
In this paper, we investigated an optimal investment problem of a defined contribution (DC) pension plan under a joint Value-at-Risk (VaR) and an expected shortfall (ES) constraint. By using a martingale method, we transformed a dynamic optimization problem to a static pointwise optimization problem and derived the closed-form representations of the optimal wealth and portfolio processes in terms of the state price density. Numerical results showed that in comparison to only an ES constraint or a VaR constraint, the joint VaR-ES constraint can not only improve risk management for the bad economic states but also lower the volatility of the optimal terminal wealth.
Citation: Yinghui Dong, Chengjin Tang, Chunrong Hua. Optimal investment of DC pension plan under a joint VaR-ES constraint[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 2084-2104. doi: 10.3934/math.2024104
[1] | Xiaoyi Tang, Wei Liu, Wanyin Wu, Yijun Hu . An optimal investment strategy for DC pension plans with costs and the return of premium clauses under the CEV model. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 21731-21754. doi: 10.3934/math.20241057 |
[2] | Zongqi Sun, Peng Yang, Jing Wu, Yunpeng Fan . The defined contribution pension plan after retirement under the criterion of a revised loss considering the economic situation. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(2): 4749-4761. doi: 10.3934/math.2024229 |
[3] | Zongqi Sun, Peng Yang, Ying Wang, Jing Lu . Research on the wealth management fees of defined contribution pensions during the pre-retirement stage. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(12): 36102-36115. doi: 10.3934/math.20241713 |
[4] | Chengjin Tang, Jiahao Guo, Yinghui Dong . Optimal investment based on performance measure with a stochastic benchmark. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2750-2770. doi: 10.3934/math.2025129 |
[5] | Melina Melina, Sukono, Herlina Napitupulu, Norizan Mohamed . Investment risk forecasting model using extreme value theory approach combined with machine learning. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 33314-33352. doi: 10.3934/math.20241590 |
[6] | Chunwei Wang, Jiaen Xu, Shujing Wang, Naidan Deng . An investment risk model with bilateral jumps. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 2032-2050. doi: 10.3934/math.2024101 |
[7] | Andrea Ratto . Higher order energy functionals and the Chen-Maeta conjecture. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(2): 1089-1104. doi: 10.3934/math.2020076 |
[8] | Omar kahouli, Mourad Elloumi, Omar Naifar, Abdellatif Ben Makhlouf, Yassine Bouteraa, Sarra Elgharbi . Enhanced general conformable controller based on Lyapunov technique for DC-DC static converters: Application to a solar system. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(5): 10698-10716. doi: 10.3934/math.2024522 |
[9] | Ali Hussein AL-Marshadi, Muhammad Aslam, Abdullah Alharbey . Design of double acceptance sampling plan for Weibull distribution under indeterminacy. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(6): 13294-13305. doi: 10.3934/math.2023672 |
[10] | Yu Yuan, Qicai Li . Maximizing the goal-reaching probability before drawdown with borrowing constraint. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(8): 8868-8882. doi: 10.3934/math.2021514 |
In this paper, we investigated an optimal investment problem of a defined contribution (DC) pension plan under a joint Value-at-Risk (VaR) and an expected shortfall (ES) constraint. By using a martingale method, we transformed a dynamic optimization problem to a static pointwise optimization problem and derived the closed-form representations of the optimal wealth and portfolio processes in terms of the state price density. Numerical results showed that in comparison to only an ES constraint or a VaR constraint, the joint VaR-ES constraint can not only improve risk management for the bad economic states but also lower the volatility of the optimal terminal wealth.
Aging is a major global trend of the 21st century. With the aging population worldwide, retirement plans play an important role in maintaining and improving the quality of life of elders. Pension funds act as one of the most important institutions in financial markets since they provide financial security after retirement. Generally speaking, there are mainly two kinds of pension funds all over the world: The defined benefit (DB) scheme and the defined contribution (DC) scheme. In a DC plan, only contributions are determined and the retirement benefits are determined by the contribution and the performance of the fund's investment portfolios during the accumulation phase. In a DB plan, the benefits at retirement are initially fixed and the contributions are calculated according to the predetermined benefits. As the longevity and investment risks of the DC plan are shifted from the sponsor to the contributors, traditional DB pension plans are gradually losing their dominance in the occupational pension systems and there has been an ongoing shift from DB to DC pensions in recent years. It is therefore crucial to find the optimal asset allocations for the DC pension fund manager during the accumulation phase so that the members can receive sufficient funds after retirement. There already exists a lot of research works on the optimal investment problem for the DC pension plans (see [1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10,11]).
In the existing literature on the optimal investment strategies for DC pension plans, a widely adopted optimization objective is the expected utility maximization of the terminal wealth. Zhang et al. [12] investigated the optimal allocation of a DC pension plan by maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth under inflation risk. Boulier et al. [13] derived the optimal allocations to maximize the coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility of terminal value over a guarantee under a stochastic interest rate. Sun et al. [14] considered a robust portfolio choice problem for a DC pension plan in a stochastic income and stochastic interest rate framework by maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth. In practice, an appropriate investment must take some regulatory constraints into account. Value-at-Risk (VaR) quantifies the worst expected loss given a preset confidence level and is widely applied in pensions and other financial institutions. See, for example, Guan and Liang [15] found the optimal allocation of a DC pension plan under a smooth concave utility criterion with a VaR constraint. Dong and Zheng [16] investigated the optimal allocation of a DC pension plan under the control and VaR constraints.
However, it has been shown in [17] that in difficult financial situations, a pure VaR constraint leads to a heavier loss than that without a VaR constraint under a concave utility. This is due to the fact that VaR-based risk management (VaR-RM) only focuses on the probability but not the magnitude of a loss when it occurs. The portfolio insurance (PI) constraint can well protect the members' benefits by keeping the optimal terminal wealth always above the minimum guarantee, but it may lead to over-cautious investment strategy and a relatively low expected terminal wealth [18,19]. Chen et al. [20] incorporated a VaR constraint with a higher protection level and a PI constraint with a lower protection level together to overcome the drawbacks of a pure VaR or PI constraint. Average Value-at-Risk (AVaR), which measures the risk by averaging all VaRs above a confidence level, has also attracted a lot of attention (see [21,22,23] and references therein). Comparing with a VaR constraint, the AVAR-constrained optimization problem is much more complex. Expected shortfall (ES, also known as limited loss) constraint in [17] has become an alternative of VaR since it can penalize both a high probability of a loss and a high expected loss, given there is a loss. Given a regulatory threshold, the shortfall occurs if the terminal wealth is below the threshold and the expected shortfall is the expectation of the losses. Basak and Shapiro [17] found that in difficult financial situations, the loss under an ES constraint is lower than that without risk constraint in a concave utility framework.
By some numerical analysis, we find that comparing with a VaR constraint, a better protection for bad economic states under an ES constraint than a VaR constraint is at a cost of lowering the optimal terminal wealth in intermediate-economic-states region. Therefore, an ES constraint results in a much higher volatility than a VaR constraint. So, extending [17], we shall investigate a utility maximization problem of a DC pension plan under a VaR-type regulation with a higher protection level and, at the same time, under an ES constraint with a lower protection level. The joint VaR-ES constraint on terminal wealth can well protect the investors' benefits in difficult financial situations, while at the same time lead to a less volatility of the optimal terminal wealth. Furthermore, a regulation with a joint VaR-ES constraint is so flexible that it can nest a pure VaR, ES or PI constraint.
In handling the utility maximization problems with or without risk constraints in a complete market, an efficient approach is the martingale method [24,25]. Extending [17], we use a martingale method to derive the optimal wealth process under a joint VaR-ES constraint. Comparing with [17] and [19], it is highly challenging and technically demanding to solve a utility maximization problem under a joint VaR-ES constraint since we need to choose two multipliers to reflect the bindingness of two risk constraints.
The paper is organized as follows. In section two, we formulate the investment problem for a DC pension fund. In section three, we use the concavification technique and the Lagrange dual method to derive the optimal terminal wealth under the joint VaR-ES constraint. In section four, we carry out some numerical analysis and investigate the impact of two risk constraints on the distribution of the optimal terminal wealth. Section five concludes the paper. The appendix contains some technical proofs.
Consider a continuous-time model with a finite time horizon T=[0,T]. Let (Ω,F,F,P) be a complete filtered probability space with filtration F:={Ft∣t∈T} and Ft is the information available before time t in the market. Assume that all random variables and stochastic processes in this paper are well-defined in this probability space. The pension fund starts at time zero and the retirement time is T.
As DC pension funds have a long investment cycle, inflation risk should be incorporated into the optimization model. To capture the inflation risk, we introduce an inflation index L(t) characterized by the following geometric Brownian motion:
dL(t)L(t)=idt+σIdWI(t),L(0)=1, | (2.1) |
where i>0 is the expected rate of inflation, WI(t) is a standard Brownian motion and σI>0 is the volatility of inflation index.
Assume that the financial market consists of three traded assets: Cash, a stock and an inflation-indexed zero-coupon bond, which is used to hedge the inflation risk.
The riskless money market account S0(t) evolves as
dS0(t)S0(t)=rdt,S0(0)=S0, | (2.2) |
where r is a constant riskless nominal interest rate in the market.
The inflation-linked indexed zero-coupon bond ¯I(t) satisfies the following stochastic differential equation:
d¯I(t)¯I(t)=rdt+σI(λIdt+dWI(t)), | (2.3) |
where λI represents the market price of risk of WI(t).
The dynamics of the stock price S1(t) are as follows:
{dS1(t)S1(t)=rdt+σSI(λIdt+dWI(t))+σS(λSdt+dWS(t)),S1(0)=s1, | (2.4) |
where σSI and σS are constants and drive the volatility of the stock, WS(t) is a standard Brownian motion and independent of WI(t) and λS represents the market price of risk of WS(t).
Before retirement, the pension members put part of their salary in the DC pension plan. Suppose that the contribution rate is a fixed percentage c (0≤c≤1) of the salary. Following [24], we assume the salary of the pension plan members depends on the inflation risk and the stock market risk and satisfies the following equation:
dY(t)Y(t)=μdt+σYIdWI(t)+σYSdWS(t),Y(0)=y0, |
where μ is the appreciation rate and σYI and σYS are constants driving the volatility of the contribution rate.
Since the market is complete, there exists a unique pricing kernel given by
dH(t)H(t)=−rdt−λIdWI(t)−λSdWS(t). | (2.5) |
As explained in [17,20], the quantity H(T,ω) is the Arrow-Debreu price per unit probability of a security, which pays out one at time T if the scenario ω happens and zero otherwise. As this value is high in a recession and low in prosperous times, H(T,ω) can directly reflect the overall state of the economy.
From Eq (2.5), we have
H(T)H(t)=exp(−(r+12(λ2I+λ2S))(T−t)−λI(WI(T)−WI(t))−λS(WS(T)−WS(t))) | (2.6) |
and, therefore, log(H(T)H(t)) is normally distributed with a mean M(t) and a variance V2(t), where
{M(t)=−(r+12(λ2I+λ2S))(T−t),V(t)=√(λ2I+λ2S)(T−t). | (2.7) |
In order to manage the risks from the financial market, the pension manager invests in the market continuously within the time horizon [0,T]. Denote the money invested in the cash, the inflation-linked indexed zero-coupon bond and the stock at time t by π0(t),π1(t) and π2(t), respectively. Denote π1≐{π1(t)|0≤t≤T}, π2≐{π2(t)|0≤t≤T}, then under the investment strategy π≐(π1,π2), the wealth process Xπ(t) of the pension fund is as follows:
{dXπ(t)=rXπ(t)dt+(π1(t)σI+π2(t)σSI)(λIdt+dWI(t))+π2(t)σS(λSdt+dWS(t))+cY(t)dt,Xπ(0)=x0, | (2.8) |
where x0≥0 is the initial wealth of the pension fund and Xπ(t)=π0(t)+π1(t)+π2(t).
Definition 2.1. A portfolio strategy π=(π1,π2) is an admissible strategy if it satisfies the following conditions:
(ⅰ) π1 and π2 are progressively measurable with respect to the filtration F.
(ⅱ) E[∫T0(π21(t)+π22(t))dt]<+∞ a.s., and there exists a unique strong solution Xπ(t) to (2.8). The set of all admissible portfolio strategies is denoted by A.
Consider a utility U, which is a strictly increasing, strictly concave, continuously differentiable, real-valued function defined on [0,∞), satisfying
U(0)=0,limx→+∞U(x)=+∞,limx→0+U′(x)=+∞,limx→+∞U′(x)=0 | (2.9) |
and
limx→+∞xU′(x)U(x)<1. | (2.10) |
Condition (2.9) ensures that the strictly decreasing function U′ has a strictly decreasing inverse I:(0,∞)→(0,∞); that is,
U′(I(y))=y,∀y>0, I(U′(x))=x,∀x>0. |
Let L1,L2 with L1<L2 be two given levels. In order to provide a downside protection, the pension manager is to find the optimal investment strategy to maximize the expected utility of the wealth at time T under simultaneous VaR and ES constraints:
{maxπ∈AE[U(Xπ(T))],s.t.Xπ(t) satisfies (2.8), E[H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))+]≤ε1,P(Xπ(T)≥L2)≥1−ε2, | (2.11) |
where 0≤ε1<∞,0≤ε2≤1 are two given constants. The VaR constraint P(Xπ(T)≥L2)≥1−ε2 requires that the probability of the terminal wealth above the level L2 is no less than 1−ε2 and the ES constraint E[H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))+]≤ε1 requires that the expected present value of the losses, given the regulatory level L1, is no more than ε1.
When ε1=∞ and ε2=1, (2.11) covers an unconstrained optimization problem:
{Problem(noconstraints):maxπ∈AE[U(Xπ(T))],s.t.Xπ(t) satisfies (2.8). | (2.12) |
When ε1=∞ and 0<ε2<1, (2.11) becomes a VaR-constrained optimization problem with regulatory level L2 as follows:
{Problem(VaR):maxπ∈AE[U(Xπ(T))],s.t.Xπ(t) satisfies (2.8), P(˜Xπ(T)≥L2)≥1−ε2. | (2.13) |
When 0<ε1<∞ and ε2=1, (2.11) becomes an ES-constrained optimization problem:
{Problem(ES):maxπ∈AE[U(Xπ(T))],s.t.Xπ(t) satisfies (2.8), E[H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))+]≤ε1. | (2.14) |
Due to the existence of contribution rate, the wealth process Xπ(t) is not self-financing. We introduce an auxiliary wealth process ˜Xπ(t) to convert the process into an equivalent self-financing one. Denote the expected present value of the payment cY(s) at time s by
D(t,s)=1H(t)E[cY(s)H(s)|Ft],s≥t. |
By simple calculation, we obtain the explicit form of D(t,s) as follows:
D(t,s)=cY(t)exp((s−t)(μ−r−σYIλI−σYSλS)),s≥t. |
Moreover, D(t,s) satisfies the following stochastic differential equation:
dD(t,s)D(t,s)=(r+σYIλI+σYSλS)dt+σYIdWI(t)+σYSdWS(t),s≥t. |
Integrating D(t,⋅) from time t to time T, we construct a new process F(t):
F(t)=∫TtD(t,s)ds,∀t∈[0,T]. | (2.15) |
F(t) represents the expected value of the accumulated contribution rates from time t to T at time t. In particular, we have
F(T)=0,F(0)=cy0μ−r−σYIλI−σYSλS(exp((μ−r−σYIλI−σYSλS)T)−1). |
Based on the differential form of D(t,s), the dynamics of F are as follows:
dF(t)=−cY(t)dt+rF(t)dt+σYIF(t)(λIdt+dWI(t))+σYSF(t)(λSdt+dWS(t)). |
Next, we construct the auxiliary process ˜Xπ(t) as follows:
˜Xπ(t)=Xπ(t)+F(t). | (2.16) |
Note that F(T)=0,˜Xπ(T)=Xπ(T). Let ˜x0=˜Xπ(0)=Xπ(0)+F(0). As such, the optimization problem over Xπ(t) is equivalent to the optimization problem over ˜Xπ(t). By Ito's formula, we have
{d˜Xπ(t)=r˜Xπ(t)dt+(π1(t)σI+π2(t)σSI+σYIF(t))(λIdt+dWI(t))+(π2(t)σS+σYSF(t))(λSdt+dWS(t)),˜Xπ(0)=˜x0. | (2.17) |
Since the market is complete and ˜Xπ(T)=Xπ(T), the optimization problem (2.11) can be expressed as
{maxXπ(T)E[U(Xπ(T))],s.t.E[H(T)Xπ(T)]≤˜x0, E[H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))+]≤ε1,P(Xπ(T)≥L2)≥1−ε2. | (2.18) |
Basak and Shapiro [17] has solved the ES- or VaR-constrained optimization problem.
In this section, we shall derive the optimal investment strategy under a joint VaR-ES constraint. We first present the optimal terminal wealths without constraints and with a VaR and an ES constraint presented in [17].
Lemma 3.1. For the unconstrained optimization problem (2.12), the optimal terminal wealth denoted by Xπ∗,yM(T) is given by
Xπ∗,yM(T)=I(yMH(T)), | (3.1) |
where the Lagrangian multiplier yM solves
E[H(T)Xπ∗,yM(T)]=˜x0. | (3.2) |
To avoid triviality, we make the following assumption:
Assumption 3.2. The risk constraints in problem (2.11) are binding, i.e.,
E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yM(T))+]>ε1,P(Xπ∗,yM(T)≥L2)<1−ε2. | (3.3) |
Lemma 3.3. Assume ˜x0≥L2E[H(T)1{H(T)≤H∗}], where H∗ solves P(H(T)≥H∗)=ε2 for a given 0<ε2<1, then for the VaR-constrained optimization problem (2.13), the optimal terminal wealth denoted by Xπ∗,yVaR(T) is as follows, with yVaR>0 satisfying E[H(T)Xπ∗,yVaR(T)]=˜x0:
Xπ∗,yVaR(T)={I(yVaRH(T)),H(T)<H2,L2,H2≤H(T)<H∗,I(yVaRH(T)),H(T)≥H∗, | (3.4) |
where H2=U′(L2)yVaR. Furthermore, yVaR>yM.
Proof. See Proposition 1 in [17].
Lemma 3.4. Assume ˜x0≥L1e−rT−ε1 for a given 0<ε1<∞, then for the ES-constrained optimization problem (2.14), the optimal terminal wealth Xπ∗,yES,λES(T) is as follows
Xπ∗,yES,λES(T)={I(yESH(T)),H(T)<H_1,L1,H_1≤H(T)<¯H1,I((yES−λES)H(T)),H(T)≥¯H1, | (3.5) |
where H_1=U′(L1)yES, ¯H1=U′(L1)yES−λES and yES>0,λES>0 are determined by
{E[H(T)Xπ∗,yES,λES(T)]=˜x0,E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yES,λES(T))+]=ε1. | (3.6) |
Proof. See Proposition 4 in [17].
Note that yES>yM,yVaR>yM. Therefore, based on Assumption 3.2, we have that
E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yVaR(T))+]>ε1,P(Xπ∗,yES,λES(T)≥L2)<1−ε2. | (3.7) |
Using a Lagrange dual method, we consider an unconstrained optimization problem as follows:
{maxXπ(T)E[L(Xπ(T),λ1,λ2)],s.t.E[H(T)Xπ(T)]≤˜x0, | (3.8) |
where
L(Xπ(T),λ1,λ2)=U(Xπ(T))−λ1H(T)(L1−X(T))1{Xπ(T)≤L1}+λ21{Xπ(T)≥L2}, | (3.9) |
for any λ1>0,λ2>0.
Theorem 3.5. Under Assumption 3.2, if there exists λ∗1>0,λ∗2>0 such that Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) solves problem (3.8) and satisfies
{P(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T)≥L2)=1−ε2,E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))+]=ε1, | (3.10) |
then Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) is the optimal solution to optimization problem (2.11).
Proof. Assume that Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) is the optimal solution to problem (3.8) with condition (3.10). As Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) is feasible for problem (2.17), we have
E[U(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))]≤maxXπ(T)E[U(Xπ(T))], |
where Xπ(T) is an arbitrary feasible solution for problem (2.17). On the other hand, since Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) solves (3.8), we have
E[L(Xπ(T),λ∗1,λ∗2)]≤E[L(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T),λ∗1,λ∗2)]. |
That is,
E[U(Xπ(T))−λ∗1H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))1{Xπ(T)≤L1}+λ∗21{Xπ(T)≥L2}]≤E[U(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))−λ∗1H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))1{Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T)≤L1}+λ∗21{Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T)≥L2}]. |
Since Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) satisfies (3.10) and Xπ(T) satisfies the joint VaR-ES constraint, we have
E[U(Xπ(T))≤E[U(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))]+λ∗1(E[λ∗1H(T)(L1−Xπ(T))1{Xπ(T)≤L1}]−ε1)+λ∗2(1−ε2−P(Xπ(T)≥L2))≤E[U(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))]. |
Hence,
maxXπ(T)E[U(Xπ(T))≤E[U(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))], |
which concludes the proof.
Proposition 3.6. Let H∗ solve P(H(T)≥H∗)=ε2 for 0<ε2<1. Assume ˜x0≥˜xmin0, where ˜xmin0=L1e2M(0)+V2(0)2−ε1+E[H(T)(L2−L1)1{H(T)<H∗}]. Under Assumption 3.2, for the joint VaR-ES constrained optimization problem (2.11), the optimal terminal wealth Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T) is as follows with the multipliers λ∗1 and y∗, satisfying:
{E[H(T)Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T)]=˜x0,E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T))+]=ε1. | (3.11) |
Case Ⅰ. If U′(L2)y∗<H∗<U′(L1)y∗, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T)={I(y∗H(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y∗,L2,U′(L2)y∗≤H(T)<H∗,I(y∗H(T)),H∗≤H(T)<U′(L1)y∗,L1,U′(L1)y∗≤H(T)<U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,I((y∗−λ∗1)H(T)),H(T)≥U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1. | (3.12) |
Case Ⅱ. If U′(L1)y∗≤H∗<U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T)={I(y∗H(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y∗,L2,U′(L2)y∗≤H(T)<H∗,L1,H∗≤H(T)<U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,I((y∗−λ∗1)H(T)),H(T)≥U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1. | (3.13) |
Case Ⅲ. If H∗≥U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T)={I(y∗H(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y∗,L2,U′(L2)y∗≤H(T)<H∗,I((y∗−λ∗1)H(T)),H(T)≥H∗. | (3.14) |
Proof. We solve problem (3.8) by the Lagrange dual theory, then for each y>0,λ1>0,λ2>0, consider the following optimization problem:
maxXπ(T)E[˜L(Xπ(T),λ1,λ2,y)], | (3.15) |
where
˜L(Xπ(T),λ1,λ2,y)=L(Xπ(T),λ1,λ2)−yH(T)Xπ(T). |
Problem (3.15) can be viewed as a static optimization problem. To solve problem (3.15), we consider a pointwise optimization problem
maxx≥0(˜Uλ1,λ2(x)−yx), | (3.16) |
where
˜Uλ1,λ2(x)=U(x)−λ1(L1−x)1{x≤L1}+λ21{x≥L2}. | (3.17) |
Define
kλ2=U(L2)+λ2−U(L1)L2−L1, | (3.18) |
which is the slope of the straight line linking points (L1,U(L1)) and (L2,U(L2)+λ2).
Since ˜Uλ1,λ2 is non-concave, Proposition A.1 solves problem (3.16) by employing the concavification method, then an optimal terminal wealth to (3.15) is
Xπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)=˜x∗,λ1,λ2(yH(T)), | (3.19) |
where x∗,λ1,λ2(z) is defined in (A.2), (A.5) and (A.7). It remains to find the multipliers y∗,λ∗1,λ∗2 via the complementary slackness conditions
{E[H(T)Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T)]=˜x0,E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T))+]=ε1,P(Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T)≥L2)=1−ε2. | (3.20) |
To prove the existence of the Lagrange multipliers, we shall choose λ1,λ2 as functions of y by using VaR and ES constraints.
Case Ⅰ. If H∗<U′(L1)y, then ˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z) in (3.19) is given by (A.2); that is,
Xπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,U′(L2)y≤H(T)<U′(˜L)y,I(yH(T)),U′(˜L)y≤H(T)<U′(L1)y,L1,U′(L1)y≤H(T)<U′(L1)y−λ1,I((y−λ1)H(T)),H(T)≥U′(L1)y−λ1, |
where ˜L∈(L1,L2) is the solution to (A.3). To meet the VaR constraint, we let H∗=U′(˜L)y and define
λ2=U(˜L)−U(L2)+U′(˜L)(L2−˜L)ˆ=g1(y). |
Since ddx(U(x)−U(L2)+U′(x)(L2−x))=U″(x)(L2−x)<0 for L1<x<L2, we have λ2>U(L2)−U(L2)+U′(L2)(L2−L2)=0.
We next show λ1 can also been chosen as a function of y by using the ES constraint. For a given y>0, define
V1(λ1)ˆ=E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,λ1,λ2(T))+]=E[H(T)(L1−I((y−λ1)H(T))1{H(T)≥U′(L1)y−λ1}]. | (3.21) |
We can conclude that V1(λ1) is a continuous and decreasing function in λ1 and, thus, bijective. Note that when λ1 tends to zero, the optimal terminal wealth tends to Xπ∗,yVaR(T) given in (3.4). Assumption 3.2 yields limλ1→0V1(λ1)=E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yVaR(T))+]>ε1. When λ1 tends to y, it holds that
limλ1→yXπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,U′(L2)y≤H(T)<H∗,I(yH(T)),H∗≤H(T)<U′(L1)y,L1,H(T)≥U′(L1)y, |
which implies that limλ1→yV1(λ1)=0<ε1. By the intermediate value theorem, for a given y, there exists a unique λ1ˆ=h1(y) such that V1(λ1)=ε1.
Case Ⅱ. If U′(L1)y≤H∗<U′(L1)y−λ1, then ˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z) in (3.19) is given by (A.5); that is,
Xπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,U′(L2)y≤H(T)<kλ2y,L1,kλ2y≤H(T)<U′(L1)y−λ1,I((y−λ1)H(T)),H(T)≥U′(L1)y−λ1. |
To ensure the VaR constraint holds, we let H∗=kλ2y and define
λ2=U(L1)−U(L2)+kλ2(L2−L1)ˆ=h2(y). |
It is easy to check λ2=(L1−L2)(U(L1)−U(L2)L1−L2−kλ2)>0.
Similarly, when λ1 tends to zero, it holds limλ1→0V1(λ1)=E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yVaR(T))+]>ε1. When λ1 tends to y, the optimal terminal wealth tends to
limλ1→yXπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,U′(L2)y≤H(T)<H∗,L1,H(T)≥H∗, |
which implies limλ1→yV1(λ1)=0<ε1. Thus, for a given y, there exists a unique λ1ˆ=h2(y) such that V1(λ1)=ε1.
Case Ⅲ. If H∗≥U′(L1)y−λ1, then ˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z) in (3.19) is given by (A.7); that is,
Xπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,U′(L2)y≤H(T)<U′(ˆL)y−λ1,I((y−λ1)H(T)),H(T)≥U′(ˆL)y−λ1, |
where ˆL∈(0,L1) is the solution to (A.8).
For a given y>0, we have limλ1→0V1(λ1)=E[H(T)(L1−Xπ∗,yVaR(T))+]>ε1 and
limλ1→yXπ∗,λ1,λ2(T)={I(yH(T)),H(T)<U′(L2)y,L2,H(T)≥U′(L2)y. |
Hence, limλ1→yV1(λ1)=0<ε1. By the intermediate value theorem, for a given y, there exists a unique λ1ˆ=h3(y) such that V1(λ1)=ε1.
To meet the VaR constraint, we let H∗=U′(ˆL)y−λ1 and define
λ2=U(ˆL)−U(L2)−λ1(L1−ˆL)+(U′(ˆL)+λ1)(L2−ˆL)ˆ=g3(y). |
Since ddx(U(x)−U(L2)−λ1(L1−x)+(U′(x)+λ1)(L2−x))=U″(x)(L2−x)<0, for 0≤x≤L1, it holds that λ2>(L1−L2)(U(L1)−U(L2)L1−L2−(U′(L1)+λ1))>0.
In total, λ1,λ2 can be chosen as functions of y:
(λ1,λ2)=1{H∗<U′(L1)y}(h1(y),g1(y))+1{U′(L1)y≤H∗<U′(L1)y−λ1}(h2(y),g2(y))+1{H∗≥U′(L1)y−λ1}(h3(y),g3(y))ˆ=(h(y),g(y)). |
Define
V2(y)=E[H(T)Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)]. |
It remains to show there exists a unique root y∗ to the budget constraint V2(y)=˜x0. Some simple calculations yield that
V2(y)=E[H(T)Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)≥L1}]+E[H(T)Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)<L1}]=E[H(T)Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)≥L1}]+E[L1H(T)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)<L1}]−ε1=E[H(T)(Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)−L1)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)≥L1}]+E[L1H(T)]−ε1=E[H(T)(Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)−L1)1{Xπ∗,h(y),g(y)(T)≥L1}]+L1e2M(0)+V2(0)2−ε1. |
It is easy to conclude
limy→0V2(y)=∞,limy→∞V2(y)=L1e2M(0)+V2(0)2−ε1+E[H(T)(L2−L1)1{H(T)<H∗}]. |
Furthermore, V2(y) is a continuous and decreasing function with respect to y. Again, by the intermediate value theorem, we have that when ˜x0≥˜xmin0, there exists a unique solution y∗ to the equation V2(y)=˜x0. Therefore, y∗,λ∗1=h(y∗),λ∗2=g(y∗) are corresponding Lagrange multipliers and Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T) given in (3.12)–(3.14) is the optimal solution to problem (2.11).
Since λ1,λ2 are related to ε1,ε2, we use the superscript ε1,ε2 in place of λ1,λ2 in Xπ∗,λ∗1,λ∗2(T); that is, the optimal terminal wealth is written as Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T).
Proposition 3.7. Let H∗ solve P(H(T)≥H∗)=ε2 for 0<ε2<1. Assume ˜x0≥˜xmin0, where ˜xmin0=L1e2M(0)+V2(0)2−ε1+E[H(T)(L2−L1)1{H(T)<H∗}]. Under Assumption 3.2, for the joint VaR-ES constrained optimization problem (2.11), the optimal wealth process and the optimal strategy are given as follows, with the multipliers λ∗1 and y∗ satisfying (3.11):
Case Ⅰ. If U′(L2)y∗<H∗<U′(L1)y∗, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)=2h1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2e(M(t)+V2(t)2)(Φ(d2(H∗,H(t),t))−Φ(d2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)))−h1(H∗,H(t),t)+L1e(M(t)+V2(t)2)(Φ(d2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t))−Φ(d2(U′(L1)y∗,H(t),t)))+h2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t)−F(t), |
where F(t) is given in (2.15),
h1(u,H(t),t)=∫d1(u,H(t),t)−∞I(y∗H(t)eR(z,t))eR(z,t)φ(z)dz,h2(u,H(t),t)=∫+∞d1(u,H(t),t)I((y∗−λ∗1)H(t)eR(z,t))eR(z,t)φ(z)dz. |
with d1(x,H(t),t)=(log(x/H(t))−M(t))/V(t), d2(x,H(t),t)=d1(x,H(t),t)−V(t), R(x,t)=V(t)x+M(t), M(t) and V(t) given in (2.7) and Φ and φ being the standard normal cumulative distribution function and the standard normal density function, respectively.
The optimal money invested in the inflation-linked indexed zero-coupon bond and the stock at time t is given by:
{π∗1(t)=σ−1I[(λI−σ−1SσSIλS)H(t)F1(y∗,H(t),t)+(σ−1SσYSσSI−σYI)F(t)],π∗2(t)=σ−1S[H(t)F1(y∗,H(t),t)λS−σYSF(t)], | (3.22) |
where
F1(y∗,H(t),t)=I(y∗H(t)eR(d1(H∗,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(H∗,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(H∗,H(t),t)+I((y∗−λ∗1)H(t)eR(d1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t)−2I(y∗H(t)eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2e(M(t)+V2(t)2)(ˉφ2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉφ2(H∗,H(t),t))+L1e(M(t)+V2(t)2)(ˉφ2(U′(L1)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉφ2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t))+ˉh1(H∗,H(t),t)−2ˉh1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉh2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t), |
with ˉφi(u,H(t),t)=−φ(di(u,H(t),t))/(v(t)H(t)), for i=1,2,
ˉh1(u,H(t),t)=∫d1(u,H(t),t)−∞I′(y∗H(t)eR(z,t))y∗e2R(z,t)φ(z)dz, |
and
ˉh2(u,H(t),t)=∫+∞d1(u,H(t),t)I′((y∗−λ∗1)H(t)eR(z,t))(y∗−λ∗1)e2R(z,t)φ(z)dz. |
Case Ⅱ. If U′(L1)y∗≤H∗<U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)=h1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2eM(t)+V2(t)2(Φ(d2(H∗,H(t),t))−Φ(d2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)))+L1eM(t)+V2(t)2(Φ(d2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t))−Φ(d2(H∗,H(t),t)))+h2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t)−F(t). |
The optimal money invested in the inflation-linked indexed zero-coupon bond and the stock at time t is given by:
{π∗1(t)=σ−1I[(λI−σ−1SσSIλS)H(t)F2(y∗,H(t),t)+(σ−1SσYSσSI−σYI)F(t)],π∗2(t)=σ−1S[H(t)F2(y∗,H(t),t)λS−σYSF(t)], | (3.23) |
where
F2(y∗,H(t),t)=I((y∗−λ∗1)H(t)eR(d1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t)−I(y∗H(t)eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2eM(t)+V2(t)2(ˉφ2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉφ2(H∗,H(t),t))+L1eM(t)+V2(t)2(ˉφ2(H∗,H(t),t)−ˉφ2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t))−ˉh1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉh2(U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1,H(t),t). |
Case Ⅲ. If H∗≥U′(L1)y∗−λ∗1, then
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)=h1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2eM(t)+V2(t)2(Φ(d2(H∗,H(t),t))−Φ(d2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)))+h2(H∗,H(t),t)−F(t). |
The optimal money invested in the inflation-linked indexed zero-coupon bond and the stock at time t is given by:
{π∗1(t)=σ−1I[(λI−σ−1SσSIλS)H(t)F3(y∗,H(t),t)+(σ−1SσYSσSI−σYI)F(t)],π∗2(t)=σ−1S[H(t)F3(y∗,H(t),t)λS−σYSF(t)], | (3.24) |
where
F3(y∗,H(t),t)=I((y∗−λ∗1)H(t)eR(d1(H∗,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(H∗,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(H∗,H(t),t)−I(y∗H(t)eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t))eR(d1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t),t)ˉφ1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)+L2eM(t)+V2(t)2(ˉφ2(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉφ2(H∗,H(t),t))−ˉh1(U′(L2)y∗,H(t),t)−ˉh2(H∗,H(t),t). |
Proof. Since H(t)˜Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t) is an F−martingale, we have
Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)=1H(t)E[H(T)˜Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(T)|Ft]−F(t). | (3.25) |
Note that log(H(T)H(t)) is normally distributed with a mean M(t) and a variance V2(t), where M(t) and V(t) are given in (2.7). Therefore, substituting Eqs (3.12)–(3.14) into Eq (3.25), we can obtain the expressions for Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t) by some straightforward calculations. Note that Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t) is a function of (t,H(t)). By Ito's formula, we have
dXπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)=G(t,H(t))dt+(λIH(t)∂Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)∂H(t)−σYIF(t))dWI(t)+(λSH(t)∂Xπ∗,ε1,ε2(t)∂H(t)−σYSF(t))dWS(t), | (3.26) |
where G(t,H(t)) is a function of (t,H(t)). Since we are only interested in the diffusion part, here we explicitly derive the diffusion parts of dXπ∗,ε1,ε2(t). By comparing the diffusion terms of dXπ∗,ε1,ε2(t) with (2.8), we can derive the optimal money invested in the inflation-linked zero-coupon bond and stock.
In this section, we carry out some numerical calculations to investigate the impact of the joint VaR-ES constraint on the optimal terminal wealth.
Assume that
U(x)=xγ,x≥0,0<γ<1. |
For all the computations, the values of certain parameters are held fixed except otherwise indicated: T=10,γ=0.3,r=0.01,μ=0.03,c=0.1,y0=5,λI=0.01,λS=0.23,σYI=σYS=0,x0=14.5,L1=10,L2=20,ε1=0.7,ε2=0.1.
Figures 1 and 2 graph the optimal terminal value Xπ∗(T) versus H(T) with different constraints. From Figure 1, we can observe that in the bad-economic-states region, the optimal terminal wealth corresponding to an ES constraint is higher than that without constraints, while the optimal terminal wealth corresponding to a VaR constraint is lower than that without constraints, which is consistent with the observations in [17]: An ES constraint can provide a better protection for bad economic states while a VaR constraint leads to heavier losses. It is noted that from Figure 1, a joint VaR-ES constraint can also improve the risk management of the bad economic states. Furthermore, we can find that from Figure 2, comparing with an ES constraint, more states are insured against and, therefore, the intermediate-economic-states region enlarges under a VaR-ES constraint, which implies a joint VaR-ES can not only provide a better protection for bad economic states, but also decrease the volatility of the optimal terminal wealth.
Table 1 lists means and standard deviations of the optimal terminal wealth and some probabilities for different constraints. We observe that the mean, the standard deviation of the optimal terminal wealth and the probability P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) without constraints are much higher than those with constraints. This is because the manager shall take more conservative allocation strategies to attain the constraints at a cost of lowering the optimal terminal wealth in good economic states regions, resulting in lower means, less volatilities and smaller P(Xπ∗(T)≥100). It can be seen from Table 1 that the probability P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) corresponding to the case of no constraints is lower than that under a VaR constraint and is higher than that under an ES constraint or a joint VaR-ES constraint, consistent with the observations from Figure 1 that in the bad-economic-states region, an ES or a joint VaR-ES constraint can provide a better protection, while a VaR constraint leads to a lower optimal terminal wealth. Table 1 also numerically verifies the observations in Figures 1 and 2, where in contrast to a pure VaR or an ES constraint, a joint VaR-ES constraint can not only improve the risk management for the bad economic states but also decreases the volatility of the optimal terminal wealth.
constraints | no constraints | VaR | ES | VaR-ES |
mean | 61.09 | 47.65 | 54.97 | 48.14 |
std dev | 98.70 | 71.50 | 89.09 | 72.55 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.158 | 0.104 | 0.137 | 0.1 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.018 | 0.033 | 0.014 | 0.016 |
Table 2 presents some probabilities, means and standard deviations of the optimal terminal wealth under a joint VaR-ES constraint for different (ε1,ε2) with (L1,L2)=(10,20). From Table 2 we can see that for a fixed ε1, the mean, the standard deviation and the probability P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) all increase in ε2, while the probabilities P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) and P(Xπ∗(T)=L2) decrease in ε2. The reason is that in order to achieve a stricter VaR constraint with a smaller ε2, the manager takes a more prudent strategy such that the optimal terminal wealth becomes less volatile, resulting in a lower expectation and a lower probability P(Xπ∗(T)≥100). In addition, more bad economic states are insured against at a cost of lowering the optimal terminal wealth in bad-economic-states regions and, therefore, leads to a lower P(Xπ∗(T)≤3). We can also observe that for a fixed ε2, the mean, the standard deviation and the probabilities P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) and P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) all increase in ε1, while the probability P(Xπ∗(T)=L2) decreases in ε1. This is due to the fact that with ε1 decreasing, in order to achieve a stricter ES constraint, the manager becomes more conservative. Therefore, the optimal terminal wealth with a smaller ε1 has a lower expectation, a less standard deviation and lower probabilities P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) and P(Xπ∗(T)=L2). However, as an ES constraint can improve the risk management of the bad economic states, a smaller ε1 brings a higher value of the optimal terminal wealth in the bad-economic-states region, leading to a lower probability P(Xπ∗(T)≤3).
(ε1,ε2) | (0.7, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.06) |
mean | 48.14 | 47.83 | 44.44 |
std dev | 72.55 | 71.87 | 64.26 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.1 | 0.098 | 0.087 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.016 | 0.012 | 0.021 |
P(Xπ∗(T)=L2) | 0.345 | 0.374 | 0.424 |
In this paper, we investigated the optimal portfolio selection problem for a DC plan manager under a joint VaR-ES constraint. The constraint requires that the terminal wealth is no less than a constant protection level with a given probability, while at the same time requires that the expected present value of the losses given the regulatory level is no more than a predetermined constant. By using a concavification technique and a martingale method, we derived the semi-analytical formulas for the optimal wealth process and the optimal wealth invested in the risky assets. Numerical results illustrated that comparing with a pure VaR constraint, a regulation with a joint VaR-ES can provide a better protection for the bad economic states. Comparing with a pure ES, more bad economic states are insured under a joint VaR-ES constraint, resulting in a less volatility of the optimal terminal wealth.
Proposition A.1. For any λ1>0,λ2>0, let ˜Uλ1,λ2 and kλ2 be defined by (3.17) and (3.18), respectively, then for y>0, the concave envelope of ˜Uλ1,λ2, denoted by ˜Ucλ1,λ2, is as follows:
Case Ⅰ. If kλ2<U′(L1), then
˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)={U(x)−λ1(L1−x),0≤x<L1,U(x),L1≤x<˜L,c˜L(x−˜L)+U(˜L),˜L≤x<L2,U(x)+λ2,x≥L2 | (A.1) |
and
˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z)={I(z),z<U′(L2),L2,U′(L2)≤z<U′(˜L),I(z),U′(˜L)≤z<U′(L1),L1,U′(L1)≤z<U′(L1)+λ1I(z−λ1),z≥U′(L1)+λ1, | (A.2) |
where ˜L is the unique solution in the interval (L1,L2) to the equation
U(L2)+λ2−U(x)L2−x=U′(x). | (A.3) |
Case Ⅱ. If U′(L1)≤kλ2<U′(L1)+λ1, then
˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)={U(x)−λ1(L1−x),0≤x<L1,kλ2(x−L1)+U(L1),L1≤x<L2,U(x)+λ2,x≥L2 | (A.4) |
and
˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z)={I(z),z<U′(L2),L2,U′(L2)≤z<kλ2,L1,kλ2≤z<U′(L1)+λ1I(z−λ1),z≥U′(L1)+λ1. | (A.5) |
Case Ⅲ. If kλ2≥U′(L1)+λ1, then
˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)={U(x)−λ1(L1−x),0≤x<ˆL,(U′(ˆL)+λ1)(x−ˆL)+U(L1)−λ1(L1−ˆL),ˆL≤x<L2,U(x)+λ2,x≥L2 | (A.6) |
and
˜x∗,λ1,λ2(z)={I(z),z<U′(L2),L2,U′(L2)≤y<U′(ˆL)+λ1,I(z−λ1),z≥U′(ˆL)+λ1, | (A.7) |
where ˆL is the unique solution in the interval (0,L1) to the equation
U(L2)+λ2−U(x)+λ1(L1−x)L2−x=U′(x)+λ1. | (A.8) |
Proof. To find the concave envelope of ˜U, we consider three cases: kλ2<U′(L1), U′(L1)≤kλ2<U′(z1)+λ1 and kλ2≥U′(z1)+λ1, respectively.
Case Ⅰ. For kλ2<U′(L1), we let ˜L be the tangent point of the line starting at (L2,U(L2)+λ2) to the curve U(x),L1≤x≤L2. It is easy to verify that there exists a unique solution to (A.3), then the concave envelope of ˜Uλ1,λ2 over [0,∞) is given by (A.1).
It is easy to obtain the superdifferential of ˜Ucλ1,λ2 as follows:
(˜Ucλ1,λ2)′(x)={∞,x=0,[U′(L1)+λ1,∞),0<x<L1,(U′(˜L),U′(L1)],L1≤x<˜L,{U′(˜L)},˜L≤x<L2,[0,U′(L2)),x≥L2. |
We can derive the maximizer of {˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)−xy} by finding those points x∗,λ1,λ2(y)∈[0,L1]∪[L1,˜L]∪[L2,∞) for which zero is in the super-differential of the function ˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)−xy, which yields (A.2).
Case Ⅱ. For U′(L1)≤kλ2<U′(L1)+λ1, we have that ˜Uλ1,λ2(x)≤kλ2(x−L1)+U(L1) for L1≤x<L2. Thus, the concave envelope of ˜Uλ1,λ2 over [0,∞) is given by (A.4). Similar to derivation of (A.2), we can obtain the maximizer of {˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)−xy} is given by (A.5).
Case Ⅲ. For kλ2≥U′(L1)+λ1, we let ˆL be the tangent point of the line starting at (L2,U(L2)+λ2) to the curve ˜Uλ1,λ2(x),x≤L1. It is easy to prove that Eq (A.8) has a unique solution in the interval [0,L1], then the concave envelope of ˜Uλ1,λ2 over [0,∞) is given by (A.6). Using the same arguments as in deriving (A.2), we have that the maximizer of {˜Ucλ1,λ2(x)−xy} is given by (A.7).
The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.
The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees and the editor for their comments and suggestions.
The research of Yinghui Dong was supported by Humanities and Social Science Research Projects in Ministry of Education (20YJAZH025) and the NNSF of China (Grant Nos. 12071335, 12371474).
The authors declare that there is no conflict of interest regarding the publication of this paper.
[1] |
G. Deelstra, M. Grasselli, P. F. Koehl, Optimal design of the guarantee for defined contribution funds, J. Econ. Dyn. Control, 28 (2004), 2239–2260. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2003.10.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2003.10.003
![]() |
[2] |
D. Blake, D. Wright, Y. Zhang, Age-dependent investing: Optimal funding and investment strategies in defined contribution pension plans when members are rational life cycle financial planners, J. Econ. Dyn. Control, 38 (2014), 105–124. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.11.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2013.11.001
![]() |
[3] |
J. Gao, Optimal portfolios for DC pension plans under a CEV model, Insur. Math. Econ., 44 (2009), 479–490. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2009.01.005 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2009.01.005
![]() |
[4] |
E. Vigna, S. Haberman, Optimal investment strategy for defined contribution pension schemes, Insur. Math. Econ., 28 (2001), 233–262. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6687(00)00077-9 doi: 10.1016/S0167-6687(00)00077-9
![]() |
[5] |
S. Haberman, E. Vigna, Optimal investment strategies and risk measures in defined contribution pension schemes, Insur. Math. Econ., 31 (2002), 35–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6687(02)00128-2 doi: 10.1016/S0167-6687(02)00128-2
![]() |
[6] |
Y. Zeng, D. P. Li, Z. Chen, Z. Yang, Ambiguity aversion and optimal derivative-based pension investment with stochastic income and volatility, J. Econ. Dyn. Control, 88 (2018), 70–103. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2018.01.023 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2018.01.023
![]() |
[7] |
L. Zhang, H. Zhang, H. X. Yao, Optimal investment management for a defined contribution pension fund under imperfect information, Insur. Math. Econ., 79 (2018), 210–224. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.01.007 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.01.007
![]() |
[8] |
A. J. G. Cairns, D. Blake, K. Dowd, Stochastic lifestyling: Optimal dynamic asset allocation for defined contribution pension plans, J. Econ. Dyn. Control, 30 (2006), 843–877. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2005.03.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2005.03.009
![]() |
[9] |
H. X. Yao, Z. Yang, P. Chen, Markowitz's mean-variance defined contribution pension fund management under inflation: A continuous-time model, Insur. Math. Econ., 53 (2013), 851–863. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.10.002 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.10.002
![]() |
[10] |
G. H. Guan, Z. X. Liang, Optimal management of DC pension plan in a stochastic interest rate and stochastic volatility framework, Insur. Math. Econ., 57 (2014), 58–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2014.05.004 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2014.05.004
![]() |
[11] |
P. Wang, Z. F. Li, J. Y. Sun, Robust portfolio choice for a DC pension plan with inflation risk and mean-reverting risk premium under ambiguity, Optimization, 70 (2021), 191–224. https://doi.org/10.1080/02331934.2019.1679812 doi: 10.1080/02331934.2019.1679812
![]() |
[12] |
A. H. Zhang, R. Korn, C. O. Ewald, Optimal management and inflation protection for defined contribution pension plans, Blatter DGVFM., 28 (2007), 239–258. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11857-007-0019-x doi: 10.1007/s11857-007-0019-x
![]() |
[13] |
J. F. Boulier, S. J. Huang, G. Taillard, Optimal management under stochastic interest rates: the case of a protected defined contribution pension fund, Insur. Math. Econ., 28 (2001), 173–189. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6687(00)00073-1 doi: 10.1016/S0167-6687(00)00073-1
![]() |
[14] |
J. Y. Sun, Y. J. Li, L. Zhang, Robust portfolio choice for a defined contribution pension plan with stochastic income and interest rate, Commun. Stat.-Theor. M., 47 (2018), 4106–4130. https://doi.org/10.1080/03610926.2017.1367815 doi: 10.1080/03610926.2017.1367815
![]() |
[15] |
G. H. Guan, Z. X. Liang, Optimal management of DC pension plan under loss aversion and Value-at-Risk constraints, Insur. Math. Econ., 69 (2016), 224–237. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.05.014 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2016.05.014
![]() |
[16] |
Y. H. Dong, H. Zheng, Optimal investment with S-shaped utility and trading and Value at Risk constraints: An application to defined contribution pension plan, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 281 (2020), 346–356. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.08.034 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2019.08.034
![]() |
[17] |
S. Basak, A. Shapiro, Value-at-Risk-based risk management: Optimal policies and asset prices, Rev. Financ. Stud., 14 (2001), 371–405. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/14.2.371 doi: 10.1093/rfs/14.2.371
![]() |
[18] |
S. Basak, A general equilibrium model of portfolio insurance, Rev. Financ. Stud., 8 (1995), 1059–1090. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/8.4.1059 doi: 10.1093/rfs/8.4.1059
![]() |
[19] |
Y. H. Dong, H. Zheng, Optimal investment of DC pension plan under short-selling constraints and portfolio insurance, Insur. Math. Econ., 85 (2019), 47–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.12.005 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.12.005
![]() |
[20] |
A. Chen, T. Nguyen, M. Stadje, Optimal investment under VaR-regulation and minimum insurance, Insur. Math. Econ., 79 (2018), 194–209. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.01.008 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2018.01.008
![]() |
[21] | H. Mi, Z. Q. Xu, D. F. Yang, Optimal management of DC pension plan with inflation risk and tail VaR constraint, arXiv. preprint, 2023, https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2309.01936 |
[22] |
F. Y. Zhang, Non-concave portfolio optimization with average Value-at-Risk, Math. Finan. Econ., 17 (2023), 203–237. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-023-00332-0 doi: 10.1007/s11579-023-00332-0
![]() |
[23] |
P. Y. Wei, Risk management with expected shortfall, Math. Finan. Econ., 15 (2021), 847–883. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-021-00298-x doi: 10.1007/s11579-021-00298-x
![]() |
[24] |
Z. Chen, Z. F. Li, Y. Zeng, J. Y. Sun, Asset allocation under loss aversion and minimum performance constraint in a DC pension plan with inflation risk, Insur. Math. Econ., 75 (2017), 137–150. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2017.05.009 doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2017.05.009
![]() |
[25] |
L. He, Z. X. Liang, Y. Liu, M. Ma, Optimal control of DC pension plan management under two incentive schemes, N. Am. Actuar. J., 23 (2019), 120–141. https://doi.org/10.1080/10920277.2018.1513371 doi: 10.1080/10920277.2018.1513371
![]() |
1. | Zilan Liu, Huanying Zhang, Yijun Wang, Ya Huang, Optimal Investment Strategy for DC Pension Plan with Stochastic Salary and Value at Risk Constraint in Stochastic Volatility Model, 2024, 13, 2075-1680, 543, 10.3390/axioms13080543 |
constraints | no constraints | VaR | ES | VaR-ES |
mean | 61.09 | 47.65 | 54.97 | 48.14 |
std dev | 98.70 | 71.50 | 89.09 | 72.55 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.158 | 0.104 | 0.137 | 0.1 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.018 | 0.033 | 0.014 | 0.016 |
(ε1,ε2) | (0.7, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.06) |
mean | 48.14 | 47.83 | 44.44 |
std dev | 72.55 | 71.87 | 64.26 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.1 | 0.098 | 0.087 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.016 | 0.012 | 0.021 |
P(Xπ∗(T)=L2) | 0.345 | 0.374 | 0.424 |
constraints | no constraints | VaR | ES | VaR-ES |
mean | 61.09 | 47.65 | 54.97 | 48.14 |
std dev | 98.70 | 71.50 | 89.09 | 72.55 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.158 | 0.104 | 0.137 | 0.1 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.018 | 0.033 | 0.014 | 0.016 |
(ε1,ε2) | (0.7, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.1) | (0.6, 0.06) |
mean | 48.14 | 47.83 | 44.44 |
std dev | 72.55 | 71.87 | 64.26 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≥100) | 0.1 | 0.098 | 0.087 |
P(Xπ∗(T)≤3) | 0.016 | 0.012 | 0.021 |
P(Xπ∗(T)=L2) | 0.345 | 0.374 | 0.424 |