makers observe almost of information on the asset), the price pressure on market orders tends to 0 and the price pressure on asset observations tends to 1, which reveals that the weight that market makers give to market orders in pricing tends to 0, the weight to asset observations tends to 1 and the insider can make no money. These results suggest that market makers can acquire information about the risky asset through a variety of channels to prevent the insider from monopolizing the market to seek excessive profit.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    The authors are supported partially by Guizhou QKZYD[2022]4055, Natural Science Research Project of Guizhou Provincial Department of Education (QJJ[2023]011), Chinese NSF Grant (11861025).

    We would like to express our sincere gratitude to three anonymous referees for their careful reading of the manuscript and very insightful suggestions, which helped us to improve the quality of the paper significantly, and three funds for their funding.

    All authors declare no conflict of interest that could affect the publication of this paper.



    [1] A. S. Kyle, Continuous auctions and insider trading, Econometrica, 53 (1985), 1315–1335. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913210 doi: 10.2307/1913210
    [2] K. Back, Insider trading in continuous-time, Rev. Financ. Stud., 5 (1992), 387–409. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/5.3.387 doi: 10.1093/rfs/5.3.387
    [3] P. Collins-Dufresne, V. Fos, Insider trading, stochastic liquidity and equilibrium prices, Econometrica, 84 (2016), 1441–1475. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA10789 doi: 10.3982/ECTA10789
    [4] B. Z. Yang, X. J. He, N. J. Huang, Equilibrium price and optimal insider trading strategy under stochastic liquidity with long memory, Appl. Math. Optim., 84 (2021), 1209–1237. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00245-020-09675-2 doi: 10.1007/s00245-020-09675-2
    [5] R. Calentey, E. Stacchetti, Insider trading with a random deadline, Econometrica, 78 (2010), 245–283. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA7884 doi: 10.3982/ECTA7884
    [6] L. Campi, U. Çetin, A. Danilova, Equilibrium model with default and dynamic insiders information, Finance Stoch., 17 (2013), 565–585. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-012-0196-x doi: 10.1007/s00780-012-0196-x
    [7] J. Ma, R. T. Sun, Y. H. Zhou, Kyle-Back equilibrium models and linear conditional mean-field SDEs, SIAM J. Control Optim., 56 (2018), 1154–1180. https://doi.org/10.1137/15M102558X doi: 10.1137/15M102558X
    [8] K. K. Aase, T. Bjuland, B. Øksendal, Strategic insider trading equilibrium: a filter theory approach, Afr. Mat., 23 (2012), 145–162. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13370-011-0026-x doi: 10.1007/s13370-011-0026-x
    [9] K. Back, S. Baruch, Information in securities markets: Kyle meets Glosten and Milgrom, Econometrica, 72 (2004), 433–465. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00497.x doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00497.x
    [10] K. Back, H. Pedersen, Long-lived information and intraday patterns, J. Financ. Mark., 1 (1998), 385–402. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1386-4181(97)00003-7 doi: 10.1016/S1386-4181(97)00003-7
    [11] S. Baruch, Insider trading and risk aversion, J. Financ. Mark., 5 (2002), 451–464. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1386-4181(01)00031-3 doi: 10.1016/S1386-4181(01)00031-3
    [12] F. Biagini, Y. Hu, T. Myer-Brandis, B. Øksendal, Insider trading equilibrium in a market with memory, Math. Finan. Econ., 6 (2012), 229–247. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-012-0065-6 doi: 10.1007/s11579-012-0065-6
    [13] L. Campi, U. Çetin, A. Danilova, Dynamic markov bridges motivated by models of insider trading, Stoch. Proc. Appl., 121 (2011), 534–567. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spa.2010.11.004 doi: 10.1016/j.spa.2010.11.004
    [14] U. Çetin, Financial equilibrium with asymmetric information and random horizon, Finance Stoch., 22 (2018), 97–126. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-017-0348-0 doi: 10.1007/s00780-017-0348-0
    [15] K. H. Cho, Continuous auctions and insider trading: uniqueness and risk aversion, Finance Stoch., 7 (2003), 47–71. https://doi.org/10.1007/s007800200078 doi: 10.1007/s007800200078
    [16] A. Daniloa, Stock market insider trading in continous time with imperfect dynamic information, Stochastics, 82 (2010), 111–131. https://doi.org/10.1080/17442500903106614 doi: 10.1080/17442500903106614
    [17] K. Back, C. H. Cao, G. A. Willard, Imperfect competition among informed traders, J. Financ., 55 (2000), 2117–2155. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00282 doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00282
    [18] K. Back, K. Crotty, T. Li, Identifying information asymmetry in securities markets, Rev. Financ. Stud., 31 (2018), 2277–2325. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhx133 doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhx133
    [19] S. Banerjee, B. Breon-Drish, Strategic trading and unobservable information acquisition, J. Finan. Econ., 138 (2020), 458–482. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2020.05.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2020.05.007
    [20] S. Banerjee, B. Breon-Drish, Dynamics of research and strategic trading, Rev. Financ. Stud., 35 (2022), 908–961. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhab029 doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhab029
    [21] J. H. Han, X. L. Li, G. Y. Ma, A. P. Kennedy, Strategic trading with information acquisition and long-memory stochastic liquidity, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 308 (2023), 480–495. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2022.11.028 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2022.11.028
    [22] J. X. Qiu, Y. H. Zhou, On the equilibrium of insider trading under information acquisition with long memory, J. Ind. Manag. Optim., 19 (2023), 7130–7149. https://doi.org/10.3934/jimo.2022255 doi: 10.3934/jimo.2022255
    [23] A. Crane, K. Crotty, T. Umar, Hedge funds and public information acquisition, Manage. Sci., 69 (2023), 3241–3262. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2022.4466 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2022.4466
    [24] S. L. Chen, H. Ma, Q. Wu, H. Zhang, Does common ownership constrain managerial rent extraction? Evidence from insider trading profitability, J. Corp. Financ., 80 (2023), 102389. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2023.102389 doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2023.102389
    [25] Y. Ma, Z. F. Li, Robust portfolio choice with limited attention, Electron. Res. Arch., 31 (2023), 3666–3687. https://doi.org/10.3934/era.2023186 doi: 10.3934/era.2023186
    [26] K. Nishide, Insider trading with correlation between liquidity trading and a public signal, Quant. Financ., 9 (2009), 297–304. https://doi.org/10.1080/14697680802165728 doi: 10.1080/14697680802165728
    [27] Y. H. Zhou, Existence of linear strategy equilibrium in insider trading with partial observations, J. Syst. Sci. Complex., 29 (2016), 1281–1292. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11424-015-4186-x doi: 10.1007/s11424-015-4186-x
    [28] K. Xiao, Y. H. Zhou, Insider trading with a random deadline under partial observations: maximal principle method, Acta Math. Appl. Sin. Engl. Ser., 38 (2022), 753–762. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10255-022-1112-6 doi: 10.1007/s10255-022-1112-6
    [29] C. Y. Dang, S. Foerster, Z. C. Li, Z. Y. Tang, Analyst talent, information, and insider trading, J. Corp. Financ., 67 (2021), 101803. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101803
    [30] P. E. Protter, Stochastic integration and differential equations, Berlin Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 1990. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-10061-5
    [31] R. S. Liptser, A. N. Shiryaev, Statistic of random process II, Berlin Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 2001. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-10028-8
    [32] J. M. Yong, X. Y. Zhou, Stochastic controls, New York: Springer, 1999. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-1466-3
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1155) PDF downloads(43) Cited by(0)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog