Research article

Interest rates affect public expenditure growth

  • Received: 22 July 2023 Revised: 17 November 2023 Accepted: 24 November 2023 Published: 29 November 2023
  • JEL Codes: H61, H62, G21, H25

  • The aim of this paper is to analyze interest rates and public spending to provide policy implications. Concretely, it explores the influence of these rates on public expenditure growth as opposite to the traditional direction view, dealing with 216 countries for the 1972–2021 period and estimating system GMM models. A balanced subsample is used for assessing Granger causality through a recent panel technique. The results are robust for the used dependent and target variables and also the methodology. They show that decreasing interest rates are associated with—and in some cases also lead to—lower per capita public expenditure growth. These results can be interpreted as a twofold effect of shifts in relative prices—through fiscal illusion—and of crowding out of private investment with respect to the public sector.

    Citation: Guillermo Peña. Interest rates affect public expenditure growth[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(4): 622-645. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023030

    Related Papers:

    [1] Richard J. Cebula, Don Capener . The impact of federal income tax rate cuts on the municipal bond market in the U.S.: A brief exploratory empirical note. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(2): 407-412. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.2.407
    [2] Jin Liang, Hong-Ming Yin, Xinfu Chen, Yuan Wu . On a Corporate Bond Pricing Model with Credit Rating Migration Risksand Stochastic Interest Rate. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(3): 300-319. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.3.300
    [3] Serçin ŞAHİN, Serkan ÇİÇEK . Interest rate pass-through in Turkey during the period of unconventional interest rate corridor. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 837-859. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.837
    [4] Jie Xiong, Geng Deng, Xindong Wang . Extension of SABR Libor Market Model to handle negative interest rates. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 148-171. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020007
    [5] Lichao Tao, Yuefu Lai, Yanting Ji, Xiangxing Tao . Asian option pricing under sub-fractional vasicek model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(3): 403-419. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023020
    [6] Tolga Tuzcuoğlu . The impact of financial fragility on firm performance: an analysis of BIST companies. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 310-342. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020015
    [7] Longfei Wei, Lu Liu, Jialong Hou . Pricing hybrid-triggered catastrophe bonds based on copula-EVT model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 223-243. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022010
    [8] Lianzhang Bao, Guangliang Zhao, Zhuo Jin . A new equilibrium trading model with asymmetric information. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 217-229. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.217
    [9] Huseyin Tastan, Sercin Sahin . Low-frequency relationship between money growth and inflation in Turkey. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 91-120. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020005
    [10] Manuela Larguinho, José Carlos Dias, Carlos A. Braumann . Pricing and hedging bond options and sinking-fund bonds under the CIR model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(1): 1-34. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022001
  • The aim of this paper is to analyze interest rates and public spending to provide policy implications. Concretely, it explores the influence of these rates on public expenditure growth as opposite to the traditional direction view, dealing with 216 countries for the 1972–2021 period and estimating system GMM models. A balanced subsample is used for assessing Granger causality through a recent panel technique. The results are robust for the used dependent and target variables and also the methodology. They show that decreasing interest rates are associated with—and in some cases also lead to—lower per capita public expenditure growth. These results can be interpreted as a twofold effect of shifts in relative prices—through fiscal illusion—and of crowding out of private investment with respect to the public sector.



    Graphical abstract:

    Interest rates{Crowding out effectFiscal illusion →↑Public Spending

    Highlights:

    ● Interest rates positively affect public expenditure through a double transmission channel.

    ● The mechanism consists of crowding out and fiscal illusion.

    ● The theoretical expectations are empirically confirmed.

    Abbreviations: GMM: generalized method of moments; SGMM: system GMM; FE: fixed effects; OLS: ordinary least squares; GDP: gross domestic product; GFC: Global Financial Crisis; G: public expenditure; D: demand; S: supply; GC: Granger cause; T-bills: Treasury bills; VAT: value added tax

    According to Blanchard (2023), the historical net debt ratios for the major countries are in most cases above 100%. With few exceptions, these debts are significantly higher than they were in 2007, before the beginning of the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). Additionally, reference interest rates have been extremely low in the last years. Traditionally, when the economic growth rate is higher than the neutral interest rate for that period, it is assumed that policies fighting income inequality must be applied in order to reduce the deviation between neutral interest rates and economic growth rate, thereby diminishing inequality. This transmission channel assumes an unequivocal direction of the effect from public spending to interest rates. The effect of public spending on economic growth (Matei, 2020) is also well known. Nonetheless, interest rates can have an impact on public expenditures if we consider the latter as endogenous. So, according to this reasoning, the question would be what interest rate we need, for instance, to fight income inequality through public expenses—i.e., the main target of the present paper is to find what type of shift of interest rates leads to an increase in public spending. For instance, inflation and interest rates are currently rising, and authors as Heinemann (2001) consider that when there is bracket creeping, which is provoked by inflation, the mix of fiscal and monetary illusion allows for real budget expansions. Recently, Murphy and Walsh (2022) have found that, contrary to the theoretical expectation that an increase in public spending will raise interest rates, the effect is negative. Going forward, we can be concerned even about the direction of influence, where the opposite direction of the relationship is relatively less studied. In fact, this topic is even more relevant nowadays with rising interest rates and high debt levels.

    In order to answer these questions, both theoretical and empirical literature is provided on fiscal illusion and concerning the relationship between fiscal policy and interest rates, in addition to showing the main determinants of public expenditure through fiscal illusion and other mechanisms. The empirical estimates analyze the effects of different kinds and specifications of interest rates and also of public expenditure, both for general and for goods and services expenses—respectively, with and without including the financing costs. The full sample database used consists of one of the largest available datasets, covering 216 countries during the 1972–2021 period. The methodology consists of two-step system GMM models, a recent test of Granger causality for panel data and a pairwise Granger causality method for a robustness check. The first methodology is chosen due to its benefits in addressing endogeneity—since two-step system GMM "relies on internal instruments (lagged values, internal transformation) to address the different sources of endogeneity" (Ullah et al., 2018). Causality with panel data and country by country methods are used to check the direction of the influence.

    Murphy and Walsh (2022) suggested the existence of a demand channel that offsets the traditional positive effect of public expenditure on interest rates, where an increase in the spending is associated with an increase in the demand and, thus, higher credit and lower interest rates. The present paper proposes two novel mechanisms for this relationship, which are opposite to the most common direction of influence addressed by the literature. Specifically, when reference rates rise, investment decreases, and—due to the trade-off between public and private investment (Yakita and Yakita, 2017)—public expenditure increases. The second transmission channel is based on fiscal illusion. The public expenditure increases since a rise in interest rates may be perceived by consumers as a higher price for the services supplied by the private sector, mostly determined by the reference rates. Therefore, consumers perceive a decrease in the relative prices of the public sector services—mostly determined by tax rates—ceteris paribus. Additionally, rising interest rates can be perceived by society as a signal of improving economic context, which is associated with higher demand and also with higher tax collection due to automatic stabilizers. Further, new explanations take into account the isolated effect of interest rates without these proposed channels. In particular, raising interest rates leads to higher funding costs. Therefore, policy makers must reduce other public expenditures in order to maintain the initial amount, ceteris paribus, expecting an isolated negative influence.

    The previous theoretical expectations are empirically confirmed, showing the need to reduce the importance of the previous transmission channels if lower indebtedness is desired in a context of rising rates. One of the first possible policy implications includes further improvements in the efficiency of the private sector to balance the shift in relative prices, as well as the trade-off of the investment by economic agents between the public and private sectors. A second possible policy measure would be raising tax rates to compensate the fiscal illusion by the government. An additional achievement of the present study—apart from the large sample, the novel direct/indirect effects and transmission channels, as well as the direction of influence—is the fact of differentiating between public expenditures with and without financing costs. The main limitation of this paper is the lack of a vast literature on this specific direction of causality by other authors. Another limitation is the diverse country sample used—a twofold (dis)advantage.

    The results show a statistically significant and robust positive effect of interest rates on public spending, also confirmed by a robustness check using different methodologies and diverse dependent and independent variables. One of the main reasons the present paper provides for this fact is that a raise in interest rates is associated with higher relative prices and lower demand in the private sector. The demand then shifts towards the goods and services of the public sector due to a crowding out effect, mainly in investment, thus increasing public expenditure. Regarding the fiscal illusion explanation, by raising the interest rates and maintaining the prices of public services—i.e., taxes—consumers perceive a decrease in the relative tax prices of the public sector vs. the private one. Therefore, there is a misperception of the costs of public goods and services, leading to buying or demanding them more and more often than otherwise.

    This paper is divided as follows. After this introduction, Section 2 provides the literature review. Section 3 explains the theory and development of hypotheses, and Section 4 presents the data and methodology. Section 5 shows the results, while Section 6 discusses them and provides a robustness check. Finally, Section 7 provides concluding remarks.

    This section initially deals with the introduction of the concept and main determinants of fiscal illusion due to its possible relevance to the study of the theoretical effects of interest rates on public spending. Second, it analyzes the literature regarding the influence of budget surplus, government debt and public spending on interest rates. Next, it presents the closest papers to the present one, to the author's knowledge. Based on the previous information, the work will propose a theoretical view for the expectations of the effects of monetary policy on public expenditure.

    Onal (2021) recently highlighted that the topic of the size of government is one with a long trajectory, developed in the 1960s thanks to the "public choice" school, which faces so-called "Keynesian biases." From this topic, a related concept emerged: fiscal illusion. Amilcare Puviani (1903) was the first one to provide a theory of this concept. Hotak and Kaneko (2022) referred to fiscal illusion as "taxpayers' perceptions of the gap between their burden and their expectations regarding the provision of public services." Oates (1988) considered this misperception to be fiscal illusion when it is "systematic." Furthermore, there is an incorrect perception of public good costs, considering the tax price lower than the real one (Brennan & Buchanan, 1980; Buchanan, 1967). Jimenez and Afonso (2021) suggested that governments can manipulate citizens through fiscal illusion in order to increase the public sector size.

    A brief literature review on the topic can be found in Facchini (2018). Regarding the first analytical models explaining fiscal illusion, Wagner (1976) developed a model in which this effect leads citizens to underestimate the real costs of public goods —that is, the fiscal price—provoking their overweighted production. One of the most relevant empirical papers in the previous decade is the estimation by Dell'Anno and Mourao (2012) of a fiscal illusion indicator (Mourao 2008, 2011) based on 50 countries for the period between 2000 and 2008. For the regression, they used self-employed workers, tax revenues over GDP, the maximum marginal tax rates in income tax and social security and institutional, political and educational explanatory variables.

    Dollery and Worthington (1996) carried out a literature review of the main articles on fiscal illusion up to the 1990s, studying public expenditure, public consumption or per capita public expenditure as main explanatory variables. They included the following as main explanatory variables, in addition to more recent inclusions: wages (Clotfelter, 1976; Wagner, 1976; Di Lorenzo, 1982a; Marshall, 1991; Dell'Anno and Dollery, 2014), poverty or inequality (Wagner, 1976; Beck, 1984), population (Oates 1975; Clotfelter, 1976; Pommerehne and Schneider, 1978; Di Lorenzo, 1982b; Marshall, 1989, 1991; Heyndels and Smolders, 1994; Dollery and Worthington, 1995), GDP or GDP per capita (Wagner, 1976; Pommerehne and Schneider, 1978; Di Lorenzo, 1982a; Marshall 1991), education or secondary education (Brazer and McCarty, 1987) and trade openness, with a positive correlation (Sáenz et al., 2013).

    Regarding fiscal variables, it is worth highlighting the indicator of tax simplicity (Wagner, 1976; Pommerehne and Schneider, 1978; Munley and Greene, 1978; Heyndels and Smolders, 1994; Worthington, 1994; Dollery and Worthington, 1995; Dell'Anno and Dollery, 2014) and the ratio of indirect taxes over direct taxes (Clotfelter, 1976; Henrekson, 1988; Dollery and Worthington, 1995). All these variables are considered as potential influences on fiscal illusion. As previously seen, none of them includes the interest rate. In the present paper, this topic is empirically dealt with.

    In relation to the literature about the linkages between fiscal and monetary policies, it is worth highlighting that most, if not all, of the literature studies the effects of fiscal policy on the interest rates but not the opposite direction of the relationship. The issue regarding the possible influences comes from some papers questioning whether the interest rates are exogenous (Wray, 2006), whether the public expenditure is productive (Aschauer, 1989) and whether it stimulates the economy (Aschauer, 1990). The positive effect of fiscal policy on the economy is a way to confirm that such policy matters (Blinder and Solow, 1973).

    Frenkel and Razin (1984) developed an analytical model in which a budget deficit raises world interest rates, negatively transmitting this deficit to the rest of the world through the world capital market. They distinguished between two different effects of a rise in government spending. If the effect is transitory, it always provokes an increase in interest rates, but if the effect is permanent, it will depend on whether the national economy is a net saver or dissaver with respect to the rest of the world economies. In this case, if there is a surplus in the current account, then there will be a rise of the world rates of interest, while if there is a deficit in the current account of the home economy, it would be associated with a decrease in the interest rates. Authors such as Evans (1985, 1987) and Cebula (1988) empirically checked whether large deficits lead to higher interest rates.

    More recently and regarding the effects of public debt on interest rates, Engen and Hubbard (2004) highlighted that, while these effects have been analyzed for decades, they are still under debate, since there is no consensus on their empirical effects yet. This debate still continues nowadays. As Blanchard (2019) recently suggested, low interest rates—since the economic growth rate is higher than the natural interest rate— are an encouragement to increase debt. Brumm et al. (2022) corrected the previous author's statement that "deficits are free" for ex-ante utility, leading to even more room to obtain Pareto improvements from budget deficits.

    Finally, and specifically focusing on public spending, Choi and Devereux (2006) empirically explored possible asymmetric effects of government spending on economic activity depending on different values of real interest rates, finding that expansionary public spending is more predisposed to short-run growth when the real interest rates of the country are low. Table 1 provides a summary of the studies of the next authors.

    Table 1.  Summary of some literature on the topic.
    Source Econometric approach Main variables used Time span Number of countries Main results Target factor/
    topic
    Mauro (1998) OLS and OLS robust Corruption and GDP per capita 1982–1995 106 Corruption reduces Public Expenditure Politicians
    Delavallade (2006) Three-stage least squares method Corruption, GDP, Total and Urban Population, Dependency Ratio, Young People, Military personnel, social contributions, lack of global freedom 1996–2001 64 Corruption distorts Public Expenditure by reducing the social portion
    Magazzino et al. (2015) Unit root tests, cointegration and GC tests General Government Expenditure, GDP, Investment/GDP 1980–2013 EU An increase in GDP tends to raise the government expenditure/GDP share Wagner's law
    Azolibe et al. (2020) Modified and Fully Modified ordinary least squares (OLS) Population age structure, self–employment, GDP per capita, inflation, control of corruption, foreign aid and unemployment 1989–2018 10 Population age structure influences the growth of public expenditure in Africa, Self–employment, GDP per capita, inflation and control of corruption (–) and foreign aid and unemployment (+) influence Population age structure
    D'Alessandro et al. (2019) Vector Auto-Regressive Federal Funds and Government Expenditures 1953–2007 US Significant reduction in interest rate after a raise in Public Expenditure Interest rates
    Murphy and Walsh (2022) Structural Vector Auto-Regressive Treasury Bill rates and Government Expenditures 1983Q1–2007Q4 US The increased demand for credit associated with government spending is offset by an increase in the supply of credit due to higher aggregate income (p.1)

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    As previously expressed, most studies focus on the effects of public spending on interest rates. Blanchard (2023) highlighted that, when monetary policy is not available for raising output toward its maximum potential since the reference interest rates are so close to the zero bound rate (ZBR), fiscal policy has to intervene by expansionary public policies, so there is a need for raising public expenditures. According to this author (pp. 6–7), the "future path of interest rates is not exogenous and depends very much on fiscal policy itself." Nonetheless, this paper is focused on the opposite direction of the effect.

    An additional topic worth mentioning is the financial sustainability issue, which is key in the recent economic literature and policy debate. The sustainability of public finances must ultimately eliminate government bankruptcy. Brady and Magazzino (2018a) used data from 19 European Monetary Union (EMU) countries for the 1970–2016 period and found that the solvency condition may be considered to be satisfied for these countries. Austerity policies would improve the conditions of the public accounts in the more indebted countries. This would restore the credibility of the institutions of these countries and reduce the spreads. Their results also showed that the co-movement of public debt ratios shows a counter-cyclical response to the common business cycle. Furthermore, they also found an unobserved factor driving such co-movement. Brady and Magazzino (2018b) applied causality tests to the 28 European Union member states for the 1980–2015 period, and they suggested the presence of the fulfillment of the neutrality hypothesis, that "government revenues do not cause the expenditures, and vice versa" (p. 1). Finally, Magazzino et al. (2019) found that G7 countries have to pay attention to the equilibrium between government expenditure and revenues, which they considered as a possible source of fiscal insolvency. They also observed bi-directional causality flows that emerge both between public revenues and expenditures and between government primary deficit and public debt.

    The main aim of this paper is to observe the influence of reference rates on public spending. In the case of the opposite direction, it is remarkable that "most macroeconomic models imply that increases in government spending cause interest rates to rise, but empirical evidence from the U.S. generally fails to support this prediction" (Murphy and Walsh, 2022). These authors found that the positive effect of public spending rates through credit demand is compensated by a rise in credit supply through an increase in income. Other authors, such as D'Alessandro et al. (2019), also found a negative effect.

    The possible effects of monetary policy on fiscal sustainability regarding public expenditure are presented. Two different potential effects with opposite sign are assessed. Finally, a discussion is provided afterwards to determine which sign is more feasible.

    The first effect considers interest rates as the fiscal price of money. The reason for considering the interest rate as a fiscal price is that money can be considered a kind of public good since it generates public positive externalities—its intrinsic price is almost null, but its benefits are very high—and the supervision of money for the whole country would be very costly for the private sector. Nonetheless, a higher interest rate would lead to a lower provision of money, and this would impede the public sector in monetizing its debt, constraining future public spending. Additionally, the public sector will pay higher interest rates for the debt, with direct negative repercussions on the public budget and thus on public expenditure.

    The second effect considers that, knowing that taxes impact in a direction opposite to the price of the good they are levying, as well as taking into account that taxes on financial services such as financial VAT have a negative effect on public expenditure, the expected sign for the effect of interest rates—price of money—would be the opposite, i.e., positive. The reason is that, taking into account the crowding out effect between the public and private sectors, if the price of financial services is raised by the central banks through a raise in the reference interest rates, then the public services would be expected to be cheaper with respect to financial services, raising the demand of public goods and therefore increasing public expenditure. Additionally, if the interest rates of the Treasury bills (T-bills) are higher, then the price of the bonds would decrease, leading to higher demand of public debt. It would then be possible to expand the quantity of debt, leading to possibly higher availability for public expenses.

    Regarding the first couple of opposite effects, it is worth highlighting that, even considering money as a convention or even a public good, the interest rate is always the reference for most of the investments made by the private sector. Therefore, raising it may lead to higher returns to the private sector and higher costs—apart from those of the debt—for the public sector. The reason is that the balance of the public and private sectors regarding the relative price in their trade-off tends toward the private sector, benefiting it, provided that reference interest rates have risen. Regarding the second couple of effects with opposite sign, the mere raise of T-bill rates could be considered as a higher public expense. Thus, it would be necessary to additionally consider not only public expenditure in the broad sense but also without including the financing costs in the expenditure, which is a robustness check that will be provided in the empirical section.

    Therefore, a positive effect of interest rates on public expenditure is expected. In addition to the previous final effect of the variable, the direct and indirect influences and transmission channels are about to be analyzed. First of all, a well-known equation explaining public expenditure (G) is presented:

    GSt=Tt+Mt+Et+rDt (1)

    which can be considered the supply (S) side (Facchini, 2018). The time is t, T is the tax revenue, M is the money creation (inflation tax of Friedman), E is the income from state properties, D is public debt, and r is interest rate. According to this, ceteris paribus, if interest rates rise, then the rest of the public expenditure has to reduce to keep the same amount. This is considered here the negative, direct effect. Additionally, the direct/indirect effects and transmission channels appear on the demand (D) side:

    GDt=A[GSt(r)T(r)]+BI(r) (2)

    where A and B are parameters of negative sign, reflecting, respectively, the reluctance of the government to raise deficits due to the need to increase taxes or the inflation tax for financing it, and the trade-off between private investment (I) and public expenditure. In (2), the isolated direct negative effect of interest rates on G and the two indirect positive ones appear. The effect related to tax revenue comes from the higher tax collection associated with good economic times. This is influenced by the signal of raising reference interest rates and the lower relative prices of services provided by the public sector keeping the same tax rates, ceteris paribus, while the prices of the goods and services obtained from the private sector—shown on the interest rate—are higher, increasing the demand of public services—and so, of G—through fiscal illusion. The other channel is the transmission through the trade-off between investment and public expenditure (Yakita and Yakita, 2017), leading to a crowding out effect. Therefore, a rise in reference rates usually leads to lower investment, and, according to this channel, G would rise.

    The database used in this paper is formed by unbalanced panel data of the 216 countries shown in Table 2 for the 1972–2021 period. The main variables used in the present paper are the target ones, which are the different specifications of interest rates, the explained variables regarding public expenditure and the control variables taken from the literature as the main determinants of fiscal illusion and public spending. The descriptive analysis of those variables is collected in Table 3. The data used are collected in the Harvard Dataverse in order to guarantee reproducibility.

    Table 2.  Data sample.
    216 countries for the 1972–2021 period
    Aruba Bermuda Czech Republic Gambia, The Jordan Monaco Norway Senegal Timor-Leste
    Afghanistan Bolivia Germany Guinea-B. Japan Moldova Nepal Singapore Tonga
    Angola Brazil Djibouti Equatorial Guinea Kazakhstan Madagascar Nauru Solomon Islands Trinidad & Tobago
    Albania Barbados Dominica Greece Kenya Maldives New Zea. Sierra Leone Tunisia
    Andorra Brunei Darussalam Denmark Grenada Kyrgyz Republic Mexico Oman El Salvador Turkiye
    United Arab Emirates Bhutan Dominican Republic Greenland Cambodia Marshall Islands Pakistan San Marino Tuvalu
    Argentina Botswana Algeria Guatemala Kiribati N. Macedonia Panama Somalia Tanzania
    Armenia Canada Ecuador Guam St. Kitts and Nevis Mali Peru Serbia Uganda
    American Samoa Switzerland Egypt, Arab Rep. Guyana Korea, Rep. Malta Philippines South Sudan Ukraine
    Antigua and Barbuda Channel Islands Eritrea Hong Kong SAR, C. Kuwait Myanmar Palau Sao Tome and Principe Uruguay
    Australia Chile Spain Honduras Lao PDR Montenegro Papua New Guinea Suriname United States
    Austria China Estonia Croatia Lebanon Mongolia Poland Slovak Republic Uzbekistan
    Azerbaijan Cote d'Ivoire Ethiopia Haiti Liberia Northern Mariana Islands Puerto Rico Slovenia St. Vincent & the Grenadines
    Burundi Cameroon Finland Hungary Libya Mozambique Korea, Dem. People's Rep. Sweden Venezuela, RB
    Belgium Congo, Dem. Rep. Fiji Indonesia St. Lucia Mauritania Portugal Eswatini British Virgin Islands
    Benin Congo, Rep. France Isle of Man Liechtenstein Mauritius Paraguay Sint Maarten (Dutch part) Virgin Islands (U.S.)
    Burkina Faso Colombia Faroe Islands India Sri Lanka Malawi West Bank and Gaza Seychelles Vietnam
    Bangladesh Comoros Micronesia, Fed. Sts. Ireland Lesotho Malaysia French Polynesia Syrian Arab Republic Vanuatu
    Bulgaria Cabo Verde Gabon Iran, Islamic Rep. Lithuania Namibia Qatar Turks and Caicos Islands Samoa
    Bahrain Costa Rica United Kingdom Iraq Luxembourg New Caledonia Romania Chad Kosovo
    Bahamas, The Cuba Georgia Iceland Latvia Niger Russian Federation Togo Yemen, Rep.
    Bosnia and H. Curacao Ghana Israel Macao SAR, C. Nigeria Rwanda Thailand South Africa
    Belarus Cayman Islands Gibraltar Italy St. Martin (French part) Nicaragua Saudi Arabia Tajikistan Zambia
    Belize Cyprus Guinea Jamaica Morocco Netherlands Sudan Turkmenistan Zimbabwe
    Note: C. – China, N. – North, H. – Herzegovina, B. – Bissau, Zea. – Zealand.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 3.  Descriptive analysis of the variables used in the estimation.
    Variable Name (unit) and Short Description Obs. Mean Std. dev. Min Max Skewness Kurtosis
    Pepcgr (%): growth rate of Public spending pc 3,777 18.45526 155.9466 −58.03723 8774.37 48.28702 2647.87
    gspepcgr (%): as pepcgr but without financing costs 3,737 15.70413 71.6467 −78.78874 2356.45 19.95582 519.712
    gkf (% of GDP): gross capital formation 8,093 23.30144 8.857052 −13.4053 89.3811 0.935966 6.02619
    pressure (% of GDP): tax revenue 4,124 17.08778 7.802476 0.000078 147.6613 3.151591 42.66256
    openness (% of GDP): trade (exports plus imports) 8,425 78.43731 54.45225 0.020999 863.1951 2.935124 20.2202
    density (people per km2): population density 10,632 334.6091 1599.583 0.098625 21388.6 9.048465 92.01418
    gdppcgr (%): growth rate of GDP pc 9,739 1.933724 6.125898 −64.99237 140.367 1.678479 51.9209
    polstab (index): political stability 4,592 −0.014807 0.994145 −3.312951 1.965062 −0.595467 2.782004
    eps (%): pure interest rate (2*lr*dr/(lr+dr)) 3,953 40.21565 1799.814 −0.994776 113115.5 62.75774 3943.24
    tbr (%): Treasury bill rate (lr−risk premium) 2,319 8.806777 9.474351 −0.541158 124.025 4.20468 32.24998
    lr (%): lending interest rate 4,473 39.40397 1493.189 0.5 99764.53 66.62715 4449.955
    dr (%): deposit interest rate 4,599 44.75213 1935.35 −0.41853 130592 66.79412 4503.728
    mid (%): mid-price of interest rates ((lr+dr)/2) 3,953 42.72524 1832.786 0.657333 115178.3 62.73961 3941.696
    eca(0−1): Europe & Central Asia m. (ECA) 10,800 0.268519 0.443205 0 1 1.044618 2.091227
    Note: pc – per capita; m. – member; obs. – observations; std. dev.: standard deviation.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The empirical strategy first applies fixed effects panel data models and then it follows the GMM econometric techniques for dynamic panel data models with robust variance estimators developed by Arellano and Bond (1991), Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). Specifically, the system GMM methods are estimated, following the analytical formulation

    yit=γyit1+TitβT+Xitβ+εit (3)

    where yit is the variable that represents the per capita public expenditure —either total or only for goods and services— growth rate for country i and year t, yit-1 is the first delay of the explained variable, and γ is its coefficient. Tit is the regression matrix of interest variables—different expressions and specifications of interest rates. Xit is the regression matrix of control variables, βT and β are the vectors of coefficients for the, respectively, interest and control variables, and εit is the perturbation. The software used was Stata 17.

    The variables employed in the estimations are collected in Table 3. The dependent variables are pepcgr and gspepcgr, where the former variable reflects the per capita public expenditure of a country, with public expenses understood as the cash flows from the public sector for operational activities and for the provision of goods and services, including the compensation of employees, interests and subsidies, donations, social benefits and other public spending such as income and dividends. The gspepcgr variable is similar to the previous one but only reflecting the payments of money due to the provision of public goods and services, so excluding financing costs. The control variables include the two previous variables, which have been multiplied by 100 from the growth rate of the original source—expense, current Local Currency Unit (LCU)—divided by the population1 and the gkf variable, which is the gross capital formation divided by the GDP. Yakita (2008) and Yakita and Yakita (2017) expected a negative sign of the coefficient associated with this variable. Trade openness is given by openness, a variable derived from the percentage of the sum of exports and imports over GDP. The density variable is the population divided by the area of the country (km2). The pressure variable measures the tax collection of a country divided by the GDP, and the gdppc variable measures the growth rate of the GDP per capita. Finally, the political stability is addressed by the polstab variable, as an index with −2.5 as the lowest political stability and 2.5 as the highest. As suggested by Mauro (1998) and others, a positive sign can be expected. All these variables have been taken from the World Development Indicators2.

    1The total population variable is also from the World Bank Indicators database. It is worth mentioning that the access was in July 2022, since the data are different for 2023. The complete databases used in this paper and its code appear in The author, 2023, "Replication Data for: Interest Rates affect Public Expenditure Growth", https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/I4XLBM, Harvard Dataverse, V1.

    2https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators.

    Regarding the interest variables, the eps variable includes the explicit specification of "pure" interest rate—i.e., the interest rate without fees or risk—proposed by López-Laborda and Peña (2018) and used in algorithmic trading by Peña (2020). It constitutes twice the product of lending and deposit interest rates divided by the sum of both of them. The tbr variable includes the interest rate of the short-term Treasury bill rates, the lr variable is the lending interest rate, the dr variable represents the deposit interest rates, and the mid variable reflects the mid-price, expressed as the arithmetic average of lr and dr. Before performing the causality test, an analysis of outliers and of the data sample, as well as a diagnostic test, will be conducted. Figure 1 shows the analysis of outliers for the dependent and control variables, showing outliers around 1990, especially Peru (PER) and Nicaragua (NIC). Each point has the label of the country according to the World Bank codes. Figure 2 shows the analysis of the averages of the target and dependent variables by country for each year, also reflecting the peak around 1990. Finally, Figure 3 reflects the averages of the same variables by year for each geographical region—East Asia & Pacific (EPA), ECA, Latin America (LATAM), Middle East and North Africa (MENA), South Asia (SA), North America (NA), Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA)—and for upper income (UI), lower income (LI) and upper/lower middle income (UMI/LMI) countries.

    Figure 1.  Analysis of outliers.
    Figure 2.  Time series analysis of the country averages of the target and dependent variables.
    Figure 3.  Cross-country section analysis of the time averages of the target and dependent variables.

    The correlation matrix appears in Table 4, in order to analyze multicollinearity. It is observed that there is not any variable with a correlation higher than 0.4, which indicates no multicollinearity.

    Table 4.  Correlation matrix.
    gkf pressure openness density gdppcgr polstab eps eca
    gkf 1
    pressure 0.1059 1
    openness 0.1115 0.1625 1
    density −0.085 0.1045 0.3177 1
    gdppcgr 0.2059 −0.0149 0.0385 −0.0161 1
    polstab 0.1303 0.2791 0.3408 0.177 −0.0493 1
    eps −0.0396 −0.1236 −0.2014 −0.1556 −0.0051 −0.2003 1
    eca −0.0039 0.0631 0.1245 −0.1013 0.1017 0.0699 0.015 1

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Finally, before the results section, the degrees of causality of the target variables on the dependent variables is assessed using Granger causality techniques. Previous authors have done this regarding the issue of the causality between interest rates and economic growth (Lee and Werner, 2018), but in this case (Psaradakis et al., 2005), it is with respect to public expenditure. It is performed by applying a recent novel technique of Granger causality for panel data that solves the so-called "Neville bias." It was proposed by Juodis et al. (2021) and developed for software in the paper of Xiao et al. (2023). The main requirement of this test regarding the present paper's data is the compulsory use of a balanced panel. As the panel handled in this paper is unbalanced, a balanced sub-sample has been employed ad hoc. Therefore, the highest number of observations has been sought while being aware of preserving the needed balanced properties of the data. A balanced sub-sample of 14 developed and developing countries and territories has been used for the period from 2004 to 2019, and it can be seen in Table 5. To the author's knowledge, this paper uses one of the largest balanced panel sets available, with updated data compared to the rest of the literature.

    Table 5.  Data sub-sample for the panel data Granger causality test.
    14 countries and territories for the 2004–2019 period (224 observations per variable)
    Armenia Bahamas, The Hungary Lebanon Sri Lanka Lesotho Moldova
    Mauritius Namibia Philippines Thailand Uruguay South Africa Zambia

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Once the panel set is chosen, the next decision is what variables are taken for the panel data Granger causality test. The results are shown in Table 6.

    Table 6.  Granger causality tests.
    Null hypothesis: The variable on the left does not GC the one on the right.
    Variables p-value Variable p-value Variables p-value Variable p-value
    eps pepc 0.293 pepc eps 0.375 eps pepcgr 0.293 pepcgr eps 0.844
    tbr pepc 0.66 pepc tbr 0.621 tbr pepcgr 0.779 pepcgr tbr 0.701
    lr pepc 0.087 pepc lr 0.704 lr pepcgr 0.127 pepcgr lr 0.35
    dr pepc 0.454 pepc dr 0.263 dr pepcgr 0.48 pepcgr dr 0.953
    mid pepc 0.187 pepc mid 0.503 mid pepcgr 0.204 pepcgr mid 0.517
    eps gspepc 0.77 gspepc eps 0.039 eps gspepcgr 0.158 gspepcgr eps 0.939
    tbr gspepc 0.904 gspepc tbr 0.041 tbr gspepcgr 0.71 gspepcgr tbr 0.102
    lr gspepc 0.267 gspepc lr 0.019 lr gspepcgr 0.062 gspepcgr lr 0.556
    dr gspepc 0.526 gspepc dr 0.122 dr gspepcgr 0.109 gspepcgr dr 0.65
    mid gspepc 0.675 gspepc mid 0.034 mid gspepcgr 0.077 gspepcgr mid 0.758
    Note: p-values lower than 0.1 are in italic bold.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The basic variables are the two dependent and the target ones, but two additional variables are also used. Nonetheless, the variables in levels are also used to check the most used ones in other papers. They will be indicated by deleting the "gr" that denotes the growth rate in each of them. Therefore, as the paper considers 4 dependent variables and 5 independent ones, 40 ( = 4×5×2) tests will be conducted. The result is multiplied by two since the causality can take two possible directions. The Granger causality test for panel data assesses whether one variable does not Granger cause (GC) another as the null hypothesis, with Granger causality as the alternative hypothesis. A unique significant direction shows in the results that interest rates GC per capita public expenditure growth, so the next analysis will be performed only with growth variables.

    Tables 7 and 8 show the results of this paper. Table 7 collects the fixed-effects models (1–10a), where the dependent variable is pepcgr for the odd models and gspepcgr for the even models. On the other hand, Table 8 shows the system GMM models for the pepcgr and gspepcgr variables, respectively. For the control variables, most models show positive and statistically significant effects of the gdppcgr variable, according to Magazzino et al. (2015). With respect to the coefficient of the lagged dependent variables, when it is statistically significant in the dynamic models, the sign is negative. This is relevant for the further interpretation of the results. The effect of the target or interest variables is the same in all cases: a positive, statistically significant relationship between the different specifications of interest rate variables and public expenditure growth for the different methods and models.

    Table 7.  Results from the fixed effects models.
    (1)a (2)a (3)a (4)a (5)a (6)a (7)a (8)a (9)a (10)a
    VARIABLES pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr
    gkf 0.173 0.246 0.202* −0.0753 0.495 0.196 0.245 0.124 0.282 0.250
    (0.448) (0.639) (0.112) (0.183) (0.386) (0.640) (0.491) (0.482) (0.423) (0.642)
    pressure 1.526 1.530 0.343** 0.604** 1.272 1.555 1.499 1.418 1.499 1.539
    (1.324) (1.418) (0.131) (0.234) (1.007) (1.232) (1.259) (1.252) (1.289) (1.407)
    openness 0.293** 0.350* 0.0258 0.152*** 0.255** 0.289 0.255** 0.263* 0.270** 0.312
    (0.123) (0.203) (0.0225) (0.0472) (0.117) (0.177) (0.109) (0.158) (0.125) (0.192)
    density 0.00313 0.00113 −0.000100 −0.000562 0.000757 −0.00276 0.00472 0.000351 0.00188 −0.000306
    (0.00375) (0.00293) (0.000688) (0.00148) (0.00319) (0.00333) (0.00351) (0.00215) (0.00342) (0.00265)
    gdppcgr −0.501 −1.058 0.413*** 0.881*** −0.987 −1.946 0.0704 −0.789 −0.682 −1.186
    (1.259) (1.292) (0.146) (0.288) (1.092) (1.516) (1.200) (1.169) (1.214) (1.394)
    eps 2.691*** 2.077**
    (0.0204) (0.956)
    tbr 0.867*** 1.091**
    (0.154) (0.416)
    lendrate 2.005*** 1.293**
    (0.00937) (0.581)
    deprate 3.260*** 1.709**
    (0.0795) (0.714)
    midprice 2.515*** 1.605**
    (0.0161) (0.748)
    Constant −70.56** −67.69 −11.68*** −24.86*** −70.32** −55.09 −70.94*** −47.82 −71.94** −61.12
    (29.07) (49.62) (3.725) (9.180) (27.07) (44.63) (25.36) (38.60) (29.19) (47.60)
    Observations 1,691 1,665 1,008 985 1,926 1,890 1,925 1,900 1,691 1,665
    R−squared 0.920 0.101 0.265 0.117 0.924 0.107 0.891 0.084 0.922 0.090
    Number of countries 96 95 57 56 102 101 106 105 96 95
    Note: *, **, *** indicate p-values, respectively, lower than 0.1, 0.05 and 0.01. Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 8.  Results from the system GMM models for the pepcgr and gspepcgr variables (var).
    (1)b (2)b (3)b (4)b (5)b (6)b (7)b (8)b (9)b (10)b
    VARIABLES pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr
    Dependent var t−1 −0.028*** 0.145 −0.0429 −0.155** −0.111*** 0.0869 −0.00139 0.143 −0.0687*** 0.144
    (0.00760) (0.127) (0.102) (0.0700) (0.0114) (0.0692) (0.0273) (0.132) (0.00941) (0.126)
    gkf −2.740 −0.791** −0.0640 −0.771*** −1.658 −0.809*** −2.777 −0.493 −2.495 −0.807**
    (1.970) (0.373) (0.132) (0.296) (1.145) (0.310) (2.643) (0.338) (1.692) (0.359)
    Pressure 0.943 0.275 0.465* 0.697 0.937* 0.445 0.852 0.220 0.929* 0.265
    (0.653) (0.705) (0.238) (0.474) (0.531) (0.658) (1.331) (0.648) (0.564) (0.705)
    openness 0.401 0.385* −0.0224 0.127** 0.235 0.261 0.470 0.355* 0.373 0.375*
    (0.330) (0.226) (0.0375) (0.0648) (0.208) (0.214) (0.437) (0.201) (0.298) (0.220)
    density 0.000217 −0.0235 0.00179 −0.00365 −0.00617 −0.0212 0.00770 −0.0201 −0.00202 −0.0234
    (0.00884) (0.0169) (0.00266) (0.00515) (0.0110) (0.0162) (0.0139) (0.0145) (0.00877) (0.0168)
    gdppcgr 0.884 −0.318 0.362** 1.203*** −0.204 −2.063 1.480 −0.353 0.475 −0.315
    (1.988) (0.737) (0.172) (0.428) (1.650) (1.950) (2.102) (0.622) (1.855) (0.729)
    eps 2.767*** 1.225***
    (0.0117) (0.372)
    tbr 1.124*** 1.549***
    (0.235) (0.505)
    lr 2.096*** 1.608***
    (0.0352) (0.432)
    dr 3.422*** 1.163***
    (0.123) (0.362)
    mid 2.609*** 1.205***
    (0.0108) (0.240)
    Observations 1,615 1,589 969 949 1,845 1,810 1,831 1,804 1,615 1,589
    Number of Countries 95 94 57 56 101 100 104 103 95 94
    Sargan p−value 0.904 0.892 0.9995 0.9998 0.682 0.833 0.799 0.767 0.924 0.887
    A−B p−value 0.912 0.973 0.3299 0.967 0.584 0.620 0.344 0.761 0.398 0.950
    Note: *, **, *** indicate p-values, respectively, lower than 0.1, 0.05 and 0.01. WC-Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The Windmeijer bias-corrected (WC)-robust estimators of Windmeijer (2005) were applied. Some tests were performed in order to check the econometrical correctness of the applied methodologies and estimated results. Specifically, the Sargan test checks the validity of the instruments—null hypothesis—and is used in the dynamic models before applying variance-covariance matrix of the estimators (VCE) robustness. The result obtained shows that the instruments are valid with acceptable p-values in most models. In addition, the Arellano and Bond (AB) test of 2nd order was performed, checking the serial autocorrelation of the residuals of order 2 (null hypothesis). The rejection of this hypothesis indicates that the residuals are Autoregressive (AR) of second order (AR2). As there was a p-value higher than 0.1 in all models, they are considered to have good econometric properties.

    The results follow Yakita (2008) and Yakita and Yakita (2017), as well as Magazzino et al. (2015), since, respectively, the trade-off of investment and public expenditure and Wagner's law are confirmed in most cases of Table 8 due to the negative and positive significant signs of the coefficients of the gkf and gdppcgr variables, respectively. Additionally, other demand factors such as the gdppcgr variable include the positive and significant sign of the coefficients of the pressure and openness variables. Regarding the target variables, the usual positive association with public expenditure of traditional macroeconomic models (Murphy and Walsh, 2022) is found, in contrast to the negative effect obtained by authors such as Murphy and Walsh (2022) and D'Alessandro et al. (2019). Concerning the economic interpretation of the results, as the target variables of monetary policy measured by interest rates have a positive and statistically significant effect on the public expenditure, the coefficient of the lag of the dependent variable is in most cases negative and significant—which indicates a decrease of the variable over time. It is known that reference interest rates have also decreased over time in most countries, and the positive sign of the relationship is confirmed. Additionally, the end of Section 3 shows that, in some cases, the hypothesis that interest rates do not Granger cause (GC) per capita public expenditure growth is rejected, but it cannot be rejected in the opposite direction of causality.

    All this means that a decrease in the interest rates leads to a reduction in public expenses, as previously expected in Section 3. Thus, the results can be interpreted as follows: Lower financial costs for the public sector, caused by lower payments of public debt, due in turn to lower reference interest rates, lead to lower public expenses, as the effect on the pepcgr variable reflects. However, they also lead to a lower provision of public goods and services as a global effect—i.e., without direct and indirect effects. This is shown by the influence on the gspepcgr variable, so it is not the only factor. Decreasing the interest rates can be considered a reduction in the private prices that encourages demand in the private sector or market of goods and services, raising private consumption. Meanwhile, the relative prices in the public sector are considered to be higher with respect to the private sector, reducing the public demand of goods and services and thus also reducing public consumption.

    Therefore, this paper questions the traditional view of considering that public expenditure may affect interest rates by showing that, when public expenditure is expressed as the growth rate of public expenditure per capita, in goods and services, monetary policy in some cases also leads to an impact on fiscal policy.

    This section starts checking the Granger causality of Section 4 by using the pairwise Granger causality country by country, showing the results for gspepcgr and eps in Table 9, and achieving similar results for other specifications. The results show a lower p-value for rejecting that the eps variable does not GC gspepcgr than the opposite direction (37% vs. 36% of the countries). Furthermore, the percentage of countries where there is univocal Granger causality rather than circular Granger causality is 52.9% vs. 19.5%. Later, Table 10 will show the robustness of the dynamic panel data system GMM and static fixed effect models by including demand factors such as political stability (Facchini, 2018) and the proposed transmission channel. The results of the previous section have also been replicated, adding this variable with similar results for the target variables3. Furthermore, a geographic factor is considered by including the World Bank's regional classification of Europe and Central Asia (eca variable). The results show that, even considering circular causation or causality in an opposite direction to the one studied here, the highest number of rejections to the null hypothesis that a variable does not GC another corresponds to the influence of eps on gspepcgr. Additional results appear in Table 10, showing the transmission channel and a robustness check using the eca variable of countries of Europe and Central Asia and the polstab variables. The results show a robust and positive influence of the two transmission channels through fiscal illusion by the positive impact of the interaction of pressure and rates on the dependent variables and via investment trade-off by the interaction of investment and rates on public expenditure. Moreover, the isolated direct effect of rates when the transmission channels are considered is negative.

    Table 9.  Robustness check of the Granger causality.
    Country eps does not GC gspepcgr? gspepcgr does not GC eps? Country eps does not GC gspepcgr? gspepcgr does not GC eps? Country eps does not GC gspepcgr? gspepcgr does not GC eps?
    Angola 0.008 0 Fiji 0.128 0.69 Namibia 0.926 0.925
    Albania 0 0.102 Micronesia, Fed. Sts. 0.276 0.866 Nicaragua 0.688 0.913
    Armenia 0.12 0.835 United Kingdom 0.371 0.809 Netherlands 0.338 0.001
    Australia 0.778 0.301 Georgia 0.08 0.081 Norway 0 0
    Azerbaijan 0.132 0.5 Guatemala 0.475 0.164 New Zealand 0.195 0.973
    Burkina Faso 0.865 0.782 Honduras 0.12 0.573 Peru 0.007 0.03
    Bangladesh 0.718 0.06 Croatia 0.806 0 Philippines 0.628 0.083
    Bulgaria 0.686 0.002 Hungary 0.011 0 Papua New Guinea 0 0.688
    Bahrain 0.637 0.492 Indonesia 0.018 0.093 Paraguay 0.003 0
    Bahamas, The 0.007 0.267 Israel 0.113 0.002 West Bank and Gaza 0.788 0.42
    Bosnia and Herzegovina 0.321 0.103 Jordan 0.479 0.119 Romania 0.227 0.541
    Belarus 0.161 0 Japan 0.567 0.155 Russian Federation 0.177 0.762
    Belize 0.595 0.371 St. Kitts and Nevis 0.884 0.513 Singapore 0.005 0.176
    Bolivia 0.003 0.023 Korea, Rep. 0.337 0.624 Solomon Islands 0.867 0.303
    Brazil 0.101 0.051 Kuwait 0.047 0.896 San Marino 0.001 0.164
    Barbados 0.084 0.047 Lebanon 0.659 0.186 Sweden 0.424 0.042
    Bhutan 0.342 0.408 St. Lucia 0.002 0.018 Seychelles 0.669 0.049
    Botswana 0.042 0.435 Sri Lanka 0.855 0.105 Togo 0.088 0.158
    Canada 0.609 0.506 Lesotho 0.025 0.627 Thailand 0.628 0.186
    Switzerland 0.652 0.308 Macao SAR, China 0.216 0.197 Timor-Leste 0.243 0.324
    Chile 0.003 0.021 Moldova 0.35 0.614 T. & Tobago 0.365 0
    Cote d'Ivoire 0.811 0.054 Madagascar 0.024 0.199 Tanzania 0.001 0
    Colombia 0.185 0.3 Maldives 0 0.419 Ukraine 0.607 0.662
    Cabo Verde 0.009 0.01 Mexico 0 0.878 Uruguay 0 0.289
    Costa Rica 0.113 0.626 North Macedonia 0 0.001 St. V. & the Grenadines 0.462 0.872
    Czech Republic 0.131 0.118 Mali 0.444 0.241 Vanuatu 0.013 0.064
    Dominican Republic 0.029 0.363 Mongolia 0.454 0.054 Samoa 0.007 0
    Egypt, Arab Rep. 0.421 0.006 Mauritius 0.347 0.183 South Africa 0.36 0.765
    Ethiopia 0.9 0.614 Malaysia 0.002 0.012 Zambia 0 0.701
    Average 0.30195402 0.31166667

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 10.  Robustness check of the panel data estimations.
    (1)c (2)c (3)c (4)c (5)c (6)c (7)c (8)c (9)c (10)c
    VARIABLES pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr pepcgr gspepcgr
    Dependent var t−1 −0.0285 −0.112** −0.0539 −0.124** −0.0607 −0.123** −0.061 −0.116**
    (0.0644) (0.0559) (0.0736) (0.0573) (0.0696) (0.0543) (0.073) (0.0576)
    gkf −0.922** −0.940* −0.247 −0.189 −0.730 −0.728 −0.844** −0.718 −0.608* −0.753**
    (0.438) (0.512) (0.260) (0.361) (0.451) (0.581) (0.419) (0.588) (0.341) (0.336)
    pressure 1.002 0.672 −0.0217 0.0970 0.393 0.416 0.293 0.340 −0.190 −0.296
    (0.703) (0.589) (0.389) (0.512) (0.562) (0.579) (0.520) (0.612) (0.249) (0.315)
    openness 0.170 0.256* 0.172 0.231* 0.194 0.255* 0.191* 0.228 0.0879 0.200***
    (0.124) (0.134) (0.120) (0.135) (0.121) (0.140) (0.124) (0.139) (0.0535) (0.0760)
    density −0.00752 −0.0109 −0.00772 −0.0203 −0.00746 −0.0137 −0.007 −0.00978 0.000737 0.00394
    (0.00549) (0.0171) (0.00780) (0.0232) (0.00649) (0.0174) (0.007) (0.0131) (0.00248) (0.00272)
    gdppcgr −0.147 −0.0696 −0.0455 0.0702 −0.163 −0.0527 −0.148 −0.0328 0.0721 0.590**
    (0.169) (0.202) (0.158) (0.199) (0.153) (0.191) (0.152) (0.184) (0.173) (0.232)
    polstab −1.204 −4.593 −3.120 −4.424 −1.721 −5.726 −2.144 −5.989 −0.938 −2.740
    (3.912) (5.092) (4.518) (5.799) (4.457) (5.372) (4.633) (6.085) (1.863) (2.376)
    eps −0.451 −1.346 −1.635** −1.701 −2.845*** −2.696** −3.379** −2.758* −4.334** −4.798**
    (0.998) (0.900) (0.811) (1.217) (1.033) (1.355) (1.499) (1.505) (1.974) (2.219)
    eps*gkf 0.0847** 0.111*** 0.0743* 0.0854* 0.0908** 0.0867* 0.0878*** 0.0932***
    (0.0371) (0.0350) (0.0413) (0.0476) (0.0379) (0.0504) (0.0317) (0.0295)
    eps*pressure 0.212*** 0.182** 0.178** 0.125 0.187** 0.142* 0.229** 0.254**
    (0.0677) (0.0760) (0.0759) (0.0780) (0.0909) (0.0809) (0.103) (0.125)
    eca 6.161 −9.925
    (12.31) (16.61)
    constant −1.892 8.741 0.218
    (14.11) (9.201) (10.13)
    Observations 1,259 1,246 1,259 1,246 1,259 1,246 1,259 1,246 1,312 1,296
    R−squared 0.366 0.221
    Number of Countries 94 93 94 93 94 93 94 93 95 94
    Sargan p−value 0.037 0.366 0.0315 0.266 0.05 0.307 0.147 0.249
    A−B p−value 0.263 0.944 0.358 0.701 0.453 0.809 0.503 0.883
    Note: *, **, *** indicate p-values, respectively, lower than 0.1, 0.05 and 0.01. Robust and WC-Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    3These particular results are not reported in the paper, but they are available from the author upon request.

    The results show a robust and statistically significant positive influence of interest rates on public expenses, not only due to the lower or higher need to pay the debt but also due to the need to pay public goods and services, reflecting a negative effect on public demand probably explained by the fiscal illusion or by the relative prices between the public and private sector. These results provide a new scope for further research and policy implications due to the effective impact of monetary policy on fiscal policy.

    The results additionally confirm the expectances of Yakita (2008) and Yakita and Yakita (2017) for the negative relationship between public and private investment, the findings by Sáenz et al. (2013) regarding the positive correlation with trade openness and the positive relation with GDP per capita by Magazzino et al. (2015). To sum up, with these robustness checks, the main result of the positive influence of interest rates on per capita public expenditure growth—even without considering financing costs of debt—is found. They also confirm the three hypotheses stated in the theoretical section concerning the demand of public spending: The direct negative effect of interest rates on the dependent variable is corroborated when the transmission channels are considered, and the positive influences of these two channels—via both fiscal illusion and crowding out—are also confirmed.

    This paper broadens the focus on fiscal-monetary policies by considering the influence of monetary policy on public expenditure, instead of considering the effects of fiscal policy on the neutral interest rates, as most authors in the literature do. This is the main novelty of the present paper. Thus, panel data of 216 countries for the 1972–2021 period was employed by using the fixed effects and system GMM models to check the effects of different specifications of interest rates on the public expenditure in general and for goods and services in particular. A balanced sub-sample of 14 countries for the 2004–2019 period was employed to check Granger causality using a novel technique recently developed: Granger causality for panel data. The null hypothesis on whether interest rates do not Granger cause (GC) per capita public expenditure is in some cases rejected only in this direction, specifically when the dependent variable is expressed in growth rates and in terms of the spending on goods and services.

    A main conclusion of this paper, in light of the theoretical and empirical exercises, is the existence of a positive influence of interest rates on public expenditure through, at least, two transmission channels: The first is fiscal illusion by increased demand of public services and then tax revenue. The second is the trade-off between public and private investment, where investment decreases with an increase in interest rates, but public expenditure increases by the crowding out effect. Once these mechanisms are considered, the direct influence of interest rates on public spending, by itself, is negative since the highest financing costs lead the government to reduce other expenditures, ceteris paribus. Overall, the first indirect positive effects predominate over the direct negative one. Some policy implications are derived from the results. For instance, in the current context of high indebtedness and an environment of rising interest rates, the transmission channel may be reduced or avoided. This could be done by improving the efficiency of the private sector to be more competitive or raising tax rates by the public sector to offset the reduction of the relative prices of the public and private sectors via fiscal illusion. The proposed policy measures of this paper can be useful for society in general and for policy and law makers in particular. Further research would take into account additional time series analysis, applying artificial intelligence, bootstrapping or machine learning techniques to study cointegration and Granger causality of the variables, according to the Toda-Yamamoto methodology.

    The author declares he has not used artificial intelligence (AI) tools for the creation of this article.

    The author acknowledges the useful comments and suggestions of four anonymous referees of the journal and expresses his gratitude for the funding received in the project entitled "Municipios y servicios financieros: shocks, ratios y efectos, " by the Fundación Ibercaja / Universidad de Zaragoza (JIUZ2022-CSJ-19); the "S23_20R: Public Economics" and "S39_23R: ADETRE" research groups, by the Government of Aragon; and the research project "CISHO, " PID2020-112773GB-I00, by the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, Rev Econ Stud 58: 277–297. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968 doi: 10.2307/2297968
    [2] Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J Econometrics 68: 29–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
    [3] Aschauer DA (1989) Is public expenditure productive? J Monetary Econ 23: 177–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(89)90047-0 doi: 10.1016/0304-3932(89)90047-0
    [4] Aschauer DA (1990) Is government spending stimulative? Contemp Econ Policy 8: 30–46. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7287.1990.tb00300.x doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7287.1990.tb00300.x
    [5] Azolibe CB, Nwadibe CE, et al. (2020) Socio-economic determinants of public expenditure in Africa: assessing the influence of population age structure. Int J Social Econ 47: 1403–1418. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSE-04-2020-0202 doi: 10.1108/IJSE-04-2020-0202
    [6] Beck JH (1984) Non-monotonic Demand for Municipal Services: Variation Among Communities, National Tax J 37: 55–68. https://doi.org/10.1086/NTJ41791933 doi: 10.1086/NTJ41791933
    [7] Blanchard O (2019) Public debt and low interest rates. Am Econ Rev 109: 1197–1229. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.109.4.1197 doi: 10.1257/aer.109.4.1197
    [8] Blanchard O (2023) Fiscal policy under low interest rates. MIT press. https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/14858.001.0001
    [9] Blinder AS, Solow RM (1973) Does fiscal policy matter? J Public Econ 2: 319–337. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(73)90023-6 doi: 10.1016/0047-2727(73)90023-6
    [10] Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econometrics 87: 115–143. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8 doi: 10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
    [11] Brady GL, Magazzino C (2018a) Sustainability and comovement of government debt in EMU Countries: A panel data analysis. Southern Econ J 85: 189–202. https://doi.org/10.1002/soej.12269 doi: 10.1002/soej.12269
    [12] Brady GL, Magazzino C (2018b) Fiscal Sustainability in the EU. Atlantic Econ J 46: 297–311. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-018-9588-4 doi: 10.1007/s11293-018-9588-4
    [13] Brazer HE, McCarty TA (1987) Interaction Between Demand for Education and for Municipal Services. Natl Tax J 40: 555–566. https://doi.org/10.1086/NTJ41788695 doi: 10.1086/NTJ41788695
    [14] Brennan G, Buchanan JM (1980) The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge University Press.
    [15] Brumm J, Feng X, Kotlikoff LJ, et al. (2022) When interest rates go low, should public debt go high? (No. w28951) Natl Bureau Econ Res. https://doi.org/10.3386/w28951
    [16] Buchanan J (1967) Public Finance in democratic process: fiscal institutions and individual choice, The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill.
    [17] Cebula RJ (1988) Federal government budget deficits and interest rates: a brief note. South Econ J, 206–210. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1058869
    [18] Choi WG, Devereux MB (2006) Asymmetric effects of government spending: does the level of real interest rates matter? IMF Staff Pap 53: 147–182. https://doi.org/10.2307/30036027 doi: 10.2307/30036027
    [19] Clotfelter CT (1976) Public expenditure for Higher Education: An Empirical Test of Two Hypotheses. Public Financ 31: 177–195. https://ideas.repec.org/a/pfi/pubfin/v31y1976i2p177-95.html
    [20] D'Alessandro A, Fella G, Melosi L (2019) Fiscal stimulus with learning-by-doing. Int Econ Rev 60: 1413–1432. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12391 doi: 10.1111/iere.12391
    [21] Delavallade C (2006) Corruption and distribution of public spending in developing countries. J Econ Financ 30: 222–239. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02761488 doi: 10.1007/BF02761488
    [22] Dell'Anno R, Dollery BE (2014) Comparative fiscal illusion: A fiscal illusion index for the European Union. Empir Econ 46: 937–960. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0701-x doi: 10.1007/s00181-013-0701-x
    [23] Dell'Anno R, Mourao P (2012) Fiscal Illusion around the World: An Analysis Using the Structural Equation Approach. Public Financ Rev 40: 270–299. https://doi.org/10.1177/1091142111425226 doi: 10.1177/1091142111425226
    [24] Di Lorenzo TJ (1982a) Utility Profits, Fiscal Illusion and Local Public Expenditures. Public Choice 38: 243–252. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00144850 doi: 10.1007/BF00144850
    [25] Di Lorenzo TJ (1982b) Tax Elasticity and the Growth of Local Public Expenditure. Public Financ Q 10: 385–392. https://doi.org/10.1177/109114218201000306 doi: 10.1177/109114218201000306
    [26] Dollery BE, Worthington AC (1995) State expenditure and fiscal illusion in Australia: a test of the revenue complexity, revenue elasticity and flypaper hypotheses, Econ Anal Policy 25: 125–140. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0313-5926(95)50021-9 doi: 10.1016/S0313-5926(95)50021-9
    [27] Dollery BE, Worthington AC (1996) The empirical analysis of fiscal illusion. J Econ Surv 10: 261–297. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.1996.tb00014.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6419.1996.tb00014.x
    [28] Engen EM, Hubbard RG (2004) Federal government debt and interest rates. NBER Macroecon Annu 19: 83–138. https://doi.org/10.1086/ma.19.3585331 doi: 10.1086/ma.19.3585331
    [29] Evans P (1985) Do large deficits produce high interest rates? Am Econ Rev 75: 68–87. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812704
    [30] Evans P (1987) Interest rates and expected future budget deficits in the United States. J Polit Econ 95: 34–58. https://doi.org/10.1086/261440 doi: 10.1086/261440
    [31] Facchini F (2018) What are the determinants of public spending? An overview of the literature. Atlant Econ J 46: 419–439. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-018-9603-9 doi: 10.1007/s11293-018-9603-9
    [32] Frenkel JA, Razin A (1984) Budget deficits and rates of interest in the world economy (No. w1354). Natl Bureau Econ Res. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1354
    [33] Heinemann F (2001) After the death of inflation: will fiscal drag survive? Fiscal Stud 22: 527–546. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-5890.2001.tb00051.x doi: 10.1111/j.1475-5890.2001.tb00051.x
    [34] Henrekson M (1988) Swedish Government Growth: A Disequilibrium Analysis, In: J. Lybeck and M. Henrekson (ed.), Explaining the Growth of Government, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
    [35] Heyndels B, Smolders C (1994) Fiscal Illusion at the Local Level: Empirical Evidence for the Flemish Municipalities. Public Choice 80: 325–338. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01053224 doi: 10.1007/BF01053224
    [36] Hotak N, Kaneko S (2022) Fiscal illusion of the stated preferences of government officials regarding interministerial policy packages: A case study on child labor in Afghanistan. Econ Anal Policy 73: 285–298. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2021.11.019 doi: 10.1016/j.eap.2021.11.019
    [37] Jimenez BS, Afonso WB (2021) Revisiting the theory of revenue diversification: Insights from an empirical analysis of municipal budgetary solvency. Public Budg Financ 42: 196–220. https://doi.org/10.1111/pbaf.12309 doi: 10.1111/pbaf.12309
    [38] Juodis A, Karavias Y, Sarafidis V (2021) A homogeneous approach to testing for Granger non-causality in heterogeneous panels. Empir Econ 60: 93–112. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01970-9 doi: 10.1007/s00181-020-01970-9
    [39] Lee KS, Werner RA (2018) Reconsidering monetary policy: An empirical examination of the relationship between interest rates and nominal GDP growth in the US, UK, Germany and Japan. Ecol Econ 146: 26–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.013 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.013
    [40] López-Laborda J, Peña G (2018) A new method for applying VAT to financial services. Natl Tax J 71: 155–182. https://doi.org/10.17310/ntj.2018.1.05 doi: 10.17310/ntj.2018.1.05
    [41] Magazzino C, Giolli L, Marco MELE (2015) Wagner's Law and Peacock and Wiseman's displacement effect in European Union countries: A panel data study. Int J Econ Financ Issues 5: 812–819. https://dergipark.org.tr/en/pub/ijefi/issue/31970/352191
    [42] Magazzino C, Brady GL, Forte F (2019) A panel data analysis of the fiscal sustainability of G-7 countries. J Econ Asymmetries 20: e00127. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeca.2019.e00127
    [43] Marshall L (1989) Fiscal Illusion in Public Finance: A Theoretical and Empirical Study, PhD Dissertation - University of Maryland.
    [44] Marshall L (1991) New Evidence on Fiscal Illusion: The 1986 Tax Windfalls. Am Econ Rev 81: 1336–1345. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006922
    [45] Mauro P (1998) Corruption and the composition of government expenditure. J Public Econ 69: 263–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00025-5 doi: 10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00025-5
    [46] Matei I (2020) Is financial development good for economic growth? Empirical insights from emerging European countries. Quant Financ Econ 4: 653–678. https://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2020030 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020030
    [47] Mourao P (2008) Towards a Puviani's Fiscal Illusion Index. Spanish Public Finance / Revista de Economía Pública 187: 49–86.
    [48] Mourao P (2011) Sins of the elder: Fiscal illusion in democracies. Spanish Public Financ 196: 9–36. https://hdl.handle.net/1822/12611
    [49] Munley VG, Greene KV (1978) Fiscal Illusion, The Nature of Public Goods and Equation Specification. Public Choice 33: 95–100. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00123948 doi: 10.1007/BF00123948
    [50] Murphy D, Walsh KJ (2022) Government spending and interest rates. J Int Money Financ 123: 102598. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102598
    [51] Oates W (1975) Automatic Increases in Tax Revenues - The Effect on the Size of the Public Budget, In: WE Oates (ed.) Financing the New Federalism: Revenue Sharing Conditional Grants and Taxation, Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.
    [52] Oates W (1988) On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion: A Survey, In: Taxation and Fiscal Federalism: Essays in Honor of Russell Mathews, edited by G. Brennan, B. Grewal, and P. Groenwegen, 65–82. Sydney: Australian National University Press, 1988.
    [53] Onal DK (2021) The Buchanan-Wagner Hypothesis: Revisiting the Theory with New Empirics for a Spendthrift Democracy. Panoeconomicus, 1–23. https://doi.org/10.2298/PAN200522009K doi: 10.2298/PAN200522009K
    [54] Peña G (2020) A new trading algorithm with financial applications. Quant Financ Econ 4: 596–607. https://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2020027 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020027
    [55] Pommerehne WW, Schneider F (1978) Fiscal Illusion, Political Institutions and Local Public expenditure. Kyklos 31: 381–408. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6435.1978.tb00648.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6435.1978.tb00648.x
    [56] Psaradakis Z, Ravn MO, Sola M (2005) Markov switching causality and the money–output relationship. J Appl Econometrics 20: 665–683. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.819 doi: 10.1002/jae.819
    [57] Puviani A (1903) Teoria della illusione finanziaria, Sandron, Palermo.
    [58] Sáenz E, Sabaté M, Gadea MD (2013) Trade openness and public expenditure. The Spanish case, 1960–2000. Public choice 154: 173–195. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9841-8
    [59] Ullah S, Akhtar P, Zaefarian G (2018) Dealing with endogeneity bias: The generalized method of moments (GMM) for panel data. Ind Market Manag 71: 69–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010 doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010
    [60] Wagner RE (1976) Revenue Structure, Fiscal Illusion and Budgetary Choice. Public Choice 25: 45–61. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01726330 doi: 10.1007/BF01726330
    [61] Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. J Econometrics 126: 25–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
    [62] Worthington AC (1994) The Nature and Extent of Fiscal Illusion in Australia, M.Ec. Dissertation - University of New England.
    [63] Wray RL (2006b) When are Interest Rates Exogenous? In: Mark Setterfield (ed.), Complexity, Endogenous Money, and Macroeconomic Theory. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781847203113.00027
    [64] Xiao J, Karavias Y, Juodis A, et al. (2023) Improved tests for Granger noncausality in panel data. Stata J 23: 230–242. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X231162034 doi: 10.1177/1536867X231162034
    [65] Yakita A (2008) Ageing and public capital accumulation. Intl Tax Public Financ 15: 582–598. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-007-9041-0 doi: 10.1007/s10797-007-9041-0
    [66] Yakita A, Yakita A (2017) Aging and Public Capital Formatio, Population Aging, Fertility and Social Security, Population Economics, Springer, Cham, 181–193. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-47644-5_12
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1590) PDF downloads(161) Cited by(0)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog