Research article Special Issues

Study on the evolutionary strategy of upward patient transfer in the loose medical consortia


  • Medical institutions in loose medical consortia tend to have poor cooperation due to fragmented interests. We aim to explore any issues associated with patient upward transfer in a loose medical consortium system consisting of two tertiary hospitals with both cooperative and competitive relationships. A two-sided evolutionary game model was constructed to assess the stability of equilibrium strategy combinations in the process of interaction between game players under different cost-sharing scenarios and different degrees of penalties when running patient upward transfer between super triple-A hospitals (STH) and general triple-A hospitals (GTH). We found that a hospital's stabilization strategy was related to its revenue status. When a hospital has high/low revenues, it will treat patients negatively/positively, regardless of the strategy chosen by the other hospital. When the hospital has a medium revenue, the strategy choice will be related to the delay cost, delay cost sharing coefficient, government penalty and the strategic choice of the other hospital. Delay cost-sharing coefficient is an important internal factor affecting the cooperation in a medical consortium for patient upward transfer. External interventions, such as government penalty mechanisms, can improve the cooperation between hospitals when hospitals have moderate revenue.

    Citation: Jialing Li, Guiju Zhu, Xinya Hu, Ruqian Fei, Dan Yu, Dong Wang. Study on the evolutionary strategy of upward patient transfer in the loose medical consortia[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 16846-16865. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023751

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xiaochun Chen, Jie Zhao, Yingying Ma, Bo Lv, Xuanjin Du . Tripartite evolutionary game study on coordination information security in prescription circulation. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(12): 21120-21146. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023934
    [2] Zheng Liu, Lingling Lang, Lingling Li, Yuanjun Zhao, Lihua Shi . Evolutionary game analysis on the recycling strategy of household medical device enterprises under government dynamic rewards and punishments. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(5): 6434-6451. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021320
    [3] Yuanyuan Huang, Yiping Hao, Min Wang, Wen Zhou, Zhijun Wu . Optimality and stability of symmetric evolutionary games with applications in genetic selection. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2015, 12(3): 503-523. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2015.12.503
    [4] Bo Lan, Lei Zhuang, Qin Zhou . An evolutionary game analysis of digital currency innovation and regulatory coordination. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(5): 9018-9040. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023396
    [5] Zhihao Zhang, Ting Zeng, Yijia Wang, Yinxia Su, Xianghua Tian, Guoxiang Ma, Zemin Luan, Fengjun Li . Prediction Model of hospitalization time of COVID-19 patients based on Gradient Boosted Regression Trees. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(6): 10444-10458. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023459
    [6] A. Swierniak, M. Krzeslak, D. Borys, M. Kimmel . The role of interventions in the cancer evolution–an evolutionary games approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(1): 265-291. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019014
    [7] Bo An . Construction and application of Chinese breast cancer knowledge graph based on multi-source heterogeneous data. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(4): 6776-6799. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023292
    [8] Dario Madeo, Chiara Mocenni, Jean Carlo Moraes, Jorge P. Zubelli . The role of self-loops and link removal in evolutionary games on networks. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(5): 5287-5306. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019264
    [9] Feiyan Ruan, Xiaotong Ding, Huiping Li, Yixuan Wang, Kemin Ye, Houming Kan . Back propagation neural network model for medical expenses in patients with breast cancer. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(4): 3690-3698. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021185
    [10] Qian Shen . Research of mortality risk prediction based on hospital admission data for COVID-19 patients. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(3): 5333-5351. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023247
  • Medical institutions in loose medical consortia tend to have poor cooperation due to fragmented interests. We aim to explore any issues associated with patient upward transfer in a loose medical consortium system consisting of two tertiary hospitals with both cooperative and competitive relationships. A two-sided evolutionary game model was constructed to assess the stability of equilibrium strategy combinations in the process of interaction between game players under different cost-sharing scenarios and different degrees of penalties when running patient upward transfer between super triple-A hospitals (STH) and general triple-A hospitals (GTH). We found that a hospital's stabilization strategy was related to its revenue status. When a hospital has high/low revenues, it will treat patients negatively/positively, regardless of the strategy chosen by the other hospital. When the hospital has a medium revenue, the strategy choice will be related to the delay cost, delay cost sharing coefficient, government penalty and the strategic choice of the other hospital. Delay cost-sharing coefficient is an important internal factor affecting the cooperation in a medical consortium for patient upward transfer. External interventions, such as government penalty mechanisms, can improve the cooperation between hospitals when hospitals have moderate revenue.



    As per capita life expectancy has increased around the world, the demand for health care has increased significantly. However, the fundamental conflict between limited resources and unlimited demand has put tremendous pressure on healthcare providers. To improve the quality and efficiency of healthcare services, the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan and other countries have taken different measures to restructure and reorganize their healthcare delivery systems since the 1970s, resulting in a more efficient and robust health care model called integrated health care [1]. The World Health Organization (2016) [2] defines integrated health care as a continuum of health promotion, disease prevention, diagnosis, treatment, disease management, rehabilitation and palliative care services, coordinated at different levels and locations within and outside the health sector, according to the whole life course of a person.

    Chinese medical institutions are divided into three levels according to the scale of development, staffing, technical level and service capacity of the hospital [3]. There is no established gatekeeper system in China and patients are free to select hospitals for medical services. Even though the positioning of tertiary hospitals is to provide medical services for patients with complicated diseases, many patients with mild diseases are keen to seek medical services in tertiary hospitals but not in lower-level hospitals, resulting in more people in tertiary hospitals and fewer people in community hospitals. According to the data reported in the 2022 China Health and Family Planning Development Bulletin [4], only 8% of China's healthcare institutions are tertiary public hospitals, but these institutions provide 66% of healthcare services such as inpatient services. In order to alleviate the mismatch between patient flow and hospital level, Chinese healthcare reformers proposed an integrated healthcare model in 2015, called medical consortia, which is an integration of medical resources to form a medical alliance with a regional tertiary hospital and several lower level hospitals such as secondary and community hospitals.

    Medical consortia can be classified by two types, loose and tight, depending on the degree of cooperation. Loose medical consortia are formed mainly through the signing of cooperation agreements on technical cooperation. Hospitals in the loose medical consortia have a weaker cooperation than the tight medical consortia. Thus, the loose medical consortia often encounter problems for compartmentalization of interests, poorer stability, unsustainability and more barriers for patient referrals [5]. Thus, we explored the issues associated with the patient upward transfer in a loose medical consortium consisting of two tertiary hospitals with both cooperative and competitive relationships. The delay cost is incorporated into the evolutionary game model to explore the effect of delay cost-sharing coefficients and government penalties on the evolutionary trajectory of the medical consortia. By constructing a two-sided evolutionary game model for super triple-A hospitals (STH) and general triple-A hospitals (GTH) in a loose medical consortium, we solved and analyzed the stability of equilibrium strategy combinations in the process of interaction between game players under different cost-sharing scenarios and different degrees of penalties. It should be noted that the STHs in this study has a higher level than GTHs. Although they form a loose alliance and GTH have a certain local reputation, GTH still relies on the medical technical support from STH, especially when treating patients with complicated diseases. Figure 1 illustrates the classification standards for Chinese hospitals and the key issues that will be explored in this study.

    Figure 1.  Criteria for classifying hospitals in China and the issue of loose medical consortia.

    This study is relevant to the current literature from two perspectives. First, the integrated health care model is a popular research area in various countries around the world. Since the introduction of integrated health care, the United States, Canada and other countries have conducted a series of studies. Early studies into integrated health care focused primarily on qualitative analysis, such as the definition of integrated health care services [6], measurement methods [7], strategic changes [8] and summaries of practical experiences or cases [9]. Some research has been conducted using questionnaires or metrological methods to study specific aspects of an integrated healthcare system, such as different groups' perceptions of integrated healthcare [10,11], patients' healthcare service quality [12], inter-hospital information synergy [13] and family physicians [14]. Some research has been conducted into the best way to promote the integrated health care with emerging technologies and approaches [15]. For example, Burns et al. [16], used social networks to study relationship coordination and integrated health care and analyze integrated health care at three levels of analysis: micro, meso and macro.

    Second, the evolutionary game approach is a very useful mathematical model that can simulate complex biological and social systems and help with better understanding and predicting their behaviors. This approach can use evolutionary game theory to explore dynamics of strategy (Cooperation or Defection) change under various competing systems in different situations of dilemma game [17]. In recent years, evolutionary game theory has been recognized as an effective tool for analyzing complex interactions among social agents and has been applied to many social issues [18,19], such as industrial pollution [20], supply chain energy conservation and emission reduction [21], agricultural supply chain finance [22], construction waste recycling behavior [23], livestock pollution control [24] and electronic product waste recycling [25]. The main topics of literature related to evolutionary games and medical problems include the multi-subject evolution of sudden public events [26], medical data sharing [27], doctor-patient disputes [28] and other aspects of geriatric health and collaboration [29].

    The main contributions of this article are as follows.

    1) From a research perspective, this study fills the current evidence gap regarding cooperation in the upward referral of patients in the context of loose medical consortia. In recent years, although the issues arising from the evolution between different subjects within an integrated healthcare system has caused a certain attention, the past research mainly focused on tightly-knit medical consortia that consists different core hospitals. Xu et al. [30] constructed an evolutionary game model involving urban tertiary hospitals and rural hospitals and verified the impact of different values through numerical simulations, proving that the urban-rural cooperation mechanism is effective. The majority of subjects in current evolutionary game models for medical clusters are tertiary and community hospitals [31]. Instead, this study focused on the issue of patient referrals from tertiary and community hospitals, which have different positioning and complementary relationships and make cooperation more likely. There are lack of studies using evolutionary game models to simulate the behavioral strategies of hospitals in loose alliances that face the dilemma of poor cooperation.

    2) The simulation in this study is more micro. The two hospitals studied in our study have unequal positions in a loose alliance and they cooperate as well as compete. The current literature on the application of evolutionary games to healthcare consortia can be classified as two main categories. One category focuses on the referral of patients in the same hospital but assess the evolutionary relationship between the hospital and other subjects such as patients and the government [32]. For example, Tao et al. [33] integrated prospect theory into the promotion of the hierarchical diagnosis and treatment system, constructing a three-party evolutionary game model containing local health departments, medical institutions, and patients, and concluded that the amount and duration of financial subsidies had strong impact on the evolution of the game system. The other category focuses on issues within the healthcare consortium other than referral of patients, such as information sharing [34].

    3) From the practice level, this paper explores a two-party evolutionary game model of hospitals with competitive nature based on the context of loose healthcare consortiums in China's national context, which is a fusion of theory and practice. The conclusions of the model should eventually be fed back to the practice level. This paper analyzes how key elements such as different costs, affect the strategic choices of the game's subjects, proposes internal and external constraints on the negative behaviors of loose healthcare associations and thus provides evidence in favor of policy recommendations to facilitate the transition from loose to close healthcare associations.

    The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we describe the background of the research and builds the evolutionary game model. In Section 3, we solve the model and analyze the stability of the strategy portfolio. In Section 4, we simulate the model, analyze the effect of different parameters on the results and present the managerial insights of the study. In Section 5, a conclusion is drawn.

    Based on the actual development situation of loose medical consortia in China, combined with evolutionary game theory, a detailed description of the problem and research hypotheses are presented below and followed by the constructed evolutionary game model.

    In a loose medical consortium, GTH and STH operate independently, admitting and treating their patients. In this work, we consider the problem of patient referral from two hospitals of the same level with competing relationships. The logical framework diagram of this paper is shown in Figure 2.

    Figure 2.  Logic diagram of patient up-transfer in a medical consortium.

    It is assumed that when a patient is eligible for referral and a GTH refers a patient up to an STH, referral costs will be incurred (e.g., communication costs incurred by the hospital for referral procedures). Admission costs are incurred when STH actively receives patients (e.g., dual transfer green lanes, coordination costs). If the two hospitals don't agree with the referral/acceptance, there would be an additional gain for both hospitals (STH and GTH). Specifically, when the GTH passively refers a patient, the patient will stay longer at the GTH for treatment and consume more medical services. When an STH passively accepts a patient, the hospital does not need to vacate a vacant bed for the patient. At the same time, GTH will not worry about the potential overspending of medical insurance funds by accepting the referral patients. There are also referral delay costs due to the negative treatment of patients. Usually, the referral delay costs include the doctor-patient conflict caused by delayed patient treatment due to complex referral procedures, the cost due to a lack of nursing beds, insufficient sharing of patient information between hospitals for patient referrals, etc. The government will implement a penalty mechanism for hospitals that negatively cooperate.

    In this section, the following hypotheses are used.

    Hypothesis 1: Two participants, a GTH and an STH, are selected in this model. There are two strategies, active referral or passive referral, for upward referral of patients from the GTH, corresponding to probabilities of x and 1x, respectively. There are two behavioral strategies for STH, active admission and passive admission, corresponding to probabilities of y and 1y, respectively. Both participants are finite and rational and adjust their strategic choices in response to events to maximize their benefits.

    Hypothesis 2: When both hospitals actively deal with referred patients, each has a base benefit, R1 and R2. When the GTH refers patients passively, patients continue to treatment and additional benefits, S1, are generated. When an STH passively accepts patients, it does not need to spare beds for them, nor does it need to worry about overspending on medical insurance funds. Thus, additional benefits, S2, are generated.

    Hypothesis 3: When both hospitals treat patients passively, the government will punish the defaulting hospital with a penalty of M.

    Hypothesis 4: Because the two hospitals are members of the medical consortium, the patient referral process should fully reflect the community attributes of the consortium. Therefore, this model introduces a cost-sharing factor α, where α(0,1), assuming that both hospitals share the delay cost when both hospitals treat referrals negatively.

    Without loss of generality, the fixed cost of referral or non-referral in both types of hospitals is set as 0. This study only considered the additional referral costs incurred by referring patients to the STH and GTH. This processing method is often used in evolutionary game research and does not impact the equilibrium results of the game. C1 denotes the referral cost of actively referring patients from the GTH and the referral cost of actively admitting patients from the STH is C2. The delay cost incurred by either hospital treating the referred patient passively is set to C3.

    The parameters used in this paper are shown in Table 1.

    Table 1.  Parameter symbols and their meanings.
    Parameters Description
    R1 Base revenue of GTH
    R2 Base revenue of STH
    S1 Additional revenue when GTH refers patients passively
    S2 Additional revenue when STH admits patients passively
    M Government penalties for hospitals that do not fulfill their alliance contracts
    C1 Referral costs for patients referred from GTH
    C2 The admission cost of patients received by STH
    C3 Delay costs incurred by either participant for passive treatment of referred patients
    α Delay cost-sharing factor

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Based on the above assumptions and parameter settings, the payoff matrix of the two-sided evolutionary game between the GTH and STH constructed in this study is shown in Table 2. The payoffs under different strategy choices are explained as follows:

    Table 2.  The payoff matrix.
    STH
    Active admission y Passive admission (1y)
    GTH Active referral R1C1, R1C1,
    x R2C2 R2C2C3M+S2
    Passive referral R1C1C3M+S1, R1C1αC3M+S1,
    (1x) R2C2 R2C2(1α)C3M+S2

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    (Ⅰ) When the strategy of the GTH and STH is (active referral, active admission), the revenues of the GTH and STH are R1C1 and R2C2, respectively.

    (Ⅱ) When the strategy of the GTH and STH is (active referral, passive admission), super tertiary hospitals are penalized by the government with M and bear the delay cost C3 alone, but receive an additional benefit S2, at which point the revenue of the GTH is R1C1 and the revenue of the STH is R2C2C3M+S2.

    (Ⅲ) When the strategy of the GTH and STH is (passive referral, active admission), this scenario is similar to case (Ⅱ), where the GTH is fined M by the government and it alone bears the delay cost C3, as well as gaining additional revenue, S1. The benefits for the GTH and STH are R1C1C3M+S1 and R2C2, respectively.

    (Ⅳ) When the strategy of the GTH and STH is (passive referral, passive admission), both hospitals are fined M by the government. Both hospitals share the delay cost C3 based on the coefficient α. At this point the benefit to the GTH is R1C1αC3M+S1 and the benefit to the STH is R2C2(1α)C3M+S2.

    Based on the Malthusian dynamic equation, the equilibrium results of the previously constructed evolutionary game model will be calculated and theoretical analysis will be conducted under different scenarios.

    Based on the above assumptions and the benefits matrix, the expected benefits of active and passive referrals for the GTH and the average expected benefits are G1, G2 and ¯G, respectively, as shown below:

    G1=y(R1C1)+(1y)(R1C1)=R1C1 (1)
    G2=y(R1C1C3M+S1)+(1y)(R1C1αC3M+S1)=R1C1αC3M+S1y(1α)C3 (2)
    ¯G=xG1+(1x)G2=R1C1+(1x)[αC3M+S1y(1α)C3] (3)

    Similarly, the expected benefits of active and passive admission of patients for the STH and the average expected benefits are E1, E2 and ¯E, respectively, which are shown below:

    E1=x(R2C2)+(1x)(R2C2)=R2C2 (4)
    E2=x(R2C2C3M+S2)+(1x)[R2C2(1α)C3M+S2]=R2C2C3M+S2+(1x)αC3 (5)
    ¯E=yE1+(1y)E2=R2C2+(1y)[S2MC3+(1x)αC3] (6)

    According to the relevant principles of evolutionary games [35], the replication dynamics equation of the evolutionary game systems of GTH and STH can be found as shown in Eq (7):

    {F(x)=dxdt=x(G1¯G)=x(1x)[yC3(1α)+αC3+MS1]F(y)=dydt=y(E1¯E)=y(1y)[xαC3+(1α)C3+MS2] (7)

    The derivatives for F(x) and F(y) are as follows:

    {dF(x)dx=(12x)[yC3(1α)+αC3+MS1]dF(y)dy=(12y)[xαC3+(1α)C3+MS2] (8)

    Equation (8) shows that the evolutionary gaming system has five equilibrium points on a plane M={(x,y)|0x,y1}: (0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1) and ((1α)C3+MS2αC3,αC3+MS1C3(1α)) (later abbreviated as (x,y). When 0(1α)C3+MS2αC31 and 0αC3+MS1C3(1α)1 hold, (x,y) is also equilibrium point.

    According to Friedman (1991) [36], the stability of the equilibrium point of an evolving system can be obtained by the local stability of the Jacobian matrix. The system Jacobi matrix J can be obtained from Eq (7), as shown in Eq (9):

    J=[F(x)xF(x)yF(y)xF(y)y]=[(12x)[yC3(1α)+αC3+MS1]x(1x)(1α)C3y(1y)αC3(12y)[xαC3+(1α)C3+MS2]] (9)

    When the determinant (detJ) and trace (traceJ) of the Jacobian matrix of the equilibrium point satisfy detJ>0 and traceJ<0, this is the local equilibrium point (LEP) in the dynamic process of system evolution, which is called an evolutionarily stability strategy (ESS).

    The stable strategy of the evolutionary game must have the anti-disturbance ability in a stable state, satisfying dF(x)dx<0 and dF(y)dy<0. The specific values of the five LEP in the Jacobi matrix of detJ and traceJ are shown in Table 3:

    Table 3.  The detJ and traceJ at each LEP.
    LEP detJ traceJ
    (0, 0) (M+αC3S1)[M+(1α)C3S2] 2M+C3S1S2
    (0, 1) (M+C3S1)[M+(1α)C3S2] αC3S1+S2
    (1, 0) (M+αC3S1)(M+C3S2) (1α)C3+S1S2
    (1, 1) (M+C3S1)(M+C3S2) 2M2C3+S1+S2
    (x,y) (M+C3S1)(M+C3S2)(M+αC3S1)[M+(1α)C3S2]C32α(1α) 0

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    A total of nine scenarios were generated with different values of the parameters, as shown in Table 4. There are four equilibrium points for each scenario and we analyzed the stability of the evolutionary equilibrium point of the game system of GTH and STH for each scenario.

    Table 4.  The evolutionary stability of each LEP.
    Scenarios LEP detJ traceJ State
    Scenarios 1:
    S1>M+C3
    S2>M+C3
    (0, 0) + ESS
    (0, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 1) + + Unstable
    Scenarios 2:
    S1>M+C3
    (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M
    (0, 0) + ESS
    (0, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 0) + + Unstable
    (1, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    Scenarios 3:
    S1>M+C3
    S2<(1α)C3+M
    (0, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (0, 1) + ESS
    (1, 0) + + Unstable
    (1, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    Scenarios 4:
    αC3+M<S1<C3+M
    S2>C3+M
    (0, 0) + ESS
    (0, 1) + + Unstable
    (1, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    Scenarios 5:
    αC3+M<S1<C3+M
    (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M
    (0, 0) + ESS
    (0, 1) + + Unstable
    (1, 0) + + Unstable
    (1, 1) + ESS
    Scenarios 6:
    αC3+M<S1<C3+M
    S2<(1α)C3+M
    (0, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (0, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 0) + + Unstable
    (1, 1) + ESS
    Scenarios 7:
    S1<αC3+M
    S2>C3+M
    (0, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (0, 1) + + Unstable
    (1, 0) + ESS
    (1, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    Scenarios 8:
    S1<αC3+M
    (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M
    (0, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (0, 1) + + Unstable
    (1, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 1) + ESS
    Scenarios 9:
    S1<αC3+M
    S2<(1α)C3+M
    (0, 0) + + Unstable
    (0, 1) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 0) Uncertain Saddle point
    (1, 1) + ESS

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Scenario 1: S1>M+C3, S2>M+C3 (high revenue, high revenue)

    In Scenario 1, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (0, 0), that is, the ESS of GTH and STH are passive referral and passive admission. For GTH, the additional benefit generated when referring patients negatively is greater than the sum of the delay cost and the penalty given by the government, which is a high benefit at this point, so GTHs are more inclined to choose to refer patients negatively. By the same token, the additional benefit to STHs when accepting patients passively is greater than the sum of penalties and the delay cost, so GTHs are also more likely to choose to admit patients passively.

    Scenarios 2: S1>M+C3, (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M (high revenue, medium revenue)

    In Scenario 2, the stable point of the dynamic evolutionary system is (0, 0). The ESS of the GTH and STH is passive referral and passive admission. For GTHs, the additional benefit generated when referring patients negatively is greater than the sum of the delay cost and the penalty given by the government. For the STHs, the additional benefit when they receive patients negatively is less than the sum of the penalty given by the government and the delay cost, but greater than the sum of the penalty and the delay cost sharing with the GTH, which is a medium-benefit state.

    Scenarios 3: S1>M+C3, S2<(1α)C3+M (high revenue, low revenue)

    In Scenario 3, the stable point of the dynamically evolving system is (0, 1). The ESS of GTH and STH is passive referral and active admission. The GTH remains in a high revenue state, so it is more inclined to choose negatively referred patients. In contrast, the additional benefit of admitting patients negatively for the STH is less than the sum of the penalty given by the government and the delay cost-shared with the GTH, which leaves the GTH in a low-benefit situation, so the STH is more likely to choose positive patient admission.

    Scenario 4: αC3+M<S1<C3+M, S2>C3+M (medium revenue, high revenue)

    In Scenario 4, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (0, 0). The ESS of the GTH and STH are passive referral and passive admission. For the GTH, the benefit is medium at this point. The gain is between the sum of the penalty and the delay cost and the sum of the penalty and the shared delay cost. The STH is more likely to choose to admit patients negatively because the additional benefit to the STH when it negatively receives patients is greater than the sum of the penalty given by the government and the delay cost, which is at a high benefit.

    Scenario 5: αC3+M<S1<C3+M, (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M (medium revenue, medium revenue)

    In Scenario 5, the stable points of the dynamic evolutionary system are (0, 0) and (1, 1). The ESS of the GTH and STH are passive referral and passive admission or active referral and active admission. For both hospitals, the benefits are moderate at this point. The benefit for both hospitals lies between the sum of the shared delay cost and penalty and the sum of the delay cost and the penalty. Both hospitals are affected by the cost-sharing coefficient and when one chooses to be negative, the other chooses to be negative and vice versa.

    Scenario 6: αC3+M<S1<C3+M, S2<(1α)C3+M (medium revenue, low revenue)

    In Scenario 6, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (1, 1). The ESS of GTH and STH is active referral and active admission.

    For tertiary hospitals, the benefits generated when treating patients negatively puts the GTH in a medium-benefit position and the STH in a low-benefit position, making both hospitals more inclined to choose to treat referred patients positively.

    Scenario 7: S1<αC3+M, S2>C3+M (low revenue, high revenue)

    In Scenario 7, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (1, 0). The ESS of GTH and STH is active referral and passive admission. The GTH chooses to treat patients positively because of the lower revenue generated when treating patients negatively. For the STH, positive referrals bring higher revenue and therefore it will choose to admit patients negatively.

    Scenario 8: S1<αC3+M, (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M (low revenue, medium revenue)

    In Scenario 8, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (1, 1). The ESS of GTH and STH is active referral and active admission. For the GTH, the benefit generated when negatively referring patients is less than the sum of the penalty and the delay cost, so the GTH is more likely to choose to refer patients actively. Similarly, for the STH, the benefit of receiving patients negatively is moderate, so both hospitals choose to treat patients positively at this time.

    Scenario 9: S1<αC3+M, S2<(1α)C3+M (low revenue, low revenue)

    In Scenario 9, the stable point of the dynamic evolution system is (1, 1). The ESS of GTH and STH is active referral and active admission. For both hospitals, the benefit when treating patients negatively is less than the sum of the penalty and the delay cost, so both hospitals will choose to treat patients positively.

    The evolutionary stability of the strategy of the GTH and STH was simulated using MATLAB R2019b. The initial values for the nine scenarios were M=10, C3=60, α=0.5 and the initial values of S1 and S2 are shown in Table 5. The evolution diagrams of the nine scenarios are shown in Figure 3. The horizontal axis represents the probability that a GTH chooses to actively refer patients; the vertical axis represents the probability that an STH chooses to actively admit patients.

    Table 5.  Initial values of S1 and S2 for the nine scenarios.
    S1 S2 S1 S2 S1 S2
    Scenario 1 80 85 Scenario 4 50 85 Scenario 7 30 85
    Scenario 2 80 55 Scenario 5 50 55 Scenario 8 30 55
    Scenario 3 80 35 Scenario 6 50 35 Scenario 9 30 35

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Figure 3.  Dynamic evolutionary process of the nine scenarios.

    Taking Scenario 1 as an example, the lines shown in the figure all converge to (0, 0), implying that the stabilization strategies of the GTH and STH converge to passive referral and passive admit.

    Based on the analysis in Section 3.2, we summarize the relationship between the hospital's revenue status, LEP and stabilization strategy corresponding to the nine scenarios in Table 6. The hospital's strategic choices are analyzed and summarized from the perspective of hospital revenue.

    Table 6.  Stability point analysis of two hospitals in different revenue states.
    Scenario The range of parameter values Revenue state LEP
    GTH STH GTH STH
    Scenario 1 S1>M+C3 S2>M+C3 High High (0, 0)
    Scenario 2 S1>M+C3 (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M Medium (0, 0)
    Scenario 3 S1>M+C3 S2<(1α)C3+M Low (0, 1)
    Scenario 4 αC3+M<S1<C3+M S2>C3+M Medium High (0, 0)
    Scenario 5 αC3+M<S1<C3+M (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M Medium (0, 0)/(1, 1)
    Scenario 6 αC3+M<S1<C3+M S2<(1α)C3+M Low (1, 1)
    Scenario 7 S1<αC3+M S2>C3+M Low High (1, 0)
    Scenario 8 S1<αC3+M (1α)C3+M<S2<C3+M Medium (1, 1)
    Scenario 9 S1<αC3+M S2<(1α)C3+M Low (1, 1)
    Note: 0 represents a negative attitude, 1 represents a positive attitude.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    High revenue state: (ⅰ) When the revenue of GTH are high enough, GTH chooses to refer patients negatively, regardless of whether STH treats patients negatively or not (see Scenarios 1–3). (ⅱ) Similarly, when the revenue of STH is high enough, the strategy is to receive patients negatively (see Scenarios 1, 4 and 7).

    Low revenue state: (ⅰ) When GTH has low revenue, regardless of whether the STH treats patients negatively or not, the revenue of the GTH is less than the sum of government punishment and shared delay costs. Under a low revenue state, GTH always choose to actively refer patients (see Scenarios 7–9). (ⅱ) When the STH has a low revenue, regardless of whether the GTH treats patients negatively, the STH always chooses to actively receive patients (see Scenarios 3, 6 and 9).

    Medium revenue state: (ⅰ) From the second and third columns of Table 6, it can be found that when GTH and STH are in a state of high revenue and medium revenue or medium revenue and high revenue, the obtained revenue by the hospitals in the negative treatment of patients are still higher than the delayed referrals costs and government punishment costs. Therefore, their LEP is (0, 0), as shown in Scenarios 2 and 4. (ⅱ) In Scenarios 6 and 8, when the status of GTH and STH belongs to the state with low revenue and medium revenue or medium revenue and low revenue, if the hospital treats patients negatively, their revenues are less than the sum of delay costs and government penalty costs. Therefore, the stability strategy of the two hospitals shifts to (1, 1). (ⅲ) When both GTH and STH are in a medium revenue state, with the intervention of the cost-sharing coefficient, the revenues of the two hospitals are in a relationship where there are 2 stabilization points in the system, i.e., (0, 0)/(1, 1). The selection of evolutionary stability strategies for two hospitals is related to the payment matrix and the initial state of the system [37].

    Among the above nine scenarios, Scenario 5 is special. In Scenario 5, the strategies of the two hospitals converged to (0, 0) and (1, 1) respectively. Therefore, Scenario 5 is selected for analysis in this study to explore the changes in the hospital's strategy by changing the parameter values.

    In Scenario 5, both hospitals are in a medium gain state and both hospitals have two ESS. Based on the initial values given in Table 6 and assuming the probability value (x,y)=(0.5,0.5), we investigated the effects of changes in penalty costs M, delay costs C3 and cost-sharing coefficients α on the evolutionary stability of the GTH and STH.

    In Figure 4, the solid line represents the evolutionary trend when M=10 and the dashed line represents the variation trend when M takes other values (M=4, 7, 13, 16, 19).

    Figure 4.  Trajectory of evolution under different penalty costs.

    ● When the government's penalty cost is small (M=4 and M=7), the ESS for GTH and STH is (0, 0), i.e., negative referral and negative admission.

    ● As the penalty cost increases (M=13, M=16, M=19), the ESS of the GTH and STH tends to decrease at the rate of (0, 0) until at the critical value M=10, the evolutionary stabilization strategy becomes (1, 1).

    In summary, in Scenario 5, as the cost of government penalties increases, the ESS of GTH and STH first changes from (0, 0) to (1, 1) and then stays at (1, 1) unchanged and the rate of convergence first decreases and then increases. The two hospitals always treat patients with the same choice.

    As shown in Figure 5, the evolutionary trajectory under changing delay cost is similar to that when changing the penalty cost in Section 4.1.

    Figure 5.  Trajectory of evolution under different delay costs.

    ● When the delay cost C3< 60 (C3 = 50 and C3 = 55), the ESS is (0, 0) and the convergence rate decreases as the delay cost increases.

    ● When the delay cost C3 = 60, the ESS of GTH and STH is (1, 1), i.e., active referral and passive admission.

    ● When the delay cost C3>60 (C3 = 65, C3 = 70, C3 = 75), the ESS is (1, 1) and the convergence rate increases as the delay cost increases.

    As shown in Figure 6, changing the cost-sharing coefficient, the GTH and STH ultimately move to active referral and active admission. When α gradually increases from 0.1 to 0.9, and x<0.5, the cost of delay to be shared by the GTH increased and the green dashed line tended to be closer to a probability of 1; the GTH gradually changes from negative referrals to positive referrals; as α gradually increased, (1α) gradually decreased and the value of delay costs shared by STH decreased. The red dashed line starts with a fast convergence to 1 and becomes a slow convergence to probability 1.

    Figure 6.  Trajectory of evolution under different delay cost-sharing coefficients.

    We focus on two tertiary hospitals with both competitive and cooperative relationships, who form a loose medical association. STH has a stronger position by providing medical technology support to GTH. Although a cooperative relationship is established through an agreement, GTH are often reluctant to upwardly refer patients to STH. We constructed an evolutionary game model between GTH and STH regarding patient upward transfer, analyzed the dynamic evolutionary process of the two hospitals inpatient referral and conducted numerical simulations on the stability of the ESS. Combining the simulation results with the three characteristics of China's healthcare resources and service system, this paper summarizes the following conclusions and management insights.

    This study found that hospitals have a preference for increasing revenue and reducing costs. The strategy choice of hospitals is primarily impacted by their revenue states. In this study we analyzed nine scenarios and classified hospitals by revenue states, which included three levels for high, medium and low. (ⅰ) Hospitals choose to treat patients negatively when they are in high revenue (see Scenarios 1, 4 and 7). Hospitals follow the rational assumptions in their own development process and in order to safeguard their own interests, hospitals like GTH have an inferior position and are usually reluctant to upwardly refer patients, as this means that they will lose the health insurance claim reimbursement. The reason STH is unwilling to accept patients is rooted in reasons such as insufficient nursing beds and overspending medical insurance reimbursements. Due to the unbalanced distribution of medical resources in China, there are significant differences in the capacity and service levels of the hospitals in different provinces and regions across China. For example, a certain tertiary hospital in the capital of a Chinese province is far more competitive than the ordinary tertiary hospitals in other prefectures in the same province because of its medical staff, medical equipment and government financial subsidies. (ⅱ) When STH and GTH are in low revenue, they choose to treat patients positively. This is because the additional benefits of the hospital are much lower than the delay costs and government penalties caused by negative referrals. At this point, the hospital will actively seek cooperation to offset the losses caused by negative referrals. It is evident that when hospitals are in a clear state of high or low revenue (see Scenarios 1, 3, 4, 6, 7 and 9), their strategic behavior is clear and decisive. (ⅲ) When the additional benefits to the hospitals are greater than the sum of the costs of delays and government penalties, the hospitals with the middle revenue will be negative and the reverse is positive (see Scenario 5).

    After proposing the new healthcare reform in 2015, the Chinese government began to emphasize an integrated healthcare service system, hoping to improve the efficiency of the healthcare system through medical consortia. However, the implementation of the medical consortium is facing numerous difficulties due to disagreements between hospitals. Additionally, the lack of cooperation mechanisms between hospitals within the consortium make the operation of medical consortium more challenging. Our research precisely confirms that a scientific and reasonable cooperation mechanism can help to with improving the operation of the medical consortium. The delay cost C3 and delay cost-sharing coefficient α in the model reflects the cooperation attribute. As the delay cost C3 increases, the ESS of GTH and STH changes from (0, 0) to (1, 1) (Figure 5). When α gradually increases from 0.1 to 0.9 and x<0.5, the cost of delay to be shared by the GTH increased, GTH's strategic choices shift from negative to positive referrals (Figure 6). Internal factor is a breakthrough for hospital collaboration. The delay cost-sharing factor ties the interests of hospitals within a medical consortium together. The strategic choice of a hospital with different cost-sharing factors will have a considerable impact on another hospital.

    China's medical service system is dominated by public hospitals, so the government has a strong control over the healthcare system, manifested in the implementation of directive tasks is an important assessment index for hospitals. Therefore, in the Chinese context, after the model introduces the governmental punishment, the hospital strategy behavior changes as shown in Figure 4. As the cost of government penalties M increases, the ESS of GTH and STH changes from (0, 0) to (1, 1). Reasonable external interventions, such as government penalty mechanisms, drive further collaboration between hospitals. Government penalties can change a hospital's revenue status and, in turn, its strategic choices. It is particularly important for the government to penalize hospitals for treating patients negatively when their additional revenue is moderate. A reasonable penalty mechanism helps to restrain self-interested behavior among hospitals within the medical association, thus maximizing win-win cooperation between the two parties.

    Based on the above findings, we provide the following suggestions and the answers for the following questions. What type of hospitals should be selected for collaboration? How to cooperate? When should the government intervene? (ⅰ) The revenue status of different hospitals varies in reality and the cooperation between medical consortia largely depends on the revenue level of the hospital itself. The members of the medical consortium should try to complement each other as much as possible. Hospitals with high revenue status not being able to take care of referral patients, so hospitals with high revenue status and medium revenue status or hospitals with medium revenue and low revenue status should be selected. (ⅱ) For hospitals with competitive relationships, genuine cooperation cannot be achieved through signing agreements and can be implemented through third-party platforms that set referral standards and reward and punishment performance. (ⅲ) Government regulatory mechanisms can help improve fragmentation within the healthcare consortium. Appropriate government penalties can change the strategic choice behavior of hospitals when there are moderate or high returns in the hospitals. Diversified forms of medical association should be designed and flexible evaluation systems should be adopted according to the state of revenue that hospitals are in.

    In the future, we will consider adding the government's reward mechanism and comparing it with the government's punishment mechanism to analyze the degree of influence of the government's reward and punishment mechanism on the referral results of the medical association. In addition, we will consider applying the dynamic game method to study the evolutionary relationship among the tripartite subjects that include hospitals, patients and government.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    This research was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 72104076) and Scientific research projects of Education Department of Hunan Province (No. 22B0630).

    The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.



    [1] World Health Organization, Integration of Health Care Delivery: Report of a WHO Study Group, World Health Organization, 1996.
    [2] World Health Assembly, Framework on integrated, people-centred health services: Report by the Secretariat. World Health Organization, 2016. Available from: https://apps.who.int/iris/handle/10665/252698.
    [3] L. Luo, J. Li, X. Xu, W. Shen, L. Xiao, A data-driven hybrid three-stage framework for hospital bed allocation: A case study in a large tertiary hospital in China, Comput. Math. Methods Med., 2019 (2019), 7370231. https://doi.org/10.1155/2019/7370231 doi: 10.1155/2019/7370231
    [4] National Health Commission of the People's Republic of China, Statistical Bulletin of China's Health Development. Central People's Government of the People's Republic of China, 2021. Available from: http://www.gov.cn/xinwen/2022-07/12/content_5700670.htm
    [5] J. Su, L. Xu, C. Yi, H. Ding, W. Zuo, F. Guo, Reflection on the implementation of community-based bi-directional referrals in the construction of regional medical consortium, Chin. Gen. Pract., 23 (2020), 1541. https://doi.org/10.12114/j.issn.1007-9572.2020.00.197 doi: 10.12114/j.issn.1007-9572.2020.00.197
    [6] H. Boon, M. Verhoef, D. O'hara, B. Findlay, N. Majid, Integrative healthcare: Arriving at a working definition, Altern. Ther. Health Med., 10 (2004), 48–56.
    [7] M. Strandberg-Larsen, A. Krasnik, Measurement of integrated healthcare delivery: a systematic review of methods and future research directions, Int. J. Integr. care, 9 (2009), e01. https://doi.org/10.5334/ijic.305 doi: 10.5334/ijic.305
    [8] J. M. Evans, G. R. Baker, W. Berta, J. Barnsley, The evolution of integrated health care strategies, Adv. Health Care Manage., 15 (2013), 125–161. https://doi.org/10.1108/s1474-8231(2013)0000015011 doi: 10.1108/s1474-8231(2013)0000015011
    [9] R. Gauld, The theory and practice of integrative health care governance, J. Integr. Care, 25 (2017), 61–72. https://doi.org/10.1108/jica-10-2016-0035 doi: 10.1108/jica-10-2016-0035
    [10] J. S. Funderburk, D. E. Sugarman, S. A. Maisto, P. Ouimette, M. Schohn, L. Lantinga, et al., The description and evaluation of the implementation of an integrated healthcare model, Fam. Syst. Health, 28 (2010), 146–160. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0020223 doi: 10.1037/a0020223
    [11] O. Zerbo, M. L. Massolo, Y. Qian, L. A. Croen, A study of physician knowledge and experience with autism in adults in a large integrated healthcare system, J. Autism Dev. Disord., 45 (2015), 4002–4014. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10803-015-2579-2 doi: 10.1007/s10803-015-2579-2
    [12] M. Cai, E. Liu, H. Tao, Z. Qian, Q. J. Fu, X. Lin, et al., Does a medical consortium influence health outcomes of hospitalized cancer patients? An integrated care model in Shanxi, China, Int. J. Integr. Care, 18 (2018), 7. https://doi.org/10.5334/ijic.3588 doi: 10.5334/ijic.3588
    [13] J. Liang, X. Zheng, Z. Chen, S. Dai, J. Xu, H. Ye, et al., The experience and challenges of healthcare-reform-driven medical consortia and Regional Health Information Technologies in China: A longitudinal study, Int. J. Med. Inf., 131 (2019), 103954. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijmedinf.2019.103954 doi: 10.1016/j.ijmedinf.2019.103954
    [14] C. Grady, H. Han, D. H. Kim, A. M. Coderre-Ball, N. Alam, Family physicians collaborating for health system integration: a scoping review, BMC Health Serv. Res., 23 (2023), 68. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12913-023-09063-w doi: 10.1186/s12913-023-09063-w
    [15] H. B. Mahajan, A. S. Rashid, A. A. Junnarkar, N. Uke, S. D. Deshpande, P. R. Futane, et al., Integration of Healthcare 4.0 and blockchain into secure cloud-based electronic health records systems, Appl. Nanosci. Name, 13 (2023), 2329–2342. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13204-021-02164-0 doi: 10.1007/s13204-021-02164-0
    [16] L. R. Burns, I. M. Nembhard, S. M. Shortell, Integrating network theory into the study of integrated healthcare, Social Sci. Med., 296 (2022), 114664. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socscimed.2021.114664 doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2021.114664
    [17] J. Tanimoto, Fundamentals of Evolutionary Game Theory and Its Applications, Springer, 2015. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-54962-8
    [18] M. A. Habib, K. A. Kabir, J. Tanimoto, Evolutionary game analysis for sustainable environment under two power generation systems, 9 (2022), 326–344. https://doi.org/10.5109/4793672
    [19] J. Tanimoto, Sociophysics Approach to Epidemics, Springer., 2021. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-33-6481-3
    [20] W. Fan, S. Wang, X. Gu, Z. Zhou, Y. Zhao, W. Huo, Evolutionary game analysis on industrial pollution control of local government in China, J. Environ. Manage., 298 (2021), 113499. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.113499 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.113499
    [21] Z. Liu, Q. Qian, B. Hu, W. L. Shang, L. Li, Y. Zhao, et al., Government regulation to promote coordinated emission reduction among enterprises in the green supply chain based on evolutionary game analysis, Resour. Conserv. Recycl., 182 (2022), 106290. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2022.106290 doi: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2022.106290
    [22] Z. Yu, S. A. Rehman Khan, Evolutionary game analysis of green agricultural product supply chain financing system: COVID-19 pandemic, Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl., 25 (2022), 1115–1135. https://doi.org/10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752 doi: 10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752
    [23] Y. Sun, Z. Gu, Implementation of construction waste recycling under construction sustainability incentives: A multi-agent stochastic evolutionary game approach, Sustainability., 14 (2022), 3702. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063702 doi: 10.3390/su14063702
    [24] X. Yunan, L. Weixin, Y. Yujie, W. Hui, Evolutionary game for the stakeholders in livestock pollution control based on circular economy, J. Cleaner Prod., 282 (2021), 125403. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.125403 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.125403
    [25] X. Zhao, X. Bai, How to motivate the producers' green innovation in WEEE recycling in China?–An analysis based on evolutionary game theory, Waste Manage., 122 (2021), 26–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wasman.2020.12.027 doi: 10.1016/j.wasman.2020.12.027
    [26] Z. Xu, Y. Cheng, S. Yao, Tripartite evolutionary game model for public health emergencies, Discrete Dyn. Nat. Soc., 2021 (2021), 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/6693597 doi: 10.1155/2021/6693597
    [27] W. Liu, S. Long, D. Xie, Y. Liang, J. Wang, How to govern the big data discriminatory pricing behavior in the platform service supply chain? An examination with a three-party evolutionary game model, Int. J. Prod. Econ., 231 (2021), 107910. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.107910 doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.107910
    [28] J. Liu, C. Yu, C. Li, J. Han, Cooperation or conflict in doctor-patient relationship? An analysis from the perspective of evolutionary game, IEEE Access, 8 (2020), 42898–42908. https://doi.org/10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2977385 doi: 10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2977385
    [29] Y. Sun, X. Zhang, Y. Han, B. Yu, H. Liu, Evolutionary game model of health care and social care collaborative services for the elderly population in China, BMC geriatr., 22 (2022), 616. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12877-022-03300-3 doi: 10.1186/s12877-022-03300-3
    [30] X. Xu, J. Liu, S. Ampon-Wireko, H. Asante Antwi, L. Zhou, Towards an integrated healthcare system: evolutionary game analysis on competition and cooperation between urban and rural medical institutions in China, Front. Public Health, 10 (2022), 825328. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpubh.2022.825328 doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2022.825328
    [31] S. Tian, Y. Chen, Vertical integration of electronic health records in medical consortiums: Dynamic modeling approach based on the evolutionary game theory, JMIR Serious Games, 11 (2023), e41528. https://doi.org/10.2196/41528 doi: 10.2196/41528
    [32] L. Luo, S. Zhang, J. Xiang, Development of the family doctor service: An evolutionary game theory analysis, Econ. Res. Ekonomska Istraživanja, 36 (2023), 2106507. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2022.2106507 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2022.2106507
    [33] C. Tao, X. Chen, W. Zheng, Z. Zhang, R. Tao, R. Deng, et al., How to promote the hierarchical diagnosis and treatment system: A tripartite evolutionary game theory perspective, Front. Psychol., 13 (2023), 1081562. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2022.1081562 doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2022.1081562
    [34] C. Q. Dong, J. D. Liu, J. N. Mi, Information-driven integrated healthcare: An analysis of the cooperation strategy of county medical community based on multi-subject simulation, Healthcare, 11 (2023), 2019. https://doi.org/10.3390/healthcare11142019 doi: 10.3390/healthcare11142019
    [35] P. D. Taylor, L. B. Jonker, Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics, Math. Biosci., 40 (1978), 145–156. https://doi.org/10.1016/0025-5564(78)90077-9 doi: 10.1016/0025-5564(78)90077-9
    [36] D. Friedman, Evolutionary games in economics, Econometrica J. Econom. Soc., 59 (1991), 637–666. https://doi.org/10.2307/2938222 doi: 10.2307/2938222
    [37] Q. Fu, L. Xin, S. Ma, Evolutionary game of carbon-emission-reduction investment in supply chains under a contract with punishment mechanism (in Chinese), J. Manage. Sci. China., 19 (2016), 56–70. https://doi.org/10.3969/j.issn.1007-9807.2016.04.005 doi: 10.3969/j.issn.1007-9807.2016.04.005
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Huanyu Shi, Zhichao Cheng, Zhuang Cao, Does an innovative case-based payment scheme promote the hierarchical medical system? A tripartite evolutionary game analysis, 2024, 23, 1475-9276, 10.1186/s12939-024-02336-8
    2. Rudan Xue, Li Xiong, Kun Wang, An evolutionary game approach for information sharing within medical consortium based on complex network, 2025, 03608352, 110963, 10.1016/j.cie.2025.110963
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1817) PDF downloads(158) Cited by(2)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog