
Citation: Yu Murayama. Inequality, mobility, and growth[J]. National Accounting Review, 2019, 1(1): 62-70. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2019.1.62
[1] | Cheng Li . Unequal wealth of nations: Evidence from the World Bank wealth accounts. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(3): 384-406. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024018 |
[2] | Jinhong Wang, Yanting Xu . Factors influencing the transition of China's economic growth momentum. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(2): 220-244. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024010 |
[3] | Ming He, Barnabé Walheer . Technology intensity and ownership in the Chinese manufacturing industry: A labor productivity decomposition approach. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 110-137. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020007 |
[4] | Liming Chen, Zhi Zhang, Fangyuan Chen, Na Zhou . A study on the relationship between economic growth and energy consumption under the new normal. National Accounting Review, 2019, 1(1): 28-41. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2019.1.28 |
[5] | Sweta C. Saxena, Giuseppe Tesoriere, Syed T. Ahmed, Wafa Aidi . Building new social contracts: a critical review of ideas and actions to fulfill African aspirations through education. National Accounting Review, 2025, 7(1): 85-105. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2025004 |
[6] | Vladimir Hlasny . Market and home production earnings gaps in Russia. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(2): 108-124. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023007 |
[7] | Serhii Shvets . Public investment as a growth driver for a commodity-exporting economy: Sizing up the fiscal-monetary involvement. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 95-115. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024005 |
[8] | Mei Liu, Qing-Ping Ma . The impact of saving rate on economic growth in Asian countries. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(4): 412-427. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022023 |
[9] | Giorgio Colacchio, Anna Serena Vergori . GDP growth rate, tourism expansion and labor market dynamics: Applied research focused on the Italian economy. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 310-328. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022018 |
[10] | Daniel Francois Meyer . Economic sectoral diversification: A case study of the Gauteng provincial region, South Africa. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(4): 356-372. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023021 |
The relationship between inequality and growth has been a major concern of macroeconomics. Most of the literature of the 1990s, e.g., Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Perotti (1996), and Persson and Tabellini (1994), theoretically and empirically shows that inequality negatively affects growth. On the other hand, Barro (2000) empirically shows that although higher inequality reduces growth in poorer countries, it encourages growth in richer countries. Although the literature on inequality and growth has expanded enormously in recent years, the positive relationship between inequality and growth in advanced economies remains insufficiently studied from a theoretical viewpoint. We therefore try to develop a theoretical model that can explain it.
In this paper, the relationship between inequality and growth is analyzed jointly with intergenerational mobility. Intergenerational mobility refers to the correlation of economic status between parents and their children. The reason why we use mobility is that inequality and mobility are strongly related. Inequality—in particular, wage inequality—has both a negative effect and a positive effect on educational decisions that determine, to a substantial degree, future economic status. The negative effect is unequal opportunity: rich parents invest more in the education of their children than poor ones; hence, inequality persists across generations and mobility is low. On the positive side, greater wage inequality (meaning a greater skill premium) increases incentives for education acquisition and therefore increases upward intergenerational mobility flow (the measure of poor-born children that become rich) and decreases downward intergenerational mobility flow (the measure of rich-born children that become poor). Empirical studies have shown both a positive correlation between inequality and mobility (Rodriguez et al., 2008) and a negative correlation (Andrews and Leigh, 2009). Theoretically, Hassler et al. (2007) give an interesting and tractable explanation for these findings. This paper extends the scope of investigation to the relationship between three factors: inequality, mobility, and growth.
To serve our purpose, our model is based on the earlier work of Maoz and Moav (1999), which studied the dynamic relationship between wage inequality, mobility, and growth. The defining features of their model can be summarized as follows. First, there is heterogeneity in the learning ability of individuals that can be represented as differences in the cost of acquiring the education necessary to become an educated worker. Second, the decision to invest in education is determined by the net benefit of acquiring an education. The threshold level of the cost of education below which individuals will seek to acquire an education is endogenous. Third, capital markets are assumed to be imperfect: educational loans are unavailable, and individuals cannot accumulate wealth. Therefore, some children may not be able to acquire an education.
We assume that wage inequality between educated and uneducated workers widens because of skill-biased technological change, which is not considered in Maoz and Moav (1999), but is a topic of much recent research. There is a consensus that recent technological progress such as the development of information technology raises the productivity of educated workers relative to uneducated workers, increasing the wage gap between them in advanced countries. In addition, we introduce education subsidies, since many governments offer these. Using this model, we are able to show that higher inequality increases upward mobility and decreases downward mobility, and thus increases the number of educated workers and thereby growth.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the model; Section 3 analyzes the evolution of the economy; Section 4 examines the impact of inequality; and Section 5 summarizes the results.
In the proposed model, the economy produces a single homogeneous good under conditions of perfect competition with a CES (constant elasticity of substitution) production function that uses educated and uneducated labor as input. The goods can be used for either consumption or investment in education. We define the number of educated and uneducated workers in period t as Et and Ut, respectively. We normalize the total number of individuals supplying labor to one and assume that each individual supplies one unit of labor inelastically. Therefore, Et and Ut=1−Et represent the amounts of educated and uneducated labor, respectively.
The production function takes the form
Yt=F(A,Et,Ut), | (1) |
where Yt is output in period t and A>1 is a productivity parameter that is assumed to affect educated labor.
Let us assume that educated and uneducated labor are perfect substitutes.1 Then, Equation (1) takes the following specific form:
1.This differs from Maoz and Moav's (1999) model, which uses the Cobb-Douglas production function. If we use the Cobb-Douglas one such that the inputs are complements, the analysis becomes more complicated, since the number of educated workers in the future affects the individual's decision regarding the acquisition of education, as well as intergenerational mobility. For details, see footnote 4.
Yt=AEt+Ut=(A−1)Et+1, | (2) |
Wages are given by the marginal productivities. If we define wet (wut) as the wage of an educated (uneducated) worker in period t, then
wet=we=A, wut=wu=1, | (3) |
where the superscripts e and u indicate educated and uneducated, respectively. From Equation (3), the ratio of educated to uneducated wages, we/wewuwu, which is our measure of wage inequality, is A.
Individuals live for two periods in overlapping generations (see Figure 1). There is no population growth, and in every time period a generation of size one is born. Individuals are heterogeneous with respect to their innate learning ability and parental education level.
In the first period of life (childhood), the individual is a consumer; during this period, he/she decides whether to acquire education and does not work. The consumption and education costs are financed by a bequest from the parent and through education subsidies provided by the government. Education subsidies are available to all children who choose to acquire education. Payment is proportional to the education costs of the child and is financed by a proportional tax on wages. In the second period of life (adulthood), the individual works and makes a bequest of all wealth to his/her child. The individual can work as an educated worker if and only if he/she acquires education in the first period of life.
Individuals gain utility from their consumption in the first period of life and their bequest to their child in the second period of life. The parents' bequest motive takes the form of paternalistic altruism: they are concerned for the wealth of their children, apart from their own consumption, in the second period of life. All individuals have identical preferences:
uit=logcit+logxit+1 | (4) |
where cit is consumption in period t and xit+1 is the bequest to the child born in period t+1.
Let θi, st∈(0,1), and τ∈(0,1) denote the education cost of individual i, the rate of education subsidy in period t, and a proportional tax rate on wages, respectively. θi represents the learning ability of the child in that the higher the ability, the lower the θi cost.2 These costs are uniformly distributed in the interval (θ_,ˉθ), where θ_≥0, and the ability of a child does not depend on the ability of his/her parent.
2 In reality, higher-ability children learn faster than lower-ability children. Thus, from a theoretical viewpoint, the education cost required for higher-ability children to become educated is lower than the cost for lower-ability children.
We assume that capital markets are imperfect: Educational loans are unavailable and individuals cannot accumulate wealth.3 If an individual acquires education, then his/her budget constraints are
3 For example, Getachew (2016) remarks that even in advanced economies, there can be a borrowing constraint because of the substantially high cost of administrating credit.
cit+(1−st)θi=xit, xit+1=(1−τ)we, | (5) |
where xit is the bequest from the individual's parent when he/she is born in period t. If he/she does not acquire education, then the constraints are
cit=xit, xit+1=(1−τ)wu. | (6) |
Young individual i will acquire education if and only if the utility derived from investing in education, log[xit−(1−st)θi]+log(1−τ)we, is greater than or equal to the utility derived from not investing in education, logxit+log(1−τ)wu:
log[xit−(1−st)θi]+log(1−τ)we⩾logxit+log(1−τ)wu. | (7) |
From Equation (7), we obtain the critical value of the education cost for individual i of generation t, ˆθit, such that only those individuals with an education cost below the threshold, θi⩽ˆθit, acquire education.
We assume that the individual's learning ability and educational investment are observable through school education: the government knows θi and ˆθit. Then, the government's budget constraint is
ˆθit∫θ_stθif(θi)dθi=stˉθ−θ_θit∫θ_θidθi=τYt, | (8) |
where f(θi) is the density function of θi.
Equation (8) can be rewritten as follows:
st=2(ˉθ−θ_)τYt(ˆθit)2−θ_2. | (9) |
From Equation (7), using Equation (2) and Equation (3), and (9), ˆθit is defined as the solution of
(ˆθit)3−xit(1−1A)(ˆθit)2−[θ_2+2(ˉθ−θ_)τ{(A−1)Et+1}]θit+xit(1−1A)θ_2=0. | (10) |
In order to simplify the analysis, the remainder of the paper makes the following two assumptions.
Assumption 1 θ_=0.
This assumption implies that the acquisition of education does not involve any cost for the highest ability individual. Under this assumption, ˆθit is given by
ˆθit=xit(1−1/1AA)±√(xit)2(1−1/1AA)2+8ˉθτ{(A−1)Et+1}2. | (11) |
The bequest from his/her parent, xit, is xet=(1−τ)we=(1−τ)A if the individual is born to an educated parent, and xut=(1−τ)wu=1−τ if born to an uneducated parent. Suppose that ˆθet (ˆθut) is the critical value of the education cost for the individual born to an educated (uneducated) parent.
The temporal evolution of Et is explained by two types of intergenerational mobility: upward and downward. Upward mobility means that an individual born to an uneducated parent acquires education, whereas downward mobility means that an individual born to an educated parent does not acquire education. The level of upward mobility in period t, UMt, and the level of downward mobility in period t, DMt, are respectively given by
UMt=(1−Et)F(ˆθut)=(1−Et)ˆθutˉθ, DMt=Et[1−F(ˆθet)]=Etˉθ−ˆθetˉθ, | (12) |
where F(⋅) is the cumulative distribution function of θi. Et will increase if and only if UMt exceeds DMt. Therefore, the dynamics of Et can be expressed as Et+1−Et=UMt−DMt. The upward and downward mobility levels are equal in the steady state: UMt=DMt. We define the steady-state level of Et as E∗, where Et=Et+1=E∗.
We make the following assumption in order to avoid a condition of no economic development.
Assumption 2 ˆθit>0.
If ˆθit=0, the most talented child will be indifferent to education investment, and no others will choose to invest. When ˆθit<0, no one will invest in acquiring education. Thus, if ˆθit⩽0, all children born to educated parents move downward and all children born to uneducated parents remain uneducated. Since only downward mobility occurs, the number of educated workers approaches 0, which is the steady-state level. This case might be expressed as a poverty trap, where the number of educated workers and output decrease to their lowest levels of 0 and 1, respectively.
Based on Assumption 2, Equation (11) is rewritten as4
4 If we suppose a Cobb-Douglas production function, Yt=AE1−αtUαt, then we and wu in Equation (7) are replaced with wet+1=(1−α)A[(1−Et+1)/(1−Et+1)Et+1Et+1]α and wut+1=αA[(1−Et+1)/(1−Et+1)Et+1Et+1]α−1, respectively. Since Et+1 affects ˆθit, the dynamics of mobility become more complicated
ˆθit=xit(1−1/1AA)+√(xit)2(1−1/1AA)2+8ˉθτ{(A−1)Et+1}2. | (13) |
Equation (13) implies that since education subsidies, τYt=τ{(A−1)Et+1}, increase with Et, ˆθit also increases with Et.
From Equation (13), considering xet=(1−τ)A and xut=1−τ, the thresholds for children of educated and uneducated parents are
ˆθet=(1−τ)A(1−1/1AA)+√{(1−τ)A}2(1−1/1AA)2+8ˉθτ{(A−1)Et+1}2, | (14) |
ˆθut=(1−τ)(1−1/1AA)+√(1−τ)2(1−1/1AA)2+8ˉθτ{(A−1)Et+1}2, | (15) |
respectively. Since xet>xut, it follows that ˆθet>ˆθut. This implies that children of educated parents are more likely to acquire education than children of uneducated parents.
Because ˆθet and ˆθut increase with Et, UMt=(1−Et)ˆθut/ˆθutˉθˉθ and DMt=Et(ˉθ−ˆθet)/(ˉθ−ˆθet)ˉθˉθ are concave. Examples of dynamic paths of UMt, DMt, and Et+1 are illustrated in Figure 2.
Figure 2 shows that Et approaches its interior steady-state value, E∗∈(0,1): in the range Et∈[0,E∗) (Et∈(E∗,1]), Et increases (decreases) monotonically toward E∗ because UMt>DMt(UMt<DMt).
Next, we consider how higher wage inequality caused by skill-biased technological change affects mobility and growth. In our model, skill-biased technological change is described by an increase in productivity parameter A. First, an increase in A increases xet or ˆθet. Second, from Equation (13), ∂ˆθit∂(1−1/1AA)>0; higher wage inequality (an increase in 1−1/1AA) affects ˆθit positively. Therefore, higher wage inequality serves as an additional incentive to invest in education. Third, an increase in A increases education subsidies, as well as ˆθit. We summarize this in the following proposition.
Proposition 1 Higher wage inequality increases ˆθet and ˆθut: it increases UMt and decreases DMt, and therefore increases Et+1, that is, growth.
If wage inequality is sufficiently high such that DMt=0 holds at Et=1, as illustrated in Figure 3, Et increases monotonically toward its corner steady-state value, E∗=1, as time passes because UMt>DMt for every value of Et.
By introducing skill-biased technological change and education subsidies into the model by Maoz and Moav (1999), this paper presents a simple theoretical model to explain the positive relationship between inequality and growth observed in advanced countries.
The analysis has several limitations from being based on a simplified model. The first is that the assumption that the government has full information about the innate ability of a child is unrealistic. This raises the question as to how education subsidies in our model should be modified when the government cannot observe an individual's ability.
A second limitation is that wages in our model are constant regardless of ability. Mobility may affect the average ability in educated and uneducated groups, and hence change wages in each of the groups if wages depend on ability.
These are subjects for further research.
I am grateful to two anonymous referees for their extremely helpful comments. Of course, all remaining errors are mine.
The author declares no conflict of interest in this paper.
[1] | Alesina A, Rodrik D (1994) Distributive Politics and Economic Growth. Q J Econ 109: 465-490. |
[2] | Andrews D, Leigh A (2009) More Inequality, Less Social Mobility. Appl Econ Lett 16: 1489-1492. |
[3] | Barro RJ (2000) Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. J Econ Growth 5: 5-32. |
[4] | Getachew YY (2016) Credit constraints, growth and inequality dynamics. Econ Model 54: 364-376. |
[5] | Hassler J, Rodríguez Mora JV, Zeira J (2007) Inequality and mobility. J Econ Growth 12: 235-259. |
[6] | Maoz YD, Moav O (1999) Intergenerational mobility and the process of development. Econ J 109: 677-697. |
[7] |
Perotti R (1996) Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say. J Econ Growth 1: 149-187. doi: 10.1007/BF00138861
![]() |
[8] | Persson T, Tabellini G (1994) Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Am Econ Rev 84: 600-621. |
[9] | Rodriguez JP, Rodriguez JG, Salas R (2008) A study on the relationship between economic inequality and mobility. Econ Lett 99: 111-114. |
1. | Fanqi Zou, Tinghui Li, Feite Zhou, Does the Level of Financial Cognition Affect the Income of Rural Households? Based on the Moderating Effect of the Digital Financial Inclusion Index, 2021, 11, 2073-4395, 1813, 10.3390/agronomy11091813 |