Research article

Robust equilibrium reinsurance and investment strategy for the insurer and reinsurer under weighted mean-variance criterion

  • Received: 05 August 2023 Revised: 10 September 2023 Accepted: 20 September 2023 Published: 25 September 2023
  • This paper investigates the time-consistent robust optimal reinsurance problem for the insurer and reinsurer under weighted objective criteria. The joint objective criterion is obtained by weighting the mean-variance objectives of both the insurer and reinsurer. Specifically, we assume that the net claim process is approximated by a diffusion model, and the insurer can purchase proportional reinsurance from the reinsurer. The insurer adopts the loss-dependent premium principle considering historical claims, while the reinsurance contract still uses the expected premium principle due to information asymmetry. Both the insurer and reinsurer can invest in risk-free assets and risky assets, where the risky asset price is described by the constant elasticity of variance model. Additionally, the ambiguity-averse insurer and ambiguity-averse reinsurer worry about the uncertainty of parameter estimation in the model, therefore, we obtain a robust optimization objective through the robust control method. By solving the corresponding extended Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation, we derive the time-consistent robust equilibrium reinsurance and investment strategy and corresponding value function. Finally, we examined the impact of various parameters on the robust equilibrium strategy through numerical examples.

    Citation: Yiming Su, Haiyan Liu, Mi Chen. Robust equilibrium reinsurance and investment strategy for the insurer and reinsurer under weighted mean-variance criterion[J]. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(10): 6384-6411. doi: 10.3934/era.2023323

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xia Zhao, Mengjie Li, Qinrui Si . Optimal investment-reinsurance strategy with derivatives trading under the joint interests of an insurer and a reinsurer. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(12): 4619-4634. doi: 10.3934/era.2022234
    [2] Yue Ma, Zhongfei Li . Robust portfolio choice with limited attention. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(7): 3666-3687. doi: 10.3934/era.2023186
    [3] Liping Fan, Pengju Yang . Load forecasting of microgrid based on an adaptive cuckoo search optimization improved neural network. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(11): 6364-6378. doi: 10.3934/era.2024296
    [4] Ke Liu, Hanzhong Liu . Testing for individual and time effects in unbalanced panel data models with time-invariant regressors. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(12): 4574-4592. doi: 10.3934/era.2022232
    [5] Nafeisha Tuerxun, Zhidong Teng . Optimal harvesting strategy of a stochastic $ n $-species marine food chain model driven by Lévy noises. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(9): 5207-5225. doi: 10.3934/era.2023265
    [6] Lingling Zhang . Vibration analysis and multi-state feedback control of maglev vehicle-guideway coupling system. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(10): 3887-3901. doi: 10.3934/era.2022198
    [7] Yan Xie, Rui Zhu, Xiaolong Tan, Yuan Chai . Inhibition of absence seizures in a reduced corticothalamic circuit via closed-loop control. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(5): 2651-2666. doi: 10.3934/era.2023134
    [8] Bangna Li, Qingqing Zhang, Xingshi He . Multi-label feature selection via constraint mapping space regularization. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(4): 2598-2620. doi: 10.3934/era.2024118
    [9] Jian-Ying Rong, Xu-Qing Liu . Hybrid principal component regression estimation in linear regression. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(6): 3758-3776. doi: 10.3934/era.2024171
    [10] Yi Gong . Consensus control of multi-agent systems with delays. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(8): 4887-4904. doi: 10.3934/era.2024224
  • This paper investigates the time-consistent robust optimal reinsurance problem for the insurer and reinsurer under weighted objective criteria. The joint objective criterion is obtained by weighting the mean-variance objectives of both the insurer and reinsurer. Specifically, we assume that the net claim process is approximated by a diffusion model, and the insurer can purchase proportional reinsurance from the reinsurer. The insurer adopts the loss-dependent premium principle considering historical claims, while the reinsurance contract still uses the expected premium principle due to information asymmetry. Both the insurer and reinsurer can invest in risk-free assets and risky assets, where the risky asset price is described by the constant elasticity of variance model. Additionally, the ambiguity-averse insurer and ambiguity-averse reinsurer worry about the uncertainty of parameter estimation in the model, therefore, we obtain a robust optimization objective through the robust control method. By solving the corresponding extended Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation, we derive the time-consistent robust equilibrium reinsurance and investment strategy and corresponding value function. Finally, we examined the impact of various parameters on the robust equilibrium strategy through numerical examples.



    Optimization problems play an important role in actuarial science, and the optimal reinsurance-investment strategies of insurers have been popular topics in financial research in recent years. Reinsurance and investment are critical tools for insurers to diversify risks and increase returns. The primary challenge for insurers is to attain optimal goals through controlling their reinsurance and investment strategies. This problem has been broadly studied with various criteria, such as minimizing the bankruptcy probability (see [1,2,3]), maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth (see [4,5,6,7]), and the mean-variance optimization (see [8,9,10,11]).

    In most studies, insurance premiums are typically determined based on future losses and charged using mean (variance) premium principles. However, in practice, current premiums are associated with historical losses. Fung et al. [12] and Niehaus and Terry [13] conducted empirical research to explore the dynamic relationship between premiums and losses. Barberis et al. [14] introduced the extrapolation bias to study a consumption-based asset pricing model. Inspired by extrapolation bias, Chen et al. [15] proposed an extrapolation claim model in which future premiums are determined by both historical and future claims and studied the optimal reinsurance strategy under this model. Hu and Wang [16] further introduced the loss-dependent premium principle and investigated how it affects the insurer's reinsurance strategy. Chen and Yang [17] extended the consideration of reinsurance and investment problems with correlated claims to the robust framework.

    In traditional investment-reinsurance models, the ambiguity-neutral insurers (ANI) trust the accuracy of parameter estimation in the model. However, in practice, it is hard to accurately estimate parameters in insurance and financial markets, resulting in so-called model uncertainty. In recent years, model uncertainty has been widely employed in optimal risk control. The main method for solving model uncertainty is the robust control method proposed by Anderson et al. [18], where they studied continuous-time asset pricing models under this method and used the difference between the reference model and the true model as a penalty term to reflect investors' attitudes towards model uncertainty. Maenhout [19] studied optimization problems in intertemporal consumption through dynamic programming and derived closed-form expressions for the optimal strategy under "homothetic robustness". These studies greatly inspired research on model uncertainty in actuarial science. Zhang and Siu [20] utilized game theory to study the investment and reinsurance problem under model uncertainty conditions. Yi et al. [21] investigated the optimal reinsurance-investment strategies when the risk asset price process is described by the Heston model. Yi et al. [22] extended the robust optimal investment-reinsurance problem to the mean-variance framework. Zheng et al. [23] explored the robust optimal strategies under the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) model and terminal utility function. Li et al. [24] considered the problem of optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance and investment under a jump model. Gu et al. [25] explored the optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance contract with fuzzy aversion. Wang et al. [26] studied the robust equilibrium reinsurance-investment strategies of two insurance companies with ambiguity aversion in a robust game framework.

    Before (re)insurance contracts are signed, negotiations take place among the participants. Therefore, (re)insurance contracts that consider the interests of multiple parties are more practical and more likely to be accepted. Recently, there have been several studies considering the multiple-party interests. Asimit and Boonen [27], Boonen and Jiang [28] and Zhuang et al. [29] explored (re)insurance contracts that considered multiple-party interests in a one-period (static) model. Moreover, there have been corresponding studies in a continuous-time (dynamic) framework. For instance, Chen and Shen [30] and Yuan et al. [31] considered the interests of both parties within a Stackelberg game framework when reinsurance contracts are signed. Apart from game-theoretic studies, there are two types of approaches that consider joint interests in a continuous-time framework. One approach combines the wealth processes of both parties to form a common wealth process to consider their interests. For instance, Zhao et al. [32] and Guan and Hu [33] considered the maximization of exponential utility criteria and mean-variance criteria, respectively, by weighting the wealth processes of the insurer and reinsurer. Yang [34] quantified the competition between the insurer and the reinsurer by representing their interests through relative wealth processes. Another approach integrates the objective criteria of both parties, which becomes more complex during the solution process due to the retention of the wealth processes of both parties. Huang et al. [35], Zhang [36] and Chen et al. [37] multiplied the objective criteria of the insurer and reinsurer to considered the optimal strategy under the maximization of the product of exponential utilities. On the other hand, Li et al. [38] and Li et al. [39] formed a common objective criterion by weighting the mean-variance criteria of the insurer and reinsurer, where the weight α represents the outcome of negotiations and serves to balance the interests of both parties.

    Although there have been numerous studies integrating the aforementioned ways of linking the interests of both parties with robustness, there is still no research on considering the mean-variance weighted criteria of both sides within a robust framework. This paper primarily focuses on this aspect. Specifically, the insurer adopts the loss-dependent premium principle by combining a weighted average of past claim indices and the expectation of future claims, which is an extension of the traditional expected premium principle. Due to the fact that the reinsurer may not have access to historical claims information, the reinsurance contract adopts the expected premium principle. In addition, both the insurer and reinsurer invest their surplus in the financial market, where the risky asset is described by the CEV model. We address the issue of parameter estimation uncertainty in the model using robust control methods and derive the extended Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation within a robust framework. Finally, by utilizing stochastic control theory, closed-form expressions for the robust equilibrium strategy and the corresponding value function can be obtained. Furthermore, we also consider several special cases of the model and analyze the impact of model parameters on the strategies through numerical simulations. Different from Yang [34], we incorporate the interests of both the insurer and reinsurer by weighting their respective objective criteria. The reinsurer's involvement in decision-making is enhanced, and we consider the CEV risk model in the investment market. Furthermore, unlike Li et al. [38] and Li et al. [39], we take into account the impact of historical claims from the perspective of the insurer. We derive robust insurance investment strategies within a robust framework, and the numerical analysis reveals different effects of parameters on the strategies.

    This paper is structured as follows: In Section 2, we introduce our model from three perspectives. In Section 3, we present a robust optimization problem considering model uncertainty and derive the explicit solutions for the robust equilibrium strategies and the corresponding value function under the mean-variance weighted sum criterion. In Section 4, we illustrate our results through numerical simulations. Section 5 summarizes this paper. The proofs of the theorems are provided in the appendix.

    In this paper, we suppose that all investments and assets are infinitely divisible and all assets are tradable continuously over time, without considering transaction costs or taxes. Let (Ω,F,{Ft}t[0,T],P) be a complete, filtered probability space satisfying the usual conditions, where the information flow {Ft}t[0,T] is generated by independent random processes and includes all market information available before time t. Here, T>0 is a fixed, finite time horizon.

    We assume that the surplus process of the insurer satisfies the following classical risk model,

    dR(t)=cdtdN(t)i=1Zi,

    where c is the premium rate, N(t) is a homogeneous Poission process with intensity λ>0, {Zi,i1} is a sequence of positive independent and identically distributed random variables and independent of N(t), and they have a common distribution function of F(z) with finite first and second moments, where FZ(z)=0 for z0 and 0<FZ(z)1 for z>0. The process L(t) can be approximated by a diffusion model

    L(t)μdtσ0W0(t),

    where μ=λE(Z),σ20=λE(Z2) and W0(t) is a standard Brownian motion on (Ω,F,P).

    The traditional premium principle is based on future losses, but in reality, premiums are also related to historical claims. For instance, when renewing the insurance contracts, insurance companies will take into account the claims that have occurred in the recent past. Inspired by Barberis et al. [14], we assume that the insurer is an extrapolator who believes that if claims have recently increased (decreased), they will continue to show an increasing (decreasing) trend in the near future. Then, we introduce the loss-dependent premium principle proposed by Hu and Wang [16], which is constructed by a stochastic volatility model. Firstly, we define the exponential weighted average of historical losses as follows:

    v(t)=βt0eβ(ts)dL(sdt),0<β<1, (2.1)

    where dL(sdt) means the total claims that occurred during the time interval [sdt,s], and the constant parameter β represents the strength of extrapolation. When β is relatively large, v(t) is primarily determined by recent losses. The differential form of v(t) is

    dv(t)=β(μv(t))dtβσ0dW0(t). (2.2)

    It should be noted that the total weight of past losses, given by βt0eβ(ts)ds=1eβ(t), is less than 1. Therefore, we assign a time-varying weight of eβ(t) to the expected future loss. Subsequently, the premium charged by the insurer per unit of time based on the loss-dependent premium principle is as follows:

    C=(1+n1)[v(t)+eβtμ],

    here n1 represents the safety loading of the insurer. When β=0, this premium principle can degenerate to the traditional expected value premium principle.

    In general, insurers transfer their potential claim risks by purchasing reinsurance and investing in financial markets. We suppose that the insurer chooses to purchase proportional reinsurance in this paper, and the retention level of the insurer is q(t)[0,1]. Since the reinsurer may not have access to the insurer's historical claim information, assuming that the reinsurance contract follows the expected premium principle, the insurer should pay the reinsurer a reinsurance premium of (1+n2)(1q(t))μ at time t. To exclude the insurer's arbitrage behavior, we require n2>n1. Therefore, the surplus process in the presence of the reinsurance of the insurer and reinsurer are respectively given by

    dR1(t)=[(1+n1)(v(t)+eβtμ)]dt[(1+n2)(1q(t))μ]dtq(t)[μdtσ0dW0(t)],

    and

    dR2(t)=(1+n2)(1q(t))μdt(1q(t))[μdtσ0dW0(t)].

    In addition, both the insurer and reinsurer are allowed to invest their surplus in a financial market which consists of two kinds of asset: risk-free asset and risky asset. The price process of the risk-free asset is given by

    dB(t)=rB(t)dt,B(0)=1,

    where r>0 is the risk-free interest rate. The price of the risky assets available for the insurer and reinsurer to invest in are described by the CEV model:

    dS1(t)=S1(t)[b1dt+σ1Sδ11(t)dW1(t)],S1(0)=s11, (2.3)
    dS2(t)=S2(t)[b2dt+σ2Sδ22(t)dW2(t)],S2(0)=s21, (2.4)

    where b1>0, b2>0 are expected instantaneous rates of return of the risky assets. Without any loss of generality, we assume that b1>r, b2>r, σ1Sδ11(t), σ2Sδ22(t) are instantaneous volatilities, δ1, δ2 are elasticity parameters that satisfy the general condition δ10, δ20, W1(t) and W2(t) are standard Brownian motions defined on the complete probability space (Ω,F,P), and they are independent of W0(t), i.e., E[W0(t)W1(t)]=0 and E[W0(t)W2(t)]=0.

    Remark 2.1. We denote E[W1(t)W2(t)]=ρt,ρ(1,1]. When W1(t) and W2(t) are dependent and W1(t)W2(t) (i.e., 0<|ρ|<1), it is difficult to obtain explicit solutions for the optimal strategies. Therefore, this paper provides analytical results only for the cases of ρ=0 and ρ=1. For the case of ρ=1, which corresponds to both parties investing in the same risky asset S1(t), the solution process is similar to the case of ρ=0 but simpler. The analytical results for the case of ρ=1 are discussed in Remark 3.4. In the following discussion, we will focus on the case of ρ=0.

    Let π1(t) denote the amount invested by the insurer in the risky asset S1(t), and π2(t) denote the amount invested by the reinsurer in the risky asset S2(t) at time t. Assume that u(t):=(π1(t),π2(t),q(t))t[0,T] represents the decision variables of both the insurer and reinsurer at time t, then, the wealth processes of the insurer and reinsurer are respectively described by

    dX(t)=[rX(t)+(b1r)π1(t)+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+q(t)n2μ]dt+q(t)σ0dW0(t)+π1(t)σ1Sδ11(t)dW1(t), (2.5)

    and

    dY(t)=[rY(t)+(b2r)π2(t)+n2(1q(t))μ]dt+(1q(t))σ0dW0(t)+π2(t)σ2Sδ22(t)dW2(t), (2.6)

    with the initial conditions X(0)=x0 and Y(0)=y0.

    Similar to Chen and Yang [17] and Huang et al. [35], we provide the following definition of admissible strategies:

    Definition 1. A strategy u(t):=(π1(t),π2(t),q(t))t[0,T] is called a admissible strategy if it satisfies

    (i) π1(t), π2(t) and q(t) are progressively measurable, and π1(t),π2(t)[0,+),q(t)[0,1] for any t[0,T];

    (ii) E[T0u(t)2dt]<, where u(t)2=q2(t)+π21(t)+π22(t);

    (iii) (t,x,y,v,s1,s2)[0,T)×R2×R+×R2, the equations (2.5) and (2.6) have unique strong solutions {Xu(t)}t[0,T] and {Yu(t)}t[0,T] respectively, with Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[U(Xu(T))]<, Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[U(Yu(T))]<.

    Let U denote the set of all admissible strategies.

    When signing a reinsurance contract, negotiation between both parties is required. The optimal strategy for one party often conflicts with the interests of the other party, therefore, contracts that maximize the common interests of both parties are more likely to be accepted. In this paper, we adopt the mean-variance weighted objective criterion used in Li et al. [38] and Li et al. [39]. This objective criterion considers the optimization problem from the perspectives of both insurers and reinsurers, where both parties aim to maximize the expected terminal wealth and minimize the variance of terminal wealth. The specific form is as follows

    supuUJu(t,x,y,v,s1,s2):=supuU{αJux(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)+(1α)Juy(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)}, (3.1)

    where

    Jux(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[Xu(T)]γ12Vart,x,y,v,s1,s2[Xu(T)],Juy(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[Yu(T)]γ22Vart,x,y,v,s1,s2[Yu(T)].

    The weighting parameter α (0α1) plays a role in balancing the interests of the insurer and reinsurer. The specific value of α can be determined by the insurer and reinsurer through relative weighting of their respective ultimate objectives. In reality, some large financial companies not only own insurance companies but also reinsurers, and these large financial companies may make reinsurance and investment decisions for both. In addition, Golubin [40] discusses methods for determining the value of α. One approach is to rely on exogenous methods provided by experts based on empirical research. Another method is based on cooperative game theory. For further discussion on the determination of α, refer to Golubin [40] and the references therein.

    In the given framework, the ambiguity-neutral insurer (ANI) and the ambiguity-neutral reinsurer (ANR) do not doubt the accuracy of the probability distribution P and its parameter estimation. However, in theory, the parameter model used contains significant uncertainties. These uncertainties mainly come from two aspects, it is difficult for investors to accurately estimate the expected return process of risky assets, and there may also be errors in estimating the drift parameters. On the other hand, there may also be uncertainties in the parameter estimation of the surplus process for the insurer.

    To consider the uncertainty of the model, we adopt a systematic and quantitative approach by referring to the methods proposed by Anderson et al. [18]. Therefore, we consider alternative models to obtain robust optimal strategies by broadly defining a class of probability measures Q that are equivalent to the probability measure P. Let these alternative probability measures belong to set Q, which is defined by

    Q:={QQP}.

    Next, we introduce a process {θ(t)=(θ0(t),θ1(t),θ2(t))t[0,T]} satisfying

    1) θ(t) is progressively measurable;

    2) E[exp(12T0θ(t)2dt)]<, where θ(t)2=θ20(t)+θ21(t)+θ22(t).

    We denote the space of all such processes as Θ. For each θΘ, we define a new probability measure Q that is absolutely continuous with respect to P on FT and satisfies

    dQdP|Ft:=exp{t0θ(u)dW(u)12t0θ(u)2du},

    where W(t)=(W0(t),W1(t),W2(t)) is a standard three-dimensional Brownian motion. Therefore, by choosing different processesθΘ, different probability measures for the diffusion part of the wealth process are obtained. According to the Girsanov's theorem, the Brownian motion under QQ can be defined as dWQ(t)=dWP(t)+θ(t)dt, i.e.,

    dWQ0(t)=dW0(t)+θ0(t)dt,dWQ1(t)=dW1(t)+θ1(t)dt,dWQ2(t)=dW2(t)+θ2(t)dt.

    It can be observed that the main difference between the alternative model and the reference model lies in the drift term. Moreover, since the Brownian motion W0,W1,W2 are mutually independent, they remain independent even after the measure transformation.

    Under the probability measure Q, the Eqs (2.5) and (2.6) can be respectively rewritten as follows:

    dXu(t)=[rXu+(b1r)π1(t)+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+q(t)n2μq(t)σ0θ0π1(t)σ1θ1Sδ11(t)]dt+q(t)σ0dWQ0(t)+π1(t)σ1Sδ11(t)dWQ1(t), (3.2)
    dYu(t)=[rYu+(b2r)π2(t)+n2μ(1q(t))σ0θ0(1q(t))π2(t)σ2θ2Sδ22(t)]dt+(1q(t))σ0dWQ0(t)+π2(t)σ2Sδ22(t)dWQ2(t). (3.3)

    The Eqs (2.3) and (2.4) become

    dS1(t)=S1(t)[(b1σ1θ1Sδ11(t))dt+σ1Sδ11(t)dWQ1(t)], (3.4)
    dS2(t)=S2(t)[(b2σ2θ2Sδ22(t))dt+σ2Sδ22(t)dWQ2(t)]. (3.5)

    Correspondingly, the differential of historical loss information v in Eq (2.2) becomes

    dv(t)=β(μv(t)+σ0θ0)dtβσ0dWQ0(t). (3.6)

    The value functions in Eq (3.1) ignore the uncertainty of the model, but the ambiguity-averse insurer (AAI) and ambiguity-averse reinsurer (AAR) are skeptical about the accuracy of the reference model P, and they choose Q as a probability measure for the alternative model from Q. Actually, the ambiguity-averse policy maker wants to find the worst alternative from the available alternatives to deal with the mean-variance optimization problem. Inspired by Maenhout [19], Yi et al. [21] and Yuan et al. [31], we modify the objective functions of the AAI and AAR as robust optimization problems formulated by the following equations:

    JQ,ux=EQt,x,y,v,s1,s2[Xt,x,y,v,s1,s2(T)]γ12VarQt,x,y,v,s1,s2[Xt,x,y,v,s1,s2(T)]+EQ[hx(QP)],JQ,uy=EQt,x,y,v,s1,s2[Yt,x,y,v,s1,s2(T)]γ22VarQt,x,y,v,s1,s2[Yt,x,y,v,s1,s2(T)]+EQ[hy(QP)],

    where h(QP) is a penalty function that measures the relative entropy between Q and P, and also reflects the decision maker's confidence in the reference model P. Correspondingly, the weighted sum objective criterion considering model aversion is described by

    supuUinfQQJQ,u(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=supuUinfQQ{αJQ,ux(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)+(1α)JQ,uy(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)}. (3.7)

    A smaller penalty term indicates that the decision maker has less trust in the reference model, and the deviation between the worst-case substitute model and the reference model will be greater. When h(QP)=0, the penalty term disappears and the decision maker has no information about the true model, and all the alternative models are on the equal footing. When h(QP), the ambiguity-averse decision maker strongly believes that the reference model P is the true model, and any substitute model that deviates from P will be punished infinitely. It should be emphasized that the penalty term depends on the relative entropy generated by diffusion risk. The increase in relative entropy from t to t+dt is equal to 12[θ20(t)+θ21(t)]dt in the insurance model, while it is equal to 12[θ20(t)+θ22(t)]dt in the reinsurance model.

    We consider the penalty function of the following form used in Huang et al. [35] and Wang et al. [26],

    hx(QP)=TtΨx(s,Xu(s),v(s),θ(s))ds,hy(QP)=TtΨy(s,Yu(s),v(s),θ(s))ds,

    where

    Ψx(s,Xu(s),v(s),θ(s))=θ20(s)2ϕ0(s,Xu(s),v(s))+θ21(s)2ϕ1(s,Xu(s),v(s)),Ψy(s,Yu(s),v(s),θ(s))=θ20(s)2ϕ0(s,Yu(s),v(s))+θ22(s)2ϕ2(s,Yu(s),v(s)).

    The advantage of this penalty function is that it makes the robustness of the model not dependent on wealth variables X and Y. Based on the approaches of Zeng et al. [10] and Wang et al. [26], we assume that

    ϕ0(t,Xu(t),v(t))=ϕ0(t,Yu(t),v(t))=m0,ϕ1(t,Xu(t),v(t))=m1,ϕ2(t,Yu(t),v(t))=m2,

    where mi0,i=0,1,2, represents the ambiguity-aversion coefficient describing the decision maker's attitude towards diffusion risk. Specifically, we interpret m0 as the degree of ambiguity aversion in the claim process, andm1,m2 as the degree of ambiguity-aversion in the investment market. When mi=0, the policy maker's attitude towards diffusion risk is ambiguity-neutral. It is worth noting that the optimization problem in Eq (3.7) is time-inconsistent, thus the Bellman optimality principle is invalidated. We use game-theoretic methods from Björk and Murgoci [41] and Björk et al. [42] to solve it and derive the time-consistent equilibrium strategy.

    Definition 2. For an admissible strategy u(t)={(π1(t),π2(t),q(t))}t[0,T] with any fixed initial state (t,x,y,v,s1,s2)[0,T]×R×R×R+×R+×R+, we define the following strategy

    uε(λ)={˜u,tλ<t+ε,u(λ),t+ελ<T, (3.8)

    where ˜u=(˜π1,˜π2,˜q), and εR+. If ˜u=(˜π1,˜π2,˜q)R×R×R, we have

    limε0infJu(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)Juε(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)ε0,

    then u is called an equilibrium strategy, and the equilibrium value function is Ju(t,x,y,v,s1,s2).

    For any φ(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)C1,2,2,2,2,2([0,T]×R×R×R+×R+×R+), we denote

    Auφ(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=φt+[rx+(b1r)π1+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+qn2μqσ0θ0π1σ1θ1sδ11]φx+[ry+(b2r)π2+n2(1q)μ(1q)σ0θ0π2σ2θ2sδ22]φy+β(μv+σ0θ0)φv+(b1σ1θ1sδ11)s1φs1+(b2σ2θ2sδ22)s2φs2+12(q2σ20+π21σ21s2δ11)φxx+12[(1q)2σ20+π22σ22s2δ22]φyy+12β2σ20φvv+12σ21s2δ1+21φs1s1+12σ22s2δ2+22φs2s2+q(1q)σ20φxyqβσ20φxv(1q)βσ20φyv+π1σ21s2δ1+11φxs1+π2σ22s2δ2+12φys2.

    Similar to the proof of Theorem 4.1 of Björk and Murgoci [41] and Theorem 1 of Kryger and Steffensen [43], we have the following verification theorem:

    Theorem 3.1 (Verification Theorem). For problem (3.7), if there exist real value functions V(t,x,y,v,s1,s2), g1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2) and g2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)C1,2,2,2,2,2([0,T]×R×R×R+×R+×R+) satisfying the following conditions: (t,x,y,v,s1,s2)[0,T]×R×R×R+×R+×R+,

    supuUinfQQ{AuV(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)αAuγ12(g1(t,x,y,v,s1s2))2+αγ1g1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)Aug1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)(1α)Auγ22(g2(t,x,y,v,s1s2))2+(1α)γ2g2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)Aug2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)+α(θ202m0+θ212m1)+(1α)(θ202m0+θ222m2)}=0,V(T,x,y,v,s1,s2)=αx+(1α)y, (3.9)
    Aug1(t,x,y,v,s1s2)=0,g1(T,x,y,v,s1s2)=x, (3.10)
    Aug2(t,x,y,v,s1s2)=0,g2(T,x,y,v,s1s2)=y, (3.11)

    and

    u:=argsupuUinfQQ{AuV(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)αAuγ12(g1(t,x,y,v,s1s2))2+αγ1g1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)Aug1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)(1α)Auγ22(g2(t,x,y,v,s1s2))2+(1α)γ2g2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)Aug2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)+α(θ202m0+θ212m1)+(1α)(θ202m0+θ222m2)}, (3.12)

    then Ju(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=V(t,x,y,v,s1,s2), Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[Xu(T)]=g1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2), Et,x,y,v,s1,s2[Yu(T)]=g2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2) and u is a time-consistent robust strategy.

    After giving the verification theorem, we now present the main results in Theorem 3.2.

    Theorem 3.2 (Time-consistent robust equilibrium strategy). Let

    L1(t)=αγ1βB3(t)+(1α)γ2er(Tt)+m0(2α1)[n2μσ20m0+βαB3(t)(1α)er(Tt)],L2(t)=ασ22[γ1+m0(2α1)][er(Tt)βB3(t)]n2μ(2α1).

    For the robust optimization problem (3.7), the robust equilibrium strategies and the corresponding equilibrium value function are given by

    q1(t)={0,L1(t)0,˜q1(t),L1(t)>0andL2(t)>0,1,L1(t)>0andL2(t)0, (3.13)

    where

    ˜q1(t)=n2μ(2α1)+σ20[(1α)γ2er(Tt)+m0(2α1)(βA3(t)(1α)er(Tt))+αγ1βB3(t)]σ20[αγ1+(1α)γ2+m0(2α1)2]er(Tt),

    and

    π1(t)=(b1r)+2δ1σ21(γ1B4(t)+m1αA4(t))σ21s2δ11(γ1+m1)er(Tt), (3.14)
    π2(t)=(b2r)+2δ2σ22(γ2C5(t)+m21αA5(t))σ22s2δ22(γ2+m2)er(Tt), (3.15)
    V(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=αer(Tt)x+(1α)er(Tt)y+α(1+n1)r+β(er(Tt)eβ(Tt))v+A4(t)s2δ11+A5(t)s2δ22+A6(t), (3.16)

    where A4(t),B4(t),A5(t),C5(t) and A6(t) are given by Eqs (A.37), (A.36), (A.42), (A.41) and (A.43), respectively.

    Proof. See Appendix A.

    Remark 3.1. If β=0, the loss-dependent premium degenerates to the traditional expected value premium principle, then the robust equilibrium reinsurance strategy under expected value premium is

    q2(t)=n2μ(2α1)+σ20(1α)[γ2m0(2α1)]er(Tt)σ20[αγ1+(1α)γ2+m0(2α1)2]er(Tt).

    The robust equilibrium investment strategies under expected value premium are the same as Eqs (3.14) and (3.15). Since we assumed no correlation between the insurance market and financial market at the outset, the investment strategy is independent of the insurance market parameters.

    Remark 3.2. If mi=0,i=0,1,2, i.e., without considering robustness, the equilibrium optimal reinsurance strategy under loss-dependent premium is

    q3(t)=n2μ(2α1)+σ20[αγ1βB3+(1α)γ2er(Tt)]σ20[αγ1+(1α)γ2]er(Tt).

    The equilibrium optimal investment strategies under loss-dependent premium are

    ˆπ1(t)=b1rγ1σ21s2δ11er(Tt)[1+b1rr(1e2rδ1(tT))],ˆπ2(t)=b2rγ2σ22s2δ22er(Tt)[1+b2rr(1e2rδ2(tT))],

    which are the same as the investment strategies in Li et al. [38].

    Remark 3.3. If β=0 and mi=0,i=0,1,2, i.e., without using loss-dependent premium and without considering robustness, the result in Theorem 3.2 reduces to that in Li et al. [38].

    Remark 3.4. When ρ=1 (i.e., W1(t)=W2(t))), the robust equilibrium reinsurance strategy is the same as Eq (3.13), and the robust equilibrium investment strategy and the corresponding value function are given by the following expressions,

    π1(t)=γ2(1α)m1+γ2(b1r)+2δ1σ21[γ1B4(t)+γ2(1α)m1+γ2(m1A4(t)(1α)m1C4(t))]σ21s2δ11[γ1+αγ2(1α)m1+γ2m1]er(Tt),π2(t)=γ1αm1+γ1(b1r)+2δ1σ21[γ2C4(t)+γ1αm1+γ1(m1A4(t)αm1B4(t))]σ21s2δ11[γ2+(1α)γ1αm1+γ1m1]er(Tt),V(t,x,y,s1)=αer(Tt)x+(1α)er(Tt)y+A3(t)v+A4(t)s2δ11+A5(t).

    The process of solving for A3(t),A4(t),B4(t),C4(t) and A5(t) are similar to that in Appendix A. We omit the detailed derivation here.

    In this section, we present some numerical analysis to study the influencing factors of the robust equilibrium reinsurance-investment strategy and explain the results for better understanding in the economic sense. Unless otherwise specified, the basic parameters are shown in Table 1.

    Table 1.  Some basic parameters.
    Common parameters r μ σ0 α β m0 t T
    0.03 0.5 1.5 0.6 0.12 0.8 0 10
    Insurer n1 γ1 m1 b1 σ1 δ1 s1
    0.2 0.5 1 0.06 6.16 0.6 36
    Reinsurer n2 γ2 m2 b2 σ2 δ2 s2
    0.25 0.6 1.2 0.05 5.16 0.5 26

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    In this part, we consider the sensitivity of the equilibrium reinsurance strategy. Figure 1 shows that the robust equilibrium reinsurance strategy q1(t) decreases as α increases. This is due to the increasing decision-making power of the insurer as α increases. Considering the insurer's preference, it aims to purchase more reinsurance to transfer insurance risk to the reinsurer. When α>0.5, more voices are heard from the insurer in the decision, and the decreasing trend of q1(t) over time is attributed to the fact that, under the principle of loss-dependent insurance premium, the premium paid by policyholders is positively correlated with their past claims. Therefore, this premium principle imposes constraints on policyholders' behavior. A decrease in premiums collected by the insurer leads to a reduction in its retention level. On the other hand, when α<0.5, the reinsurer who apply the expected premium principle are given more priority, and q1(t) also decreases over time. This can be attributed to the accumulation of investment returns in financial markets over time, which increases the wealth of the reinsurer and their risk absorption capacity. Therefore, they are more willing to take on more reinsurance business.

    Figure 1.  The effects of α and t on q1(t).

    Figure 2(a) reveals that the insurer's retention level q1(t) increases with the increase in extrapolation intensity β at the initial stage of decision-making. Moreover, as β becomes larger, q1(t) becomes more sensitive with a larger rate of change. This is attributed to the negative correlation between the dynamic weighted average loss v in Eq (2.2) and the insurer's wealth dynamics in Eq (2.5), which enables risk hedging. As β increases, the insurer's ability to resist risk also increases.

    Figure 2.  Effects of β,t,α and n2 on q1(t).

    From Figure 2(b), it is observed that when α>0.5, q1(t) increases with an increase in safety loading n2, whereas for α<0.5, there is a decreasing trend in q1(t) with an increase in n2. This can be attributed to the fact that when the insurer dominates, the cost of reinsurance becomes more expensive with an increase in safety loading n2, and therefore, the insurer is more inclined to purchase less reinsurance to maintain stable income. Conversely, when the reinsurer dominates, he will gain more profit from reinsurance with an increase in n2, and thus is more willing to accept more reinsurance.

    Figure 3 reveals that q1(t) decreases with an increase in the parameter m0. As m0 increases, the AAI becomes more uncertain towards the claim distribution, and will be more likely to purchase an increased amount of reinsurance to counteract the impact of model uncertainty. Furthermore, q1(t) is a decreasing function of parameter γ1. As γ1 increases, the AAI becomes more risk-averse and will purchase more reinsurance to transfer the risk to the reinsurer. On the other hand, q1(t) is an increasing function of parameter γ2. As γ2 increases, the AAR becomes more risk-averse and thus is more willing to accept less reinsurance.

    Figure 3.  Effects of γ1,γ2 and m0 on q1(t).

    Figures 4-6 illustrate the impact of various variables on the equilibrium reinsurance strategies under three different models. One common observation is that q3(t)>q1(t)>q2(t). The explanation for q1(t)>q2(t) is that, compared to the expected premium principle, the insurer's ability to absorb risk under the loss-dependent premium principle is stronger, reducing the demand for risk transfer through reinsurance. The reason for q3(t)>q1(t) is that, compared to ambiguity-neutral decision makers, the AAI have a greater aversion to model uncertainty, and thus tend to adopt more conservative strategies by transferring more of their risk to the reinsurer, resulting in a higher demand for reinsurance.

    Figure 4.  Effects of t and β on q1(t),q2(t),q3(t).
    Figure 5.  Effects of n2 and m0 on q1(t),q2(t),q3(t).
    Figure 6.  Effects of r1 and r2 on q1(t),q2(t),q3(t).

    In Figure 4(a), it is worth noting that under the expected value premium principle, q2(t) increases with t, while under the loss-dependence premium principle, q1(t) and q3(t) decrease with t. Figure 4(b) shows that as β increases, the change trend of q1(t) and q3(t) are the same, indicating that considering robustness does not affect the correlation between q(t) and β.

    As is shown in Figure 5(a), the equilibrium reinsurance strategies for all three models increase with the increase of n2. From Figure 5(b), we can see that as the ambiguity aversion coefficient m0 increases, both q1(t) and q2(t) show a decreasing trend, which indicates that the impact of robustness on q(t) is similar under the two aforementioned premium principles. Figure 6 illustrates that the correlation between the equilibrium reinsurance strategies of the three models and the risk aversion coefficients γ1 and γ2 is the same.

    In this part, we discuss the impact of model parameters on the equilibrium investment strategy. Here, π1 and π2 represent the robust equilibrium investment strategy of the AAI and AAR, respectively, and π1 and π2 represent the equilibrium investment strategies of the ANI and ANR.

    Figure 7(a) demonstrates the increasing trends of π1(π1) and π2(π2) as t increases. This phenomenon can be attributed to the fact that over time the insurer and reinsurer enhance their risk-bearing capacity while accumulating wealth, consequently leading to a gradual increase in the allocation of investment towards risk assets. From Figure 7(b), we observe that the robust equilibrium investment strategy π1(π2) decreases as the elasticity coefficient δ1(δ2) increases. Higher values of δ may lead to a larger decrease in expected volatility and an increased likelihood of significant adverse movements in the risky asset prices. Therefore, with an increase in δ, both the insurer and reinsurer prefer to reduce their investments in the risky asset to mitigate risks.

    Figure 7.  Effects of t and δ1(δ2) on π1(π2),π1(π2).

    As shown in Figure 8, the robust equilibrium investment strategy for the insurer (reinsurer) is an increasing function of b1(b2), and a decreasing function of r. This is in accordance with our intuition. As b1(b2) increases, the insurer (reinsurer) will obtain higher returns from investments, leading them to increase their investments in risky assets to gain more profits. Furthermore, as r increases, risk-free assets become more attractive, and the insurer (reinsurer) is willing to invest more funds into risk-free assets. Consequently, the amount of investment in risky assets decreases.

    Figure 8.  Effects of b1(b2) and r on π1(π2),π1(π2).

    Figure 9(a) reveals that the coefficient of risk aversion γ1(γ2) has a negative effect on the robust equilibrium investment strategy of the insurer (reinsurer). This means that the insurer (reinsurer) with a higher level of risk aversion will reduce her or his investment in risky assets to avoid risks. Figure 9(b) demonstrates that the insurer (reinsurer) reduces her or his investment in the risky market as the ambiguity-aversion coefficient m1(m2) increases. As mentioned earlier, the ambiguity-aversion coefficient can describe the decision-maker's attitude towards model uncertainty. Therefore, when m1(m2) is larger, the AAI (AAR) is more averse to uncertain risks, and thus is less willing to invest in risky assets.

    Figure 9.  Effects of r1(r2) and m1(m2) on π1(π2),π1(π2).

    Additionally, we can observe the same phenomenon from Figures 7-9: π1>π1;π2>π2. Due to the aversion to the uncertainty of estimating parameters in the risky market, the ambiguity-aversion decision-makers adopt more conservative investment strategies, i.e., reducing risk investments to resist ambiguity uncertainty.

    In this paper, we study the robust equilibrium reinsurance-investment problem for the AAI and the AAR under a mean-variance weighted sum objective criterion. Specifically, it is assumed that the net claims process is approximated by a diffusion process, and the insurer considers the historical claims and adopts the loss-dependent premium principle. However, due to information loss, the reinsurer still employs the traditional expected value premium principle. Both the insurer and reinsurer invest in risk-free and risky assets, where the price process of the risky asset is modeled by the CEV model. After considering the uncertainty of model parameters, we employ robust optimization methods and derive the extended HJB equation. Through dynamic programming theory, we derive closed-form expressions for robust equilibrium reinsurance-investment strategies, as well as their corresponding value functions. We also provide numerical simulations to illustrate the economic implications of our results. We find that the impact of some model parameters on the reinsurance strategy depends on the weighting parameters. In the early stages of decision-making, there is an inverse relationship between extrapolation intensity and reinsurance demand, and employing the loss-dependent premium principle reduces the insurer's demand for reinsurance. Moreover, we find that ambiguity aversion has a significant impact on the reinsurance-investment strategy. As the degree of ambiguity aversion increases, the demand for reinsurance also increases, while the investment in risky assets decreases.

    In future research, it may be worthwhile to consider jump risk asset price processes or Ornstein-Uhlenbeck processes. Additionally, robust optimization objectives can be extended to include Alpha-robust mean-variance criteria. These extensions could provide more complex problems and greatly enrich our research.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 11701087), the Natural Science Foundation of Fujian Province (Nos. 2023J01537, 2023J01538). The authors contributed equally to this work.

    The authors declare that there is no conflict of interest.

    Proof of Theorem 3.2

    In order to solve the extended HJB Eqs (3.9)-(3.11), we postulate the following form of solution,

    V(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=A1(t)x+A2(t)y+A3(t)v+A4(t)s2δ11+A5(t)s2δ22+A6(t), (A.1)
    g1(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=B1(t)x+B2(t)y+B3(t)v+B4(t)s2δ11+B5(t)s2δ22+B6(t), (A.2)
    g2(t,x,y,v,s1,s2)=C1(t)x+C2(t)y+C3(t)v+C4(t)s2δ11+C5(t)s2δ22+C6(t), (A.3)

    with boundary conditions

    A1(T)=α,A2(T)=1α,B1(T)=C2(T)=1,A3(T)=A4(T)=A5(T)=A6(T)=0,B2(T)=B3(T)=B4(t)=B5(T)=B6(T)=C1(T)=C3(T)=C4(T)=C5(T)=C6(T)=0.

    The partial derivatives are

    Vt=A1tx+A2ty+A3tv+A4ts2δ11+A5ts2δ22+A6t,Vx=A1,Vy=A2,Vv=A3,Vs1=2δ1s2δ111A4,Vs2=2δ2s2δ212A5,Vs1s1=2δ1(2δ1+1)s2δ121A4,Vs2s2=2δ2(2δ2+1)s2δ222A5,g1t=B1tx+B2ty+B3tv+B4ts2δ11+B5ts2δ22+B6t,g1x=B1,g1y=B2,g1v=B3,g1s1=2δ1s2δ111B4,g1s2=2δ2s2δ212B5,g1s1s1=2δ1(2δ1+1)s2δ121B4,g1s2s2=2δ2(2δ2+1)s2δ222B5,g2t=C1tx+C2ty+C3tv+C4ts2δ11+C5ts2δ22+C6t,g2x=C1,g2y=C2,g2v=C3,g2s1=2δ1s2δ111C4,g2s2=2δ2s2δ212C5,g2s1s1=2δ1(2δ1+1)s2δ121C4,g2s2s2=2δ2(2δ2+1)s2δ222C5,Vxx=Vyy=Vvv=Vxv=Vyv=Vxy=Vxs1=Vys2=0,g1xx=g1yy=g1vv=g1xv=g1yv=g1xy=g1xs1=g1ys2=0,g2xx=g2yy=g2vv=g2xv=g2yv=g2xy=g2xs1=g2ys2=0, (A.4)

    where V,gi,Ai,Bi and Ci are abbreviations for V(t,x,y,v,s1,s2),gi(t,x,y,v,s1,s2),Ai(t),Bi(t) and Ci(t), respectively.

    Substituting Eqs (A.1)-(A.4) into Eqs (3.9)-(3.11), we have

    supuUinfQQ{A1tx+A2ty+A3tv+A4ts2δ11+A5ts2δ22+A6t+[rx+(b1r)π1+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+qn2μqσ0θ0π1σ1θ1sδ11]A1+[ry+(b2r)π2+n2(1q)μ(1q)σ0θ0π2σ2θ2sδ22]A2+β(μv+σ0θ0)A3(b1σ1θ1sδ11)2δ1s2δ11A4(b2σ2θ2sδ22)2δ2s2δ22A5+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)A4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)A5αγ1[12(q2σ20+π21σ21s2δ11)B21+12((1q)2σ20+π22σ22s2δ22)B22+12β2σ20B23+2σ21δ21s2δ11B24+2σ22δ22s2δ22B25+q(1q)σ20B1B2qβσ20B1B3(1q)βσ20B2B32π1σ21δ1B1B42π2σ22δ2B2B5](1α)γ2[12(q2σ20+π21σ21s2δ11)C21+12((1q)2σ20+π22σ22s2δ22)C22+12β2σ20C23+2σ21δ21s2δ11C24+2σ22δ22s2δ22C25+q(1q)σ20C1C2qβσ20C1C3(1q)βσ20C2C32π1σ21δ1C1C42π2σ22δ2C2C5]+θ202m0+αθ212m1+(1α)θ222m2}=0, (A.5)
    B1tx+B2ty+B3tv+B4ts2δ11+B5ts2δ22+B6t+[rx+(b1r)π1+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+qn2μqσ0θ0π1σ1θ1sδ11]B1+[ry+(b2r)π2+n2(1q)μ(1q)σ0θ0π2σ2θ2sδ22]B2+β(μv+σ0θ0)B3[b1σ1θ1sδ11]2δ1s2δ11B4[b2σ2θ2sδ22]2δ2s2δ22B5+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)B4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)B5=0, (A.6)
    C1tx+C2ty+C3tv+C4ts2δ11+C5ts2δ22+C6t+[rx+(b1r)π1+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ+qn2μqσ0θ0π1σ1θ1sδ11]C1+[ry+(b2r)π2+n2(1q)μ(1q)σ0θ0π2σ2θ2sδ22]C2+β(μv+σ0θ0)C3[b1σ1θ1sδ11]2δ1s2δ11C4[b2σ2θ2sδ22]2δ2s2δ22C5+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)C4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)C5=0. (A.7)

    Based on Eq (A.5), by fixing q,π1,π2 and maximizing over θ, we obtain the following first-order condition for the minimum point θ,

    θ0(q)=m0[qσ0A1+(1q)σ0A2βσ0A3],θ1(π1)=m1σ1α(π1sδ11A12δ1sδ11A4),θ2(π2)=m2σ21α(π2sδ22A22δ2sδ22A5). (A.8)

    Replacing Eq (A.8) back into Eq (A.5) yields

    A1tx+A2ty+A3tv+A4ts2δ11+A5ts2δ22+A6t+[rx+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ]A1+(ry+n2μ)A2+β(μv)A312m0σ20(A2βA3)22b1δ1s2δ11A42b2δ2s2δ22A5+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)A4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)A5αγ1[12σ20B22βσ20B2B3+12β2σ20B23+2σ21δ21s2δ11B24+2σ22δ22s2δ22B25](1α)γ2[12σ20C22βσ20C2C3+12β20σ20C23+2σ21δ21s2δ11C24+2σ22δ22s2δ22C25]+supq{R0(q)}+supπ1{R1(π1)}+supπ2{R2(π2)}=0, (A.9)

    where

    R0(q)=qn2μ(A1A2)m0σ20q(A1A2)(A2βA3)12m0σ20q2(A1A2)2αγ1σ20[12q2(B1B2)2+q(B1B2)(B2βB3)](1α)γ2σ20[12q2(C1C2)2+q(C1C2)(C2βC3)],R1(π1)=(b1r)π1A112π21σ21s2δ11[αγ1B21+(1α)γ2C21]+2π1σ21δ1[αγ1B1B4+(1α)γ2C1C4]m12ασ21(π1sδ11A12δ1sδ11A4)2,R2(π2)=(b2r)π2A212π22σ22s2δ22[αγ1B22+(1α)γ2C22]+2π2σ22δ2[αγ1B2B5+(1α)γ2C2C5]m22(1α)σ22(π2sδ22A22δ2sδ22A5)2.

    Differentiating Eq (A.9) with respect to π1,π2 and q, we obtain the following first-order optimality conditions:

    q=n2μ(A1A2)σ20[αγ1(B1B2)2+(1α)γ2(C1C2)2+m0(A1A2)2]+αγ1(B1B2)(B2βB3)+(1α)γ2(C1C2)(C2βC3)+m0(A1A2)(A2βA3)αγ1(B1B2)2+(1α)γ2(C1C2)2+m0(A1A2)2, (A.10)
    π1=(b1r)A1+2σ21δ1[αγ1B1B4+(1α)γ2C1C4]+m1ασ212δ1A1A4σ21s2δ11[αγ1B21+(1α)γ2C21]+m1ασ21s2δ11A21, (A.11)
    π2=(b2r)A2+2σ22δ2[αγ1B2B5+(1α)γ2C2C5]+m21ασ222δ2A2A5σ22s2δ22[αγ1B22+(1α)γ2C22]+m21ασ22s2δ22A22. (A.12)

    Introducing q,π1,π2 into Eq (A.9) gives

    A1tx+A2ty+A3tv+A4ts2δ11+A5ts2δ22+A6t+[rx+(1+n1)(eβtμ+v)(1+n2)μ]A1+ryA2+n2μA2+β(μv)A32b1δ1s2δ11A42b2δ2s2δ22A5+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)A4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)A5αγ1[12σ20B22βσ20B2B3+12β2σ20B23+2σ21δ21s2δ11B24+2σ22δ22s2δ22B25](1α)γ2[12σ20C22βσ20C2C3+12β20σ20C23+2σ21δ21s2δ11C24+2σ22δ22s2δ22C25]12m0σ20(A2βA3)2+R0(q)+R1(π1)+R2(π2)=0. (A.13)

    By matching the coefficients of variables x,y,v,s1 and s2, we obtain that

    {(A1t+rA1)x=0,(A2t+rA2)y=0,[A3t+(1+n1)A1βA3]v=0, (A.14)
    [A4t2b1δ1A42αγ1σ21δ21B242(1α)γ2σ21δ21C24+s2δ11R1(π1)]s2δ11=0, (A.15)
    [A5t2b2δ2A52αγ1σ22δ22B252(1α)γ2σ22δ22C25+s2δ22R2(π2)]s2δ22=0, (A.16)

    and the rest is

    A6t+[(1+n1)eβtμ+(1+n2)μ]A1+n2μA2+βμA3+δ1σ21(2δ1+1)A4+δ2σ22(2δ2+1)A512m0σ20(A2βA3)212β2σ20[αγ1B23+(1α)γ2C23]12σ20[αγ1B22+(1α)γ2C22]+βσ20[αγ1B2B3+(1α)γ2C2C3]+R0(q)=0. (A.17)

    By substituting q,π1,π2 into Eqs (A.6) and (A.7), and then separating the variables x,y,v,s1 and s2, we can obtain the following equations:

    {(B1t+rB1)x=0,(B2t+rB2)y=0,[B3t+(1+n1)B1βB3]v=0, (A.18)
    B4t+(b1r)π1s2δ11B1m1σ21(π1s2δ11)2A1αB1+2m1δ1σ21π1s2δ11A4αB12b1δ1B4+2δ1m1π1s2δ11σ21A1αB44m1σ21δ21A4αB4=0, (A.19)
    B5t+(b2r)π2s2δ22B2m2σ22(π2s2δ22)2A21αB2+2m2δ2σ22π2s2δ22A51αB22b2δ2B5+2m2δ2σ22π2s2δ22A21αB54m2δ22σ22A51αB5=0, (A.20)
    {(C1t+rC1)x=0,(C2t+rC2)y=0,[C3t+(1+n1)C1βC3]v=0, (A.21)
    C4t+(b1r)π1s2δ11C1m1σ21(π1s2δ11)2A1αC1+2m1δ1σ21π1s2δ11A4αC12b1δ1C4+2m1δ1σ21π1s21δ1A1αC44m1δ21σ21A4αC4=0, (A.22)
    C5t+(b2r)π2s2δ22C2m2σ22(π2s2δ22)2A21αC2+2m2δ2σ22π2s2δ22A51αC22b2δ2C5+2m2δ2σ22π2s2δ22A21αC54m2δ22σ22A51αC5=0, (A.23)

    and the rest is

    B6t+[(1+n1)eβtμ(1+n2)μ]B1+n2μB2+βμB3+qn2μ(B1B2)+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)B4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)B5m0σ20[q(B1B2)+B2βB3][q(A1A2)+A2βA3]=0, (A.24)
    C6t+[(1+n1)eβtμ(1+n2)μ]C1+n2μC2+βμC3+qn2μ(C1C2)+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)C4+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)C5m0σ20[q(C1C2)+C2βC3][q(A1A2)+A2βA3]=0. (A.25)

    Considering the boundary conditions and solving Eqs (A.14), (A.18) and (A.21), we obtain

    {A1(t)=αer(Tt),A2(t)=(1α)er(Tt),B1(t)=C2(t)=er(Tt),B2(t)=C1(t)=C3(t)=0,A3(t)=α1+n1r+β[er(Tt)eβ(Tt)],B3(t)=1+n1r+β[er(Tt)eβ(Tt)]. (A.26)

    Inputting Eqs (A.26) into (A.20), (A.22) and simplifying, we have

    B5t+[2m2δ2[(b2r)(1α)+2σ22δ2(1α)γ2C52γ2δ2σ22A5](1α)(γ2+m2)2b2δ2]B5=0, (A.27)
    C4t+[2m1δ1[(b1r)α+2δ1σ21γ1αB42δ1σ21γ1A4]α(γ1+m1)2b1δ1]C4=0. (A.28)

    With the boundary condition B5(T)=0,C4(T)=0, we can find that B5(t) and C4(t) have the following solutions:

    B5(t)=0,C4(t)=0. (A.29)

    Substituting the solutions (A.29) into (A.15) and (A.19), we have

    A4t2b1δ1A4+2δ1(b1r)m1γ1+m1A4+2αδ1(b1r)γ1γ1+m1B42ασ21δ21γ1m1γ1+m1[B24+(A4α)22B4A4α]+α(b1r)22σ21(γ1+m1)=0, (A.30)
    B4t2b1δ1B4+2δ1(b1r)2γ1m1(γ1+m1)2A4α+2δ1(b1r)γ21+m21(γ1+m1)2B4+4σ21δ21γ1m21(γ1+m1)2[B24+(A4α)22B4A4α]+γ1(b1r)2σ21(γ1+m1)2=0. (A.31)

    Denote I1(t):=A4(t)+α(γ1+m1)2m1B4(t), hence I1t=A4t+α(γ1+m1)2m1B4t and I1(T)=0.

    Combining Eqs (A.31) and (A.30), we obtain the following equation

    I1t2δ1rI1+α(b1r)22m1σ21=0. (A.32)

    Solving Eq (A.32) with I1(T)=0, we obtain

    I1(t)=α(b1r)24m1δ1rσ21[1e2δ1r(Tt)]. (A.33)

    Plugging A4=I1α(r1+m1)2m1B4 into Eq (A.31) implies

    B4t+[2δ1(b1r)m1(m1γ1)(m1+γ1)22b1δ1δ1(b1r)2(γ1+3m1)γ1(γ1+m1)2r(1e2δ1r(Tt))]B4+σ21δ21γ1(γ1+3m1γ1+m1)2B24+(b1r)2γ1(γ1+m1)2σ21[b1r2r(1e2δ1r(Tt))+1]2=0. (A.34)

    Let

    k1=σ21δ21r1(γ1+3m1γ1+m1)2,k2=2δ1(b1r)m1(m1γ1)(m1+γ1)22b1δ1δ1(b1r)2(γ1+3m1)γ1(γ1+m1)2r(1e2δ1r(Tt)),k3=(b1r)2r1(γ1+m1)2σ21[b1r2r(1e2δ1r(Tt))+1]2.

    Then, the Eq (A.34) can be written as

    B4t+k1B24+k2B4+k3=0. (A.35)

    This is a regular Riccati equation satisfying k224k1k3>0, and the solution of the Eq (A.35) with the boundary condition B4(T)=0 is given by

    B4(t)=M1+etN1k1N1(etN1eTN1)1M1eTN1, (A.36)

    where

    N1=k224k1k3,M1=k2N12k1.

    Plugging Eq (A.36) into A4(t)=I1(t)α(r1+m1)2m1B4(t), we obtain

    A4(t)=I1(t)α(r1+m1)2m1(M1+etN1k1N1(etN1eTN1)1M1eTN1). (A.37)

    Substituting the solutions (A.29) into (A.16) and (A.20), we have

    A5t2b2δ2A5+2δ2(b2r)m2γ2+m2A5+2(1α)δ2(b2r)γ2γ2+m2C52(1α)δ22σ22γ2m2γ2+m2[C25+(A51α)22C5(A51α)]+(1α)(b2r)22(γ2+m2)σ22=0, (A.38)
    C5t2b2δ2C5+2δ2(b2r)2γ2m2(γ2+m2)2A51α+2δ2(b2r)γ22+m22(γ2+m2)2C5+4σ22δ22γ2m22(γ2+m2)2[C25+(A51α)22C5A51α]+γ2(b2r)2σ22(γ2+m2)2=0. (A.39)

    Referring to the procedure used to solve for A4,B5, we can derive the Riccati equation for C5 as follows

    C5t+l1C25+l2C5+l3=0, (A.40)

    where

    l1=σ22δ22γ2(γ2+3m2γ2+m2)2,l2=2δ2(b2r)m2(m2γ2)(m2+γ2)22b2δ2δ2(b2r)2(γ2+3m2)γ2(γ2+m2)2r(1e2δ2r(Tt)),l3=(b2r)2γ2(γ2+m2)2σ22[b2r2r(1e2δ2r(Tt))+1]2.

    This Riccati equation satisfies l224l1l3>0. Using standard methods, we can obtain the solution of the Eq (A.40) with C5(T)=0 as

    C5(t)=M2+etN2l1N2(etN2eTN2)1M2eTN2, (A.41)

    where

    N2=l224l1l3,M2=l2N22l1.

    Correspondingly, we have

    A5(t)=I2(t)(1α)(γ2+m2)2m2(M2+etN2l1N2(etN2eTN2)1M2eTN2), (A.42)

    where

    I2(t)=(1α)(b2r)24m2δ2rσ22[1e2δ2r(Tt)].

    By plugging the aforementioned results into Eqs (A.10), (A.11) and (A.12), the robust equilibrium strategy as described in Theorem 3.2 can be obtained.

    Subsequently, by substituting the aforementioned results into Eqs (A.17), (A.24) and (A.25), and incorporating the boundary conditions A6(T)=B6(T)=C6(T)=0, we can derive the following solutions:

    A6(t)=Tt[(1+n1)eβsμ+(1+n2)μ]A1(s)ds+Ttn2μA2(s)+βμA3(s)ds+δ1σ21(2δ1+1)TtA4(s)ds+δ2σ22(2δ2+1)TtA5(s)ds12m0σ20Tt(A2(s)βA3(s))2ds12β2σ20αγ1TtB23(s)ds12σ20(1α)γ2TtC22(s)ds+TtR0[q(s)]ds, (A.43)
    B6(t)=Tt[(1+n1)eβsμ(1+n2)μ+n2μq(s)]B1(s)ds+TtβμB3(s)+σ21δ1(2δ1+1)B4(s)ds+m0σ20Tt[βB3(s)q(s)B1(s)][q(s)(A1(s)A2(s))+A2(s)βA3(s)]ds, (A.44)
    C6(t)=Ttn2μC2(s)(1q(s))ds+σ22δ2(2δ2+1)TtC5(s)dsm0σ20TtC2(s)(1q(s))[q(s)(A1(s)A2(s))+A2(s)βA3(s)]ds. (A.45)

    Above all, the proof of Theorem 3.2 is completed.



    [1] S. Browne, Optimal investment policies for a firm with a random risk process: Exponential utility and minimizing the probability of ruin, Math. Oper. Res., 20 (1995), 937-958. https://doi.org/10.1287/moor.20.4.937 doi: 10.1287/moor.20.4.937
    [2] S. D. Promislow, V. R. Young, Minimizing the probability of ruin when claims follow brownian motion with drift, North Am. Actuarial J., 9 (2005), 110-128. https://doi.org/10.1080/10920277.2005.10596214 doi: 10.1080/10920277.2005.10596214
    [3] X. Liang, V. R. Young, Minimizing the probability of ruin: Two riskless assets with transaction costs and proportional reinsurance, Stat. Probab. Lett., 140 (2018), 167-175. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spl.2018.05.005 doi: 10.1016/j.spl.2018.05.005
    [4] H. Yang, L. Zhang, Optimal investment for insurer with jump-diffusion risk process, Insur. Math. Econ., 37 (2005), 615-634. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2005.06.009 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2005.06.009
    [5] L. Bai, J. Guo, Optimal proportional reinsurance and investment with multiple risky assets and no-shorting constraint, Insur. Math. Econ., 42 (2008), 968-975. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.11.002
    [6] Z. Liang, K. C. Yuen, J. Guo, Optimal proportional reinsurance and investment in a stock market with Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, Insur. Math. Econ., 49 (2011), 207-215. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2011.04.005 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2011.04.005
    [7] A. Gu, F. G. Viens, B. Yi, Optimal reinsurance and investment strategies for insurers with mispricing and model ambiguity, Insur. Math. Econ., 72 (2017), 235-249. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.11.007 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.11.007
    [8] C. Fu, A. Lari-Lavassani, X. Li, Dynamic mean-variance portfolio selection with borrowing constraint, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 200 (2010), 312-319. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2009.01.005 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2009.01.005
    [9] Y. Shen, Y. Zeng, Optimal investment-reinsurance strategy for mean-variance insurers with square-root factor process, Insur. Math. Econ., 62 (2015), 118-137. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.03.009 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.03.009
    [10] Y. Zeng, D. Li, A. Gu, Robust equilibrium reinsurance-investment strategy for a mean-variance insurer in a model with jumps, Insur. Math. Econ., 66 (2016), 138-152. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.10.012 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.10.012
    [11] Z. Sun, K. C. Yuen, J. Guo, A BSDE approach to a class of dependent risk model of mean-variance insurers with stochastic volatility and no-short selling, J. Comput. Appl. Math., 366 (2020), 112413. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2019.112413 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2019.112413
    [12] H. Fung, G. C. Lai, G. A. Patterson, R. C. Witt, Underwriting cycles in property and liability insurance: an empirical analysis of industry and by-line data, J. Risk. Insur., 65 (1998), 539-561. https://doi.org/10.2307/253802 doi: 10.2307/253802
    [13] G. Niehaus, A.Terry, Evidence on the time series properties of insurance premiums and causes of the underwriting cycle: new support for the capital market imperfection hypothesis, J. Risk. Insur., 60 (1993), 466-479. https://doi.org/10.2307/253038 doi: 10.2307/253038
    [14] N. Barberis, R.Greenwood, L. Jin, A. Shleifer, X-CAPM: An extrapolative capital asset pricing model, J. Financ. Econ., 115 (2015), 1-24. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.08.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.08.007
    [15] S. Chen, D. Hu, H. Wang, Optimal reinsurance problems with extrapolative claim expectation, Optim. Control Appl. Methods, 39 (2018), 78-94. https://doi.org/10.1002/oca.2335 doi: 10.1002/oca.2335
    [16] D. Hu, H. Wang, Optimal proportional reinsurance with a loss-dependent premium principle, Scand. Actuarial J., 2019 (2019), 752-767. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2019.1604426 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2019.1604426
    [17] Z. Chen, P. Yang, Robust optimal reinsurance-investment strategy with price jumps and correlated claims, Insur. Math. Econ., 92 (2020), 27-46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2020.03.001 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2020.03.001
    [18] E. W. Anderson, L. P. Hansen, T. J. Sargent, A quartet of semigroups for model specification, robustness, prices of risk, and model detection, J. Eur. Econ. Assoc., 1 (2003), 68-123. https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603322256774 doi: 10.1162/154247603322256774
    [19] P. J. Maenhout, Robust portfolio rules and asset pricing, Rev. Financ. Stud., 17 (2004), 951-983. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhh003 doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhh003
    [20] X. Zhang, T. K. Siu, Optimal investment and reinsurance of an insurer with model uncertainty, Insur. Math. Econ., 45 (2009), 81-88. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2009.04.001 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2009.04.001
    [21] B. Yi, Z. Li, F. G. Viens, Y. Zeng, Robust optimal control for an insurer with reinsurance and investment under Heston's stochastic volatility model, Insur. Math. Econ., 53 (2013), 601-614. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.08.011 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.08.011
    [22] B. Yi, F. Viens, Z. Li, Y. Zeng, Robust optimal strategies for an insurer with reinsurance and investment under benchmark and mean-variance criteria, Scand. Actuarial J., 2015 (2015), 725-751. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2014.883085 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2014.883085
    [23] X. Zheng, J. Zhou, Z. Sun, Robust optimal portfolio and proportional reinsurance for an insurer under a CEV model, Insur. Math. Econ., 67 (2016), 77-87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.12.008 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.12.008
    [24] D. Li, Y. Zeng, H. Yang, Robust optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance and investment strategy for an insurer in a model with jumps, Scand. Actuarial J., 2018 (2018), 145-171. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2017.1309679 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2017.1309679
    [25] A. Gu, F. G. Viens, Y. Shen, Optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance contract with ambiguity aversion in the principal-agent model, Scand. Actuarial J., 2020 (2020), 342-375. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2019.1669218 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2019.1669218
    [26] N. Wang, N. Zhang, Z. Jin, L. Qian, Reinsurance-investment game between two mean-variance insurers under model uncertainty, J. Comput. Appl. Math., 382 (2021), 113095. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2020.113095 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2020.113095
    [27] V. Asimit, T. J. Boonen, Insurance with multiple insurers: A game-theoretic approach, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 267 (2018), 778-790. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2017.12.026 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2017.12.026
    [28] T. J. Boonen, W. Jiang, Mean-variance insurance design with counterparty risk and incentive compatibility, ASTIN Bull., 52 (2022), 645-667. https://doi.org/10.1017/asb.2021.36 doi: 10.1017/asb.2021.36
    [29] S. C. Zhuang, T. J. Boonen, K. S. Tan, Z. Q. Xu, Optimal insurance in the presence of reinsurance, Scand. Actuarial J., 2017 (2017), 535-554. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2016.1184710 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2016.1184710
    [30] L. Chen, Y. Shen, Stochastic Stackelberg differential reinsurance games under time-inconsistent mean-variance framework, Insur. Math. Econ., 88 (2019), 120-137. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2019.06.006 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2019.06.006
    [31] Y. Yuan, Z. Liang, X. Han, Robust reinsurance contract with asymmetric information in a stochastic Stackelberg differential game, Scand. Actuarial J., 2022 (2022), 328-355. https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2021.1971756 doi: 10.1080/03461238.2021.1971756
    [32] X. Zhao, M. Li, Q. Si, Optimal investment-reinsurance strategy with derivatives trading under the joint interests of an insurer and a reinsurer, Electron. Res. Arch., 30 (2022), 4619-4634. https://doi.org/10.3934/era.2022234 doi: 10.3934/era.2022234
    [33] G. Guan, X. Hu, Equilibrium mean-variance reinsurance and investment strategies for a general insurance company under smooth ambiguity, North Am. J. Econ. Finance, 63 (2022), 101793. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2022.101793 doi: 10.1016/j.najef.2022.101793
    [34] P. Yang, Robust optimal reinsurance strategy with correlated claims and competition, AIMS Math., 8 (2023), 15689-15711. https://doi.org/10.3934/math.2023801 doi: 10.3934/math.2023801
    [35] Y. Huang, Y. Ouyang, L. Tang, J. Zhou, Robust optimal investment and reinsurance problem for the product of the insurer's and the reinsurer's utilities, J. Comput. Appl. Math., 344 (2018), 532-552. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2018.05.060 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2018.05.060
    [36] Q. Zhang, Robust optimal proportional reinsurance and investment strategy for an insurer and a reinsurer with delay and jumps, J. Ind. Manage. Optim., 19 (2023), 8207-8244. https://doi.org/10.3934/jimo.2023036 doi: 10.3934/jimo.2023036
    [37] L. Chen, X. Hu, M. Chen, Optimal investment and reinsurance for the insurer and reinsurer with the joint exponential utility under the CEV model, AIMS Math., 8 (2023), 15383-15410. https://doi.org/10.3934/math.2023786 doi: 10.3934/math.2023786
    [38] D. Li, X. Rong, H. Zhao, Time-consistent reinsurance-investment strategy for an insurer and a reinsurer with mean-variance criterion under the CEV model, J. Comput. Appl. Math., 283 (2015), 142-162. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2015.01.038 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2015.01.038
    [39] D. Li, X. Rong, Y. Wang, H. Zhao, Equilibrium excess-of-loss reinsurance and investment strategies for an insurer and a reinsurer, Commun. Stat. Theory Methods, 51 (2022), 7496-7527. https://doi.org/10.1080/03610926.2021.1873379 doi: 10.1080/03610926.2021.1873379
    [40] A. Y. Golubin, Pareto-optimal insurance policies in the models with a premium based on the actuarial value, J. Risk Insur., 73 (2006), 469-487. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6975.2006.00184.x doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2006.00184.x
    [41] T. Björk, A. Murgoci, A general theory of Markovian time inconsistent stochastic control problems, 2010. Available from: http://www.ssrn.com/abstract = 1694759.
    [42] T. Björk, M. Khapko, A. Murgoci, On time-inconsistent stochastic control in continuous time, Finance Stochastics, 21 (2017), 331-360. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-017-0327-5 doi: 10.1007/s00780-017-0327-5
    [43] E. M. Kryger, M. Steffensen, Some solvable portfolio problems with quadratic and collective objectives, 2010. Available from: http://www.ssrn.com/abstract = 1577265.
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1228) PDF downloads(47) Cited by(0)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog