We prove that Theorem 4.16 in [
Citation: Bernardo D'Auria, José Antonio Salmerón. A note on Insider information and its relation with the arbitrage condition and the utility maximization problem[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(5): 8305-8307. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023362
[1] | Bernardo D'Auria, José Antonio Salmerón . Insider information and its relation with the arbitrage condition and the utility maximization problem. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(2): 998-1019. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020053 |
[2] | Min Zhu, Xiaofei Guo, Zhigui Lin . The risk index for an SIR epidemic model and spatial spreading of the infectious disease. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2017, 14(5&6): 1565-1583. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2017081 |
[3] | Tao Li, Xin Xu, Kun Zhao, Chao Ma, Juan LG Guirao, Huatao Chen . Low-carbon strategies in dual-channel supply chain under risk aversion. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(5): 4765-4793. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022223 |
[4] | Carlos Camilo-Garay, R. Israel Ortega-Gutiérrez, Hugo Cruz-Suárez . Optimal strategies for a fishery model applied to utility functions. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(1): 518-529. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021028 |
[5] | Fangyuan Chen, Siya Chen, Weizhong Yang . Vanishing and spreading conditions for a free-boundary epidemic model with subclinical infections and vaccination. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(7): 6523-6535. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022307 |
[6] | Vincenzo Luongo, Maria Rosaria Mattei, Luigi Frunzo, Berardino D'Acunto, Kunal Gupta, Shankararaman Chellam, Nick Cogan . A transient biological fouling model for constant flux microfiltration. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(1): 1274-1296. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023058 |
[7] | Qiaoling Chen, Fengquan Li, Sanyi Tang, Feng Wang . Free boundary problem for a nonlocal time-periodic diffusive competition model. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 16471-16505. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023735 |
[8] | Qian Ding, Yunfeng Liu, Yuming Chen, Zhiming Guo . Dynamics of a reaction-diffusion SIRI model with relapse and free boundary. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(2): 1659-1676. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020087 |
[9] | Agustín Gabriel Yabo, Jean-Baptiste Caillau, Jean-Luc Gouzé . Optimal bacterial resource allocation: metabolite production in continuous bioreactors. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(6): 7074-7100. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020364 |
[10] | Shayna Berman, Gavin D'Souza, Jenna Osborn, Matthew Myers . Comparison of homemade mask designs based on calculated infection risk, using actual COVID-19 infection scenarios. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(8): 14811-14826. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023663 |
We prove that Theorem 4.16 in [
In this note we show that the result of Theorem 4.16 of [1] is false by constructing a sequence of simple predictable strategies achieving Free-Lunch-with-Vanishing-Risk (FLVR) whose existence contradicts the conclusions of the theorem. The fault in the proof in [1] comes from the improper use of a bound on the compensator αG. Indeed the bound holds only P-almost surely, that is not strong enough to assure the required Novikov condition.
Using the notation introduced in [1], we consider the initial enlargement G⊃F obtained by extending the natural filtration by the random variable
![]() |
(1) |
Assuming a constant proportional volatility ξ>0, it follows that
ST=˜s0exp(ξBT) ,˜s0:=s0exp(∫T0(ηt−ξ2/2)dt) , |
and the random variable G can be rewritten as , where ck:=˜s0eξk. The length of each interval is λk:=c2k−c2k−1=˜s0eξ2k(1−e−ξ)>0. To simplify the computations, we assume that the interest rate r=0.
Proposition 1. Let G be as in (1), the condition (FLVR)H(G) is satisfied.
Proof. Without loss of generality, we assume that, for some t0<T there exists k0∈Z such that c2k0−λk0/4≥St0≥c2k0−1+λk0/4. We reason for the case G=0, that in particular implies that ST∉(c2k0−1,c2k0), the case G=1 is equivalent by symmetry. We define the following finite sets
Aδn:={c2k0−λk04−δ(k0)2n, c2k0−1+λk04+δ(k0)2n} ,n≥0 , |
together with the following sequence of stopping times, τ0=t0 and for n≥1
τ2n−1:=inf{τ2n−2≤t<T:Sτ2n−2∉{c2k0, c2k0−1}, St∈Aδ∞} ,τ2n:=inf{τ2n−1≤t<T:St∈{c2k0, c2k0−1}∪Aδn} . |
where we define inf∅=T. With some abuse of notation, we construct a sequence of strategies {Θn}n with Θ0=0 and for n≥1, being Cn the following Fτ2n−1-measurable random variable
Cn:={+1 if Sτ2n−1=c2k0−λk0/4−1 if Sτ2n−1=c2k0−1+λk0/4 . |
We prove that the sequence of strategies {Θn}n achieves a gain greater than λk04−δ(k0), and by appropriately choosing δ(k0) we can get (FLVR)H(G). To short the notation, we introduce the family
XΘmT=X0+m∑n=1HnCn(Sτ2n−Sτ2n−1)=X0−m∑n=1Hnδ(k0)2n+λk04(1−Hm)≥X0−δ(k0)(1−12m)+λk04(1−Hm)≥X0−δ(k0)+λk04(1−Hm) . |
We need to verify that limm→∞Hm=0, P(⋅|G=0)-a.s. By definition of convergence a.s., it is equivalent to
limm→∞P(Hm<ε|G=0)=1 ,∀ε>0 . |
The sequence of indicator functions is strictly decreasing by construction, so we need to check that
1=limm→∞P(Hm=0|G=0)=limm→∞P(Sτ2n∈{c2k0,c2k0−1} for some n<m|G=0)=limm→∞P(Sτ2n∈{c2k0,c2k0−1} for some n<m|ST∉(c2k0−1,c2k0)) , |
where the last condition is satisfied.
Remark. By using an analogous technique, it can be proved that any random variable generates (FLVR) when B is a subset of positive probability less than one.
Since the result of Theorem 4.16 in [1] is false, we prove here a weaker result by showing that the strategies of type buy-and-hold do not generate arbitrage, (NA), as it is shown in the following proposition.
Proposition 2. Let G be as in (1), the condition (NA)H(G) is satisfied with strategies of the type Θ= , being σ any G-stopping time and C a Gσ-measurable random variable not identically zero.
Proof. We claim that there exists some achieving arbitrage and we look for a contradiction. We start by computing the following conditional probabilities
P(ST<Sσ|Gσ,σ<T)=P(BT<Bσ|Gσ,σ<T)>0 ,P(ST>Sσ|Gσ,σ<T)=P(BT>Bσ|Gσ,σ<T)>0 . | (2) |
We introduce the event A:={C(ST−Sσ)<0}, by the definition of arbitrage we have P(A)=0 and jointly with the law of total probability we find the following contradiction,
0=P(A)=P(C=0)P(A|C=0)+P(C<0)P(A|C<0)+P(C>0)P(A|C>0)=P(C<0)P(ST−Sσ>0)+P(C>0)P(ST−Sσ<0)=P(C<0)E[P(ST>Sσ|Gσ,σ<T)]+P(C>0)E[P(ST<Sσ|Gσ,σ<T)]>0 , |
which is positive because P(C≠0)>0 and the conditional probabilities given by (2).
The authors declare there is no conflict of interest.
[1] |
B. D'Auria, J. A. Salmerón, Insider information and its relation with the arbitrage condition and the utility maximization problem, Math. Biosci. Eng., 17 (2020), 998–1019. 10.3934/mbe.2020053 doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020053
![]() |