Research article

Forward looking up-/down correlations

  • Received: 25 March 2021 Accepted: 27 May 2021 Published: 03 June 2021
  • JEL Codes: C58, G11, G17

  • Equity returns are typically higher correlated during market downturns than during bullish times. This paper develops a novel approach how investor expectations for such correlation asymmetries can be quantified from forward-looking data. Based on option implied volatilities, it is found that the correlation asymmetry is significant, rejecting the use of the classic mono-correlation assumption. Further, the spread between expected down and up correlations is time-varying and positively dependent on the current market mood: stock diversification is more difficult when it is needed the most. Thus, the three main advantages of the proposed model are (ⅰ) the distinction between up- and down-correlations, (ⅱ) it actually captures investor expectations as traded in current market prices and (ⅲ) the immediate response to the current market outlook. Practical relevance of this paper is highlighted by the computation of expected up-/down CAPM betas.

    Citation: Wolfgang Schadner. Forward looking up-/down correlations[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(3): 471-495. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021021

    Related Papers:

    [1] Mehmet F. Dicle . US Implied Volatility as A predictor of International Returns. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(4): 388-402. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.4.388
    [2] Jie Xiong, Geng Deng, Xindong Wang . Extension of SABR Libor Market Model to handle negative interest rates. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 148-171. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020007
    [3] Hammad Siddiqi . Financial market disruption and investor awareness: the case of implied volatility skew. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(3): 505-517. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022021
    [4] Elyas Elyasiani, Luca Gambarelli, Silvia Muzzioli . The Information Content of Corridor Volatility Measures During Calm and Turmoil Periods. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(4): 454-473. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.4.454
    [5] Mara Madaleno, Elisabete Vieira . Volatility analysis of returns and risk: Family versus nonfamily firms. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(2): 348-372. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.2.348
    [6] Didier Sornette, Peter Cauwels, Georgi Smilyanov . Can we use volatility to diagnose financial bubbles? lessons from 40 historical bubbles. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 486-590. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.1
    [7] Sebastian Ferrando, Andrew Fleck, Alfredo Gonzalez, Alexey Rubtsov . Trajectorial asset models with operational assumptions. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(4): 661-708. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.4.661
    [8] David Melkuev, Danqiao Guo, Tony S. Wirjanto . Applications of random-matrix theory and nonparametric change-point analysis to three notable systemic crises. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(2): 413-467. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.2.413
    [9] Elvira Caloiero, Massimo Guidolin . Volatility as an Alternative Asset Class: Does It Improve Portfolio Performance?. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(4): 334-362. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.4.334
    [10] Chikashi Tsuji . The historical transition of return transmission, volatility spillovers, and dynamic conditional correlations: A fresh perspective and new evidence from the US, UK, and Japanese stock markets. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 410-436. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024016
  • Equity returns are typically higher correlated during market downturns than during bullish times. This paper develops a novel approach how investor expectations for such correlation asymmetries can be quantified from forward-looking data. Based on option implied volatilities, it is found that the correlation asymmetry is significant, rejecting the use of the classic mono-correlation assumption. Further, the spread between expected down and up correlations is time-varying and positively dependent on the current market mood: stock diversification is more difficult when it is needed the most. Thus, the three main advantages of the proposed model are (ⅰ) the distinction between up- and down-correlations, (ⅱ) it actually captures investor expectations as traded in current market prices and (ⅲ) the immediate response to the current market outlook. Practical relevance of this paper is highlighted by the computation of expected up-/down CAPM betas.



    Equity investment practice frequently distinguishes between up- and down correlations as stock markets typically face such asymmetries: during bullish times, average correlation among stocks is low to moderate, but remarkably increases if markets turn into bearish. This effect is not only thoroughly documented within realized return patterns (e.g. Erb et al. (1994) or Ang & Chen (2002)), but also highly affects portfolio diversification. Given so, this paper investigates whether such correlation duality also exists at investor expectations and how it can be quantified from forward looking data. Hence, aim of the presented paper is to develop an econometric model which is able to fulfill this task. The core of the model builds on option implied volatilities, which reflect per construction investor expectations. Upon those risk believes it is demonstrated that asymmetric up-/down correlations will cause skewness in the joint distribution of the market portfolio. Let the correlation spread be understood as down-correlations minus up ones. If this spread is positive, then marginal return distributions of constituents will aggregate superior for the negative side of the joint distribution (i.e., market portfolio) than for the positive side. As a logic consequent, the joint distribution will be negatively skewed, even though if single stocks would be normally distributed. Thus, the model argues that expected skewness of the market portfolio in excess of marginal skews can be directly linked to correlation duality, which in turn allows to estimate such. Besides the theoretical discourse, robustness of the model is verified upon simulated data to analyze its precision and to verify that it is free of statistical biases. From empirical data of the S & P500 I demonstrate that it is straightforward to implement and highlight its practical usage for applications in corporate finance (e.g., equity valuation) or portfolio management.

    While the body of finance literature on option implied volatilities is already very broad (like Schmalensee & Trippi (1978), Bakshi et al. (2003) or Schneider et al. (2020)), research on equity implied correlations is scarce (e.g., Skintzi & Refenes (2005)). Further, although correlation duality is profoundly documented within historical return data (Longin & Solnik (1995), Cappiello et al. (2006) or Ang & Bekaert (2015)), to the best of my knowledge no study yet analyzed up- and down correlations within forward looking data. Therefore, this paper contributes to existing literature by providing a model which is able to quantify expected correlation asymmetries and delivers initial insights into their empirical behavior with some remarkable findings.

    The reading starts with a brief literature overview to trace the outline of the relevant field. Section 3 sketches the model from a theoretical perspective, whose quality is evaluated on simulated data in Section 4. Within the fifth section the model is applied upon real world data which allows to analyze empirical characteristics of the expected correlation spread. Final conclusion are drawn in Section 6.

    Generally speaking, this paper relates to two areas of finance research. First, to empirical studies analyzing equity correlations during different market phases. Second, to the measurement of investor expectations out of option data.

    The field of correlation's time varying behavior enjoys a broad body of academic literature. For example, there are earlier studies like King & Wadhwani (1990) or Bertero & Mayer (1990) which found that correlations across international financial markets significantly increased during the market crash of 1987, which gives indication in favor of down correlations being higher than up correlations. On a long time analysis (1960–1990), Longin & Solnik (1995) conclude that the level of correlation is greater during phases of high volatility, which can also be interpreted in favor of the market mood dependent correlation duality. However, there are also early studies that do not coerce with this statement, like Kaplanis (1988) or Ratner (1992) who claim that correlations remain constant over time, or Kizys & Pierdzioch (2006) who find on the period of 1970–2004 that correlation's dependence on the business cycle is not significant. Erb et al. (1994) explicitly analyze correlation structures among countries in dependence of the economic cycle with the conclusion, that during recessions they are substantially greater than during market recoveries. While there are conflicting results especially at earlier studies, by now the majority of evidence consent to correlation asymmetries, for example Ramchand & Susmel (1998), Longin & Solnik (2001), Ang & Chen (2002), Sancetta & Satchell (2007), Cappiello et al. (2006) or Ang & Bekaert (2015). Besides macroeconomic analyzes of equity correlation structures, other works focused on implementing such asymmetries. A frequent example in that context are dual factor pricing models (especially CAPM, see Pettengill et al. (1995)), which are not only used at investment practice, but also find broad support in academic research like Howton & Peterson (1999), Faff (2001), Pettengill et al. (2002) or Chong et al. (2011), Chong & Phillips (2013).

    What those mentioned studies have in common is that they analyze correlations of realized returns. When quantifying expectations, however, the use of such historical return data can be problematic as there is no guarantee that realizations in the past will repeat themselves in the future. (cp. Bali et al. (2019) or Schneider et al. (2020)) This is why the study presented here focuses on the use of forward looking data. Or, to be more precisely, the model builds on the availability of option implied volatilities. Literature in this discipline was initialized by Black & Scholes (1973), the use of implied volatilities as investor expectations goes back to Schmalensee & Trippi (1978). Guo et al. (2016) point out that working with implied volatilities rather than option prices directly became common practice in quantitative finance. Recent examples of option implied information are (among many others) Bakshi et al. (2003) who provide a model for ex-ante higher moments, Schneider et al. (2020) analyzing asset pricing anomalies or Bali et al. (2019) with an expectation-based empirical asset pricing study - just to name a few. Besides the field of asset pricing, implied volatilities are also used in an economic context, for example by Fassas, Kenourgios & Papadamou (2020) to quantify the effect of monetary policy announcements upon expected currency risk. Or, by Fassas, Papadamou & Philippas (2020) where implied volatilities serve to measure international spillover effects in investor risk-aversion with respect to quantitative easing. Also pointing into the behavioral direction, Äijö (2008) and Schadner (2020a) find empirical support that the implied volatility term structure indicates investor sentiment. On the econometric side, Jeon et al. (2020) demonstrate that implied volatilities can be used to enhance the predictive power of existing models.

    As there exist many studies on implied volatilities as well as implied correlations for the FX market (e.g., Walter & Lopez (2000)), literature on implied equity correlations is rather scarce. The difficulty of computing implied correlations (and the respective matrix) arises from the fact that in a stock market there are no direct derivatives for pairs of stocks, thus no unique solution to this problem currently exists. However, one mathematically feasible solution to the ex-ante correlation matrix is the CBOE Implied Correlation Index (cp. Skintzi & Refenes (2005)), which solves the puzzle under the equi-correlation assumption (i.e., all pairs within the implied correlation matrix share the same value). This purely ex-ante methodology was mixed with ex-post computations by researchers like Buss & Vilkov(2009, 2012), Numpacharoen & Numpacharoen (2013) or Driessen et al. (2013). Building on Skintzi & Refenes (2005)'s equicorrelation method, Linders & Schoutens (2014) provide an empirical analysis of the implied correlation surface with options of fixed maturities and different degrees of moneyness. They find that, just like for the implied volatility smile (cp. Mixon (2010)), the ex-ante correlation curve over degrees of moneyness is typically downward sloping. Without further tests nor discussion, they mention that "...the decreasing implied correlation curve may imply that the market expects stocks to go down simultaneously, while they are expected to go up more independently" (Linders & Schoutens (2014)). This statement is key cause for this study to not only develop a model that captures implied correlation duality, but also to investigate whether there is a link between the implied correlation surface and ex-ante correlation spreads.

    Assume a financial market of n traded stocks iI={1,,n} that are weighted according to the n×1 vector w to form the market portfolio m. There are financial options upon each single firm as well as the market index per se traded, such that respective prices can be used to express implied volatilities of the underlying.1 As implied volatilities are per definition forward looking, they serve as proxies for expected risk under the risk neutral measure.2 Given this framework, m's first two central moments are identical to its cumulants κ and computed as

    κ1;m=μm=wμand (1)
    κ2;m=σ2m+κ21;mwithσ2m=wDΓDw (2)

    1For example, by Black-Scholes option pricing formula an observed call price can be iteratively solved to observe the implied volatility the derivative is priced under, see e.g. Schmalensee & Trippi (1978).

    2Known in finance literature as Q-measure. Note that the study presented here makes all computations for Q dynamics. The reader interested in P expectations can apply the very same model, but has to subtract a variance risk premium from Q implied volatilities, see e.g. in Carr & Wu (2006).

    where μ corresponds to the n×1 vector of expected stock returns, Γ to the n×n correlation matrix and D being a n×n diagonal matrix of implied volatilities, i:Dii=σi. Since w is directly observable and σ2m as well as D can be easily estimated from option prices, CBOE's equicorrelation approach now sets all off-diagonal elements within Γ equal to an average level ˉc that resembles Equation 2, meaning that wDΓDwwDˉΓDw. CBOE's respective white paper (Skintzi & Refenes (2005)) suggests approximating ˉc by iteratively solving this equilibrium. However, different to that, Schadner (2020b) suggests a closed form solution that is computational more efficient. Let us introduce the n×n identity matrix E as well as J=1E where 1 is a n×n unity matrix (consisting only of 1's). Thus, the equicorrelation matrix can be split up as

    ˉΓ=(1ˉcˉc1)=ˉc(0110)+(1001)=ˉcJ+Eij:ˉcij=ˉc (3)

    such that the implied correlation puzzle under the equicorrelation model is solved by

    ˉc=σ2mv0v1withv0:=wD2w,v1:=wDJDw (4)

    which is basically one plausible solution to this ex-ante correlation puzzle. Nonetheless, as only n+1 implied volatilities are observable but there exist (n21)/n unknown correlation pairs, several other theoretically possible solutions exist. Say we fix option's time to maturity to some fixed target level τ (e.g., one month), and apply Equation 4 over different levels of moneyness d=ln(PstrikeP0).3 In the Black-Scholes market model, where higher than 2nd order moments are zero and correlations are symmetric, all implied volatilities would form a flat surface over all levels of τ and d. This assumption is clearly an unrealistic scenario, but still a good starting point hence it became common practice to compute Black-Scholes implied volatilities and fit regression splines to estimate higher moments (cp. Zhang & Xiang (2008)). With Equation 3, ˉc can be easily computed for different levels of d, which by plotting ˉc against d forms the implied correlation surface. Figure 1 is such an example of the S & P500 for the dates Dec. 31, 2007 and Sept. 30, 2015.

    Figure 1.  S & P500 implied correlation surface over different levels of moneyness observed on Dec. 31, 2007 and Sept. 30, 2015. A downward sloping curvature is presumed to indicate that investors expect stock returns to correlate higher for market downturns than for up moves. This believe is referred to as correlation duality.

    3P0 is the current price of the underlying, Pstrike the strike price of the option.

    While in the Black-Scholes framework this curve should be flat, Linders & Schoutens (2014) find that empirically this curve is typically of negative slope. Without any proof, they mention that this smirk may be attributable to the fact that realized correlations during market downturns are on average higher than for up markets, and that the slope may be directly interpreted as investor expect correlation asymmetries. However, to the best of the author's knowledge, no study yet has explicitly analyzed whether this statement holds or not.

    For the subsequent reading please consider the following notation: when used as syntax, + refers to positive returns (i.e., interval over [0,)); vice versa, refers to negative returns (interval of (,0)). Further, note that generally for any pdf of x it holds that

    σ2=E[x2]E[x]2 (5)
    σ2+μ2=x2f(x)dx (6)
    =0x2f(x)dx+0x2f(x)dx (7)
    =PM+PM+ (8)

    with PM as the 2nd order lower partial moment and PM+ as the 2nd order upper partial moment, both with a reference point equal to 0 such that PM corresponds to negative returns and vice versa PM+ to positive ones.

    Lemma 1. Correlation-duality causes skewness in the joint distribution of the portfolio.

    Proof   Consider a continuous multivariate normal random variable ˜X={˜x1,˜x2,...} which describes a set of correlated stocks I. The return vector of the market portfolio rm is thus given as the value weighted sum of ˜X, rm=w˜X. If joint densities of ˜X are elliptical, then it is straight forward that the joint distribution rm will be normally distributed and the link between stocks can be efficiently expressed by their linear dependence, i.e. Pearson's correlation. In such a setting, PMm can be (statistically unbiased) approximated by the value weighted aggregate of individual PMi's:3

    PMmwLΓLwwLˉΓLwLn×n:{Lij=PMii=j0ij (9)
    ^PMm=ˉcl1+l0 (10)

    4Like portfolio value-at-risk from the RiskMetrics model, see Longerstaey & Spencer (1996).

    with ^PMm as the unbiased approximate of PMm and

    l1=wLJLwandl0=wLLw (11)

    Note that likewise D is a diagonal matrix of volatilities, L is a diagonal matrix of individual partial moments. Equations 9 to 11 are equivalent for the construction of PM+m, hence

    ^PM+m=ˉcl+1+l+0 (12)

    What happens now if correlations are on average higher during market downturns (rm<0) than during market recovery (rm>0), say ˉc>ˉc>ˉc+? To analyze this, we define the correlation-duality regime as follows:

    corr{˜X}:={Γ+ˉc+J+Eifrm>0ΓˉcJ+Eifrm<0 (13)

    Meaning that positive market returns are generated under Γ+ and vice versa with Γ. Given so, the PMm's will now aggregate under different correlation parameter, that is,

    ^PMm=ˉcl1+l0and^PM+m=ˉc+l+1+l+0 (14)

    Let us define Δˉc:=ˉcˉc+ and note that l1's and l0's (Equation 11) are drawn from individual distributions, hence (mathematically) independent of Δˉc. Henceforth, by Equation 14 it follows that

    iffΔˉc>0:^PMm(ˉc)>^PMm(ˉc)and^PM+m(ˉc+)<^PM+m(ˉc) (15)

    such that with an increasing correlation spread, probability mass within the joint distribution will be shifted from the positive to the negative tail. Henceforth, the joint distribution becomes asymmetric, which is in contradiction to the joint distribution being normal. In this sense, the larger the discrepancy between ˉc+ and ˉc, the more will be one side of the mean be weighted against the other one. From this follows that correlation duality causes skewness in the return distribution of the market portfolio, even though if single constituents would be normally distributed. By Equation 15, if ˉc>ˉc+ then median(rm)>μm which implies that rm will be negatively skewed; vice versa for ˉc<ˉc+. Hence,

    ^PMmΔˉc>0and^PM+mΔˉc<0γmΔˉc<0a.s. (16)

    means that the larger the correlation spread, the more negative the expected skew of the market portfolio becomes. This law should still hold if individual stock returns are not normally distributed, even if other aggregation procedures apply. Thus, X may be described by any realistic multivariate stock return distribution, it generally holds that ˉc+ˉc creates skewness in the market portfolio.

    Lemma 2. Correlation-duality causes portfolio skewness as it causes co-skewness among stocks.

    Proof  Consider the way Pearson's skewness is defined,

    γ:=sσ3=E[(xμσ)3]=E[x3]3E[x2]μ+2μ3σ3=κ33κ2κ1+2κ31κ3/22 (17)

    with s as the distribution's third (non-standardized) moment. The first two moments were already defined in Equation 2. For our market portfolio the observable term that remains is the third cumulant κ3;m which is computed from

    κ3;m=wκ3;X(ww)ijkwiwjwksijk (18)

    where κ3;X is the super-symmetric (non-standardized) skew-co-skewness matrix of size n×n2. This means that κ3;X is a combination of n many symmetric n×n matrices,

    κ3;Xn×n2={κ3;1n×nκ3;2n×nκ3;nn×n} (19)

    κ3;m is thus equivalent to the value weighted sum of each possible skew/co-skewness term sijk. Like the co-variance matrix has entries for single firm variances, κ3;X also has entries that are linked to individual distribution's skewness. Specifically, firm i's skewness is captured at the ith position on the diagonal of the κ3;i sub-matrix,

    individualskews:diag(κ3;i)i=si=γiσ3iiI (20)

    All other elements within κ3;X that are not on such special positions are co-skewness terms. In the case of normally distributed stocks we faced individual skews equal zero, γi=0,i. Under non-normal distributions, individual skews may be different from zero, but still computable (from option data) on an individual level and thus independent of other firms. Therefore, one recognizes that correlation-duality can only drive cross-sectional co-skewness terms in order to cause skew in the aggregated portfolio. Being aware of that, one can distinguish γm generated from individual skew and γm caused by co-skewness. To get there, I develop an approach to compute the equi-co-skew from option data which is similar to the equicorrelation procedure before.

    Let K be a n×n2 matrix with 0's on the positions indicated by Equation 20 and 1's otherwise. Respectively, 1n×n2K indicates positions affected by individual skews. Likewise D contained firm volatilities, we capture individual skew loadings on the n×n diagonal matrix S. Hence the feasible solution to κ3;X with individual skews but equi-co-skews is given by

    κ3;X=ˉsKcoskews+S(1K)skews (21)

    which implies

    κ3;m=w[ˉsK+S(1K)](ww) (22)
    =ˉswK(ww)u1+wS(1K)(ww)u0 (23)
    =ˉsu1+u0 (24)

    With this simplification, portfolio skewness composes as

    γm=1σ3m[ˉsu1+u03μmσ2mμ3m] (25)

    through which the equi-co-skew can be computed out of option data,

    ˉs=1u1[γmσ3mu0+3μmσ2m+μ3m] (26)

    As far as the author is aware of this approach is first in finance literature to estimate expected co-skewness completely from ex-ante data and is perhaps interesting for several other applications. Back to our task, since all individual skew contributions are captured within u0 and co-skew effects within ˉsu1, by Equation 25 one can distinguish portfolio skewness generated from firm skews and co-skews as 5

    γm=γm;co+u0σ3mwithγm;co:=ˉsu1σ3m3μmσmμ3mσ3m (27)

    5Note that in the case of multivariate normal it holds that ˉs0. This is easily illustrated by ˜XN():s˜X=E[˜X3]3E[˜X2]E[˜X]+2E[˜X]3 and since in this case it holds that u0=0andE[˜X3]=ˉsu1+u03E[˜X2]E[˜X]2E[˜X]3s˜X=0iffˉs0γ˜X=0.

    Therefore, since

    γmΔˉc<0andu0σ3mΔˉcγm;coΔˉc<0 (28)

    it is shown that correlation-duality causes skewness as it generates co-skewness among stocks.

    To quantify the magnitude of Δˉc on γm, one has to approximate the shape of market distribution. I do so by Gram-Charlier expansion using the first three moments, 6 whose cdf is generally given as

    F(x)=f(x)dx (29)
    =ϕ(x)[1+γ6He3(z)]dxHe3=z33z,z=xμσ (30)
    =ϕ(x)dx+γ6ϕ(x)He3(z)dx (31)

    6As demonstrated above, correlation duality is a generator of asymmetry, thus I am not interested into excess kurtosis and assume even higher moments are neglectable small.

    where ϕ(x) denotes the pdf of a normal distribution and He3 is the third Hermite polynomial. Taking Equation 5, for the market portfolio one writes

    σ2m+μ2mPM=x2ϕ(x)dxPMnorm+γm6x2ϕ(x)He3(z)dxPMcorr (32)

    which can be interpreted as the total 2nd partial moment of the skewed joint distribution PM composes of a normally distributed part PMnorm and a correction term PMcorr. The split is convenient because for PMnorm we know that the aggregation formula of Equation 14 applies unbiased, such that it holds

    PMPMcorr=0x2ϕ(x)dx+0x2ϕ(x)dx (33)
    ^PM^PMcorr=ˉcl1+l0+ˉc+l+1+l+0 (34)

    Note that from option implied data, the parameters σ,γ,μ can be estimated, such that the integrals can be computed. In order to correct for individual skews, PMcorr is computed under γm;co (Equation 27) rather than total γm which should remove potential statistical biases related to non-symmetric marginal distributions. With this in mind, we can do the split

    ^PM^PMcorr=ˉcl1+l0and^PM+^PM+corr=ˉc+l+1+l+0 (35)

    such that by rearranging terms, the average expected up and down correlation can be computed by

    ˉc=1l1[^PM^PMcorrl0]andˉc+=1l+1[^PM+^PM+corrl+0] (36)

    Lemma 3. The option implied correlation surface contains information about asymmetric expectations for up-/down correlations.

    Proof  It is generally known that a smile within the Black-Scholes implied volatility surface over different strikes refers to non-zero higher moments believes (cp. for example Bakshi et al. (2003), Mixon (2010)). Respectively, the slope within is (positively) connected to ex-ante skewness for which finance literature developed several methods to approximate. On the example of Gram-Charlier expansion, the volatility surface σ(d) over different levels of moneyness d can be interpolated as

    σ(d)=σATM+γd6τd:=ln(PstrikeP0) (37)

    (cp. Jarrow & Rudd (1982)) with Pstrike as the option's strike level, P0 as the current price of the underlying and σATM as the at-the-money implied volatility (i.e., σ(Pstrike=P0)). In awareness of Equation 4, one is now able to write the implied volatility surface in terms of equi-correlations,

    σm(d)=ˉc(d)v1+v0 (38)

    so combining these two equations, the implied correlation surface can be directly linked to market skewness, 7

    (ˉc(d)v1+v0σm)6τd=γmˉc(d)=1v1(σm+γmd6τ)2v0v1 (39)

    7Note that for simplicity σmσm;ATM in my notation.

    Therefore, substituting back in what we already know,

    ˉc(d)=1v1[σm+(γm;co(ˉc+,ˉc)+u0σ3m)d6τ]2v0v1 (40)

    models the link between asymmetric expected correlations and the implied correlation surface. Since

    d:γm;coΔˉc<0ˉc(d)Δˉc<0a.s. (41)

    it is shown that the implied correlation surface reflects that investors may have different believes for up- than for down correlations. Further, this will also confirm the statement of Linders & Schoutens (2014) that if ˉc(d)d<0, then Δˉc>0

    Besides the demonstrated Gram-Charlier case, within every risk-neutral approximation method available in literature, 8 γm is positively proportional to σ(d)d such that the result of Equation 41 generally holds almost surely.

    8It is common that a negative slope within the implied volatility surface corresponds to negative skewness believes (see e.g. Jarrow & Rudd (1982), Bakshi et al. (2003), Mixon (2010) or Bali et al. (2019))

    Quality of the dual-correlation model is evaluated upon simulated data, where one can explicitly control for true up-/down correlations and backtest the estimation precision as if they were hidden. For this purpose, the simulation is broken down into two parts. I start by analyzing the joint distributional asymmetry caused through a correlation spread. Specifically, the impact of Δˉc on ΔPM and on portfolio skewness are quantified. Then I continue by evaluating the model precision itself, that is the error of true up-/down correlations versus those estimated through the Gram-Charlier approach. All computations executed within this section and in the empirical part were made using the statistical software R.

    The simulation data is generated as follows. The number of stocks is set to n=100 and the time-series length to 1000, where one time step represents one trading day. For all stocks the mean return is defined to equal the risk free rate, which is set to 1% per year, thus i:μi=rf=1%/252.9 Differently, stock volatilities are drawn from a random uniform distribution ranging between 10%/252 and 50%/252. Since real stock markets typically show a very unequally distribution of market values, w is created as

    w=w0w0withw0(i)=1ln(i+1)i[1,n] (42)

    9Same mean return for all stocks is required to meet Q dynamics. 1% p.a. divided by 252 trading days converts annual quotations to daily returns.

    to better meet real world scenarios.10 With this setting, two correlated multivariate normal return matrices are generated, one under the true up correlation, r+N(μ,σ;ˉc+), and one under the true down correlation, rN(μ,σ;ˉc). ˉc+ is drawn from a uniform random distribution within [0.2,0.6] and respectively ˉc[0.3,0.7]. Now, two portfolios are formed, r+p=wr+ and rp=wr, which serve as reference. The cross-sectional return matrix r with distinct up-/down correlations is now generated by combining the subsamples r+|r+p>0 and r|rp<0,

    r:=[r+|r+p>0r|rp<0] (43)

    10Visualization of input volatilities and weights can be found in the Appendix.

    where rows are randomly re-sampled afterwards in order to remove systematic auto-correlation. Once r is generated, the return vector of the market portfolio simply evolves as rm=wr. This procedure is then repeated a 1000 times to get a basket of simulated return data under different correlation spreads.

    As discussed in Section 3, ceteris paribus, a difference in up- and down correlations is expected to cause asymmetric 2nd order partial moments in the joint distribution of the market portfolio. By the simulated data one is now able to explicitly verify this argument. For each of the 1000 simulated r matrices I compute PM, PM+ and skewness of the respective market portfolio. Figure 2 visualizes the spread in partial moments as well as γm plotted against Δˉc, both plots come with a linearly fitted line to further emphasize the relation. Although every single firm's r is drawn from a normal distribution, both plots confirm that the joint distribution becomes asymmetric around its mean as soon as down-correlations are different from up-correlations. Note that Δˉc=0 leads to γm being on average 0, which is straight forward as it describes the mono-correlation regime-otherwise, if this picture would not evolve, then there would be an error in the generated data. The proper fit of the OLS lines indicate that there is no systematic statistical bias with respect to the approximation of the lower partial moments by the suggested Gram-Charlier expansion. By Equation 35 this linearity is an important feature.11 Goodness of fit of the regression lines are 0.91 and 0.86 with highly significant coefficients (t-statistics of 103.5, 78.0). Importantly, there does not seem to be any significant misestimation with respect to the level of the correlation spread, neither in ΔPM nor in γm. With the patterns found in Figure 2 Hypothesis 1 can be confirmed. Since all individual skews are equal to 0, the right plot of Figure 2 together with Equation 27 confirm Hypothesis 2.

    Figure 2.  Analysis of (true) correlation spread's impact on portfolio asymmetries (Δˉc=ˉcˉc+). Left plot displays difference in partial moments (PMPM+), right plot highlights generated portfolio skewness. As proposed by the model, Δˉc causes both asymmetric PM to PM+ as well as skewness in the return distribution of the market portfolio. This observation is an incentive to model a dual-correlation regime via the skewness channel.

    11I confirm that Gram-Charlier expansion is suitable as both plots seem to result in (ⅰ) elliptical estimates, (ⅱ) do not show patterns of non-linearity and (ⅲ) residuals look to fulfill homoscedasticity. In the case of simulated data being drawn from a different distribution one may check whether the correction term of Equation 36 is sufficient to remove statistical biases, otherwise further specifications are required.

    Having underpin Hypothesis 1 and 2, the question arises of how precise the proposed approximation method is. For this purpose I plot ex-ante specified up-/down correlations against estimated ones of Equation 36 and investigate whether there are systematic misestimations. Figure 3 does this plot. In addition, the displayed lines are of intercept 0 and slope of 1. Hence the lines serve as reference: the closer the estimates are on the line the higher the accuracy. Therefore, by Figure 3 one observes that estimation accuracy seems proper and there is no significant heteroscedasticity with respect to the level of true up-/down correlations. This conclusion is important in an econometric sense, as by such one can presume the model to be statistically unbiased. The estimation error for up-correlations ranged between 0.055 and 0.061 at a mean of 0.002, respective values for the down-scenario are 0.081, 0.071 and 0.0005.

    Figure 3.  True up-/down correlations versus estimated ones. Red lines are of intercept zero and slope 1 to serve as accuracy reference. Left and mid plot show levels, right plot the difference in estimated versus true dual-correlations. The Gram-Charlier approach as discussed seems to deliver a good fit for estimating correlation duality. From visual inspection, no statistical bias of the estimation model with respect to the level of true correlations is observable.

    Going further into details, one may be also interested whether there is a statistical bias related to the spread of correlations. Herein Figure 4 grasps the corresponding results. From visual inspection I am not able to identify any systematic misestimation, as residuals for both cases seem to be homoscedastic in Δˉc.

    Figure 4.  Estimation error of up-/down correlations versus correlation spreads. No clear dependence observable, thus no statistical bias with respect to Δˉc. Thus, I suggest the Gram-Charlier approach to be a feasible estimation model for expected up- and down correlations.

    Concluding the Simulation, I find support in favor of Hypothesis 1 and 2. By inspecting residuals of estimated up-/down correlations, I presume that the proposed method delivers accurate and statistically unbiased estimates for ˉc+ and ˉc. Hence I suggest the model to be robust and appropriate for econometric usage.

    Within this section the discussed framework is applied upon empirical data. First, I start by computing time-series of expected up-, down- and mid- correlations and compare them to each other. Mid correlation is simply defined as the one used in Equation 3, that is CBOE's equi-correlation. Second, I analyze whether the implied correlation smirk as mentioned in Section 3 or Linders & Schoutens (2014) is indeed empirically linked to differences in expected up-/down correlations. Within the third part the model is used to demonstrate practical relevance upon an example of computing expected up- and down CAPM betas, which are frequently used by portfolio managers (but typically estimated ex-post).

    All data are derived from Bloomberg L.P. and Thomson Reuter's Datastream. Computations are made upon the S & P 500 cross-section using option implied volatilities with a target maturity of 1 month for both the single stocks and the index itself. The observation horizon is Dec. 2007 to Sept. 2018 and the computations are rolled over on an end-of-monthly basis. Note that the input data reflect investor expectations under risk-neutrality (Q-measure), which can be transformed into P dynamics by explicitly modeling expected variance as well as correlation risk premia. However, this is out of the scope of this study and I would like to refer the reader interested into such a conversion to Carr & Wu (2009) or Fassas & Papadamou (2018).

    Herein the described model of Section 3 is applied upon empirical data to compute time series of up and down correlations. Computations are made under the correction of firms' individual ex-ante skews, 12 see Equation 27. The results are visualized in Figure 5 and summarized in Table 1. Overall I find that for the entire observation horizon the correlation spread was positive with a slightly increasing trend. This means that the aggregate of investor expectations thoroughly presumed equity returns to be higher correlated for market downturns (rm<0) than for recoveries (rm>0). As can be seen in Figure 5, the correlation spread shows time-varying behavior and ranges between 0.074 and 0.303 with a mean of 0.167. Thus, non-surprisingly, a t-test of the spread results in Δˉc being significantly positive at a t-statistic of 41.18. When compared to CBOE's equicorrelation, the ˉc+ was on average 24.7% lower than ˉc, while ˉc was 25% higher, hence diversification opportunities diminish in bearish markets. Concluding those observations, patterns found in empirical ex-post analyses (discussed in Section 2) are also reflected ex-ante within investor expectations, such that assuming a mono-correlation regime may cause statistical biases in financial analyses. This significant spread also underlines the importance of using a dual-correlation regime within practical applications.

    Figure 5.  Time Series of estimated up-, down- and mid correlations. Upper panel displays the level, lower panel the spread between down and up correlations. While overall there is an declining trend for the absolute level, the spread seems to increase over time. Estimates were made by correcting for individual firm skews.
    Table 1.  Summary statistics of expected up (ˉc+), down (ˉc) and mid (ˉc) correlations. Interestingly, up correlations were on average 24.7% lower compared to the classic mid correlation; respectively, down correlations exceeded mid correlations by 25.0%. The average spread between ˉc and ˉc+ is 0.167, while the minimum spread is 0.074, which is not even close to zero. Thus, empirics strongly support existence of a dual-correlation regime and reject the mono-correlation assumption.
    Corr. Min. 1st Qu. Median Mean 3rd Qu. Max.
    up 0.049 0.196 0.293 0.300 0.392 0.626
    mid 0.104 0.290 0.372 0.384 0.477 0.737
    down 0.161 0.367 0.453 0.468 0.555 0.854
    Δˉc 0.074 0.133 0.165 0.167 0.197 0.303
    up/mid -54.5% -31.3% -21.8% -24.7% -16.7% -8.1%
    down/mid 8.3% 17.3% 22.4% 25.0% 31.6% 55.1%

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    12Ex-ante skewness are estimated according to Jarrow & Rudd (1982), i.e. regression fit of Equation 37

    In this context I believe it is further interesting to analyze correlation's and spread's dependency on market mood. With economic intuition one would argue that an risk averse investor trades a higher spread for bearish times (i.e., greater likelihood for downturns) than for confident times. For this purpose I use the sentiment index iH of Schadner (2020a)13 which is a measure of the magnitude and the direction of the market mood (optimistic/pessimistic). iH as originally presented is transformed in the following way, ~iH=2(iH0.5) such that ~iH(1,1), from which follows that ~iH is specified over the same interval as correlations are. ~iH is interpreted as the more positive ~iH becomes, the better the observed market mood; vice versa, if ~iH turns negative, then investors are pessimistic. Respective results of the conducted analysis can be found in Figure 6 and Table 2. Since it is documented that the level of average implied correlation seems to be dependent on the economic cycle (see Linders & Schoutens (2014)), I start by quantifying the link between ˉc and ~iH. From plotting empirical ~iH against ˉc and fitting a simple OLS regression, I find that there is a significant negative relation between those two variables with a coefficient of 0.717 (t-statistic of -18.56). Hence the finding coerces with the statement of Linders & Schoutens (2014). I further investigate how Δˉc changes with respect to changes in ~iH. If market participants are risk averse, then economic intuition would tell that correlation spreads increase if market fear rises and vice versa. Let Δt(Δˉc):=ΔˉctΔˉct1 and Δt(iH):=~iHt~iHt1 express the time changes in correlation spreads and market mood, by plotting corresponding observations against each other (Figure 6, right plot) one can inspect that the suggested relation indeed holds in empirical data. Also for this setting, a simple OLS regression delivers a proper fit and indicates the regression's coefficients to be highly significant at a level of 0.225 and t-statistic of 7.828.

    Figure 6.  Implied correlations versus market mood. X-axes are assigned to the transformed implied Hurst exponent (~iH): above 0 indicates an optimistic market phase, below 0 reflects a bearish market. Left plot displays the level of average correlations on the y-axis versus level of ˜c, right plot the time-changes of Δˉc vs. time-changes of ˜c. The displayed pattern seems interesting in the following sense: market mood and average correlations tend to move in opposing directions. Thus, when diversification is need the most, i.e. during bearish markets (˜c<0), it is more difficult to achieve. This risk aversion can be also observed with a look on time-increments; when the mood drops then this comes simultaneously with an increase in Δˉc. Other way around, investors are willing to reduce correlation spreads when market mood rises.
    Table 2.  Fitted OLS regression lines with respect to market mood (~iH), see Figure 6. First column (1) analyzes the levels of equicorrelations vs. ~iH, second column the time-changes in the correlation spread with respect to time changes in ~iH. Average correlation relates significantly negative to market mood. Thus, high correlation expectations are observed during bearish markets, while bullish markets are easier to diversify at. The significant negative relation in (2) is equivalently interpreted as investors risk-aversion: if sentiment drops, than there may be a higher likelihood of market downturns, thus market participants increase the traded correlation spread.
    (1) levels (2) time increments
    average corr. Δt(Δˉc)
    ~iH 0.717 Δt~iH 0.225
    (0.039) (0.029)
    Intercept 0.518 Intercept 0.001
    (0.010) (0.003)
    R2 0.729 0.325
    Note:    *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    13Option implied Hurst exponent which is computed from the term-structure of S & P500 ATM implied volatilities.

    An additional empirical analysis has been carried out with respect to the S & P 500 constituent turnover. The turnover is defined as the number of firms entering or exiting the index, respective decisions for the index are made on a quarterly basis. Hence, the data is split into quarters and for each sub-sample the turnover as well as quarter-average and end-of-quarter ˉc, Δˉc are computed. In a next step, Spearman dependencies between turnover and ˉc, Δˉc are estimated.14 The results indicate no monotonic relationship between the turnover and ˉc, estimates are 0.023 (q.-average) and 0.010 (end-of-q.). The relationships between turnover and implied spreads Δˉc are slightly negative at 0.161 (q.-average) and 0.212 (end-of-q.), but still in-significant. Therefore I conclude that there is no substantial dependence between turnover rates and implied correlations.

    14Spearman instead of Pearson measure is used due to the smaller sample size.

    Within the subsequent analysis it is evaluated whether Hypothesis 3 is met in empirical data or not. Specifically, time series of equicorrelations (Equation 3) are computed for moneyness levels of 90%, 95%, 100%, 105% and 110%; Figure 7 shows the respective output. Hypothesis 3 basically states that the duality spread (ˉcˉc+; cp. Figure 5) has to increases when the lines in Figure 7 diverge, and diminish when the lines within the plot overlap. The test of Hypothesis 3 is broken down into two set-ups, a 'two-sided' one (Figure 8, upper plots) and a 'one-sided' one (Figure 8, lower plots). For the two-sided set-up both options of the OTM spread have a moneyness level different from 100%, while for the one-sided set-up one of the option's moneyness level is fixed to at-the-money and the other one is non-ATM. The reason to do so is the following, while with the two-sided test I evaluate whether there is a general connection between moneyness spreads and correlation duality, the one-sided test also evaluates whether the direction is correct. Let excess correlations be defined as estimates in excess of ˉc (i.e., mid-correlation computed under ATM level). By the economic argument of Linders & Schoutens (2014) as well as the sketched proof before, the excess down correlation has to be positively related to excess correlations of moneyness levels lower than 100%. Vice versa, excess correlations of moneyness > 100% should be positively related to the excess up-correlation. The two-sided spreads are chosen to be symmetric around ATM, thus I analyze the 95%–105% spread and the 90%–110% one. For the one-sided test implied estimates are compared for ±5% in excess of ATM. Results for the one-sided as well as two-sided set-up can be found in Figure 8 and Table 3. Generally, I find thorough empirical support for Hypothesis 3. As initially suggested, all four analyzes realize a significant positive relation between spreads from the correlation smile and spreads from estimated up-/down correlations. This does not only confirm the model, but also motivates to use (excess) correlations of the implied smile as proxies for expected up- and down correlations.

    Figure 7.  Time series of implied (mid-)correlations for different levels of option moneyness. Obviously the implied correlation surface is not flat thorough the observation period as lines do not coerce. Hypothesis 3 claims that the spread among different levels of moneyness links to investors expecting different up- than down correlations.
    Figure 8.  Upper plots display correlation spreads from non-ATM options (y-axis) versus spread of estimated up-/down correlations (x-axis); left-upper plot shows values from moneyness equal to 100 ± 5%, right-upper plot the 100 ± 10% case. The linearly fitted blue lines support the statement that implied correlation smiles indicate correlation duality. Lower plots display spreads in excess of the mid-correlation. As suggested by the model, excess down correlations are positively linked to excess OTM spreads, same holds for excess up correlations and ITM spreads. Summary statistics of the OLS fitted lines can be found in Table 3.
    Table 3.  Linearly fitted regression lines as displayed in Figure 8. All slopes are (ⅰ) significant and (ⅱ) close to 1. This pattern supports the statement that a smirk in the implied correlation surface (Figure 1) can be interpreted as investors expect up-movements to be less correlated than down-movements.
    moneyness spread:
    95% - 105% 90% - 110% 5% - 100% 100% - 110%
    Up-/Down Spread 1.003 0.947
    (ˉcˉc+) (0.137) (0.174)
    Excess Down 1.037
    (ˉcˉc) (0.232)
    Excess Up 1.003
    (ˉcˉ2+) (0.202)
    Intercept 0.065 0.118 0.064 −0.001
    (0.024) (0.030) (0.020) (0.017)
    R2 0.294 0.188 0.135 0.162
    Note:    *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    From those observations I conclude the statement of Linders & Schoutens (2014) and thus also Hypothesis 3 to hold. Hence the implied correlation surface may be directly used for approximating expected up-/down correlations.

    Within this section I highlight the use of the dual correlation regime upon the example of up- and down betas of the CAPM model (Sharpe (1964)), which are frequently used by investment practitioners in the context of corporate valuation, portfolio or risk management purposes. (cp. Chong & Phillips (2013)) Worth to mention, the beta-duality within this study is addressed via the channel of asymmetric correlation believes, an alternative (economic) approach is given by Campbell & Vuolteenaho (2004) who break CAPM beta into two components: a discount-rate beta and a cash-flow beta. Within their work, the former one is the "good" beta, the latter one the "bad" beta. At the dual-correlation model, up-betas are "good" (preferred by investors) and down-betas are "bad" (disfavored).15

    15 A link between the two models exists if it can be proven that discount-rate and cash-flow news are drivers of asymmetric correlation believes. This proof requires an in-depth theoretical and empirical analysis and is out of scope of this study.

    Under standard CAPM, a stock's beta βi is defined as

    βi=cov(i,m)σ2m=ρi,mσiσmσ2m (44)

    Thus, the extension for correlation duality is very simple; given volatilities as well as correlations are computed ex-ante, at time t, the vector of expected up betas β+ and down betas β evolve from Equations 36 and 44 as

    β+=1σ2mDΓ+Dw and β=1σ2mDΓDw (45)

    which are computed on a monthly basis. Note that the use of implied data here has two main advantages. First, beta estimates are per construction time conditional as implied volatilities are. Second, since all input data are ex-ante, estimates reflect per definition investor expectations which is a key requirement of CAPM.

    For the empirical analysis the correlation estimates from before are used to compute β+t and βt for each t. Respectively, mid-betas (βmid) are calculated under the equicorrelation regime using ˉc. Therefore, I receive time-series for each of the three different beta vectors. Table 4 summarizes the resulting estimates over time and stocks. Since by Figure 5 the down correlation is mainly larger than its counterpart, it is not surprising that β+it's are on average below 1 and βit's above 1. By expressing the estimates relative to βmid the picture is very similar to Table 3 from before. That is, the mono-correlation model would underestimate market risk exposure on average by 24.8%, while it overestimates upside potential by 24.5%. This conclusion fosters the relevance of such a dual-correlation regime for efficient portfolio risk management. Densities of β+ and β are visualized in Figure 10. At Figure 9 time-series of the cross-sectional beta vectors are summarized, showing the 5% and 95% quantile as well as the mean of β+ and β. As Δˉc is increasing over the observation horizon, it follows that average β+ decreases while β increases over t. Interesting at this point, the discrepancy between up- and down betas is less during the time period of the financial crisis (2008).

    Table 4.  Summary statistics of cross-sectional and time-conditional expected CAPM up- and down beta estimates. First two rows give insights to the distributions of betas. Last two rows show how the dual betas are different in comparison to standard CAPM betas. Thus one sees that expected up betas are significantly overestimated, on average by 24.5%, while the opposite holds for downside betas by 24.8%.
    Min. 1st Qu. Median Mean 3rd Qu. Max.
    β+ 0.017 0.617 0.781 0.836 0.999 5.142
    β 0.029 1.052 1.294 1.379 1.592 10.324
    β+/βmid -54.5% -31.3% -21.7% -24.5% -16.5% -7.8%
    β/βmid 8.0% 17.2% 22.2% 24.8% 31.6% 55.1%

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Figure 9.  Time series of cross-section's estimated up- and down CAPM betas. mean corresponds to cross-sectional average beta, q5 to the 5% and q95 to the 95% quantile.
    Figure 10.  Visualization of Table 4: Densities of up- and down CAPM betas over the entire cross section and time series. Up-betas peak below 1, down-betas above. This is due to the fact that investors expect the cross-section to correlate higher for market down movements than for growth phases. Hence there is a larger risk exposure for the downside.

    Henceforth it gets obvious that there is a clear difference between expected up- and down betas. To put it in a nutshell, the empirical application demonstrates that the proposed model of correlation duality is straight forward to implement and gives some interesting insights to financial market's behavior.

    It is commonly known that equity correlations are typically higher during market down turns than for recovery times, which is not only documented in academic literature, but also frequently incorporated by investment practitioners for risk- and portfolio management purposes. Given this fact, this paper develops a model which allows to estimate expected up- and down correlations while relying purely on forward looking data (i.e., option implied volatilities). To the best of my knowledge, the method is first to be completely specified ex-ante and thus not affected by a backward looking bias, which allows to react faster to changes in the the current market situation. When validated on simulated data, the approach evolves to deliver reliable and unbiased estimates. Applied upon empirical data (S & P500, 2007–2018), several conclusions are derived. For example, expected down correlations are mainly higher than up correlations; the spread is on average 0.167. In greater detail, it is observed that this spread is time-varying and significantly dependent on current market mood: the worse, the greater the correlation spread. From this follows that stock diversification is expected to be more difficult when it is needed the most. By comparing estimated ex-ante up-/down correlations with the implied correlation surface I am able to confirm presumptions made in other studies, demonstrating that there is a theoretical as well as empirical link between them. To further highlight the practical relevance of a dual-correlation regime, empirical insights are provided that there is a substantial difference between expected up- and down CAPM betas. Additional potential practical implications of the implied correlation regime are for example at portfolio management, where one wants to control for down-side risk (e.g., value-at-risk) using such forward looking information. Another example could be in the context of policy research: implied volatility indices are highly affected by policy announcements (e.g., Rehman (2017), Shaikh (2019)), analyzing respective responses of implied up- and down-correlations is then likely to indicate how policy announcements affect changes in investor risk perceptions.

    Most of the research for this work has been conducted during the author's former affiliation with the University of Innsbruck, Austria.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Äijö J (2008) Implied volatility term structure linkages between VDAX, VSMI and VSTOXX volatility indices. Glob Fin J 18: 290-302. doi: 10.1016/j.gfj.2006.11.003
    [2] Ang A, Bekaert G (2015) International asset allocation with regime shifts. Rev Fin Stud 15: 1137-1187. doi: 10.1093/rfs/15.4.1137
    [3] Ang A, Chen J (2002) Asymmetric correlations of equity portfolios. J Fin Econ 63: 443-494. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(02)00068-5
    [4] Bakshi G, Kapadia N, Madan D (2003) Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the differential pricing of individual equity options. Rev Fin Stud 16: 101-143. doi: 10.1093/rfs/16.1.0101
    [5] Bali TG, Hu J, Murray S (2019) Option implied volatility, skewness, and kurtosis and the cross-section of expected stock returns. SSRN (accessed at Jul. 20, 2020).
    [6] Bertero E, Mayer C (1990) Structure and performance: global interdependence of stock markets around the crash of October 1987. Eur Econ Rev 34: 1155-1180. doi: 10.1016/0014-2921(90)90073-8
    [7] Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Pol Econ 81: 637-654. doi: 10.1086/260062
    [8] Buss A Vilkov G (2009) Option-implied correlation and factor betas revisited. SSRN (accessed at Jun. 9, 2020).
    [9] Buss A, Vilkov G (2012) Measuring equity risk with option-implied correlations. Rev Fin Stud 25: 3113- 3140. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhs087
    [10] Campbell JY, Vuolteenaho T (2004) Bad beta, good beta. Am Econ Rev 94: 1249-1275. doi: 10.1257/0002828043052240
    [11] Cappiello L, Engle RF, Sheppard K (2006) Asymmetric dynamics in the correlations of global equity and bond returns. J Fin Econometrics 4: 537-572. doi: 10.1093/jjfinec/nbl005
    [12] Carr P, Wu L (2006) A tale of two indices. J Deriv 13: 13-29. doi: 10.3905/jod.2006.616865
    [13] Carr P, Wu L (2009) Variance risk premiums. Rev Fin Stud 22: 1311-1341. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhn038
    [14] Chong J, Pfeiffer S, Phillips MG (2011) Can dual beta filtering improve investor performance. J Pers Fin 10: 63-86.
    [15] Chong J, Phillips MG (2013) Measuring risk for cost of capital: the downside beta approach. J Corp Treas Man 4: 344-352.
    [16] Driessen J, Maenhout PJ, Vilkov G (2013) Option-implied correlations and the price of correlation risk. Adv Risk Port Man, SSRN (accessed at Jun. 8, 2020).
    [17] Erb CB, Harvey CR, Viskanta TE (1994) Forecasting international equity correlations. Fin An J 50: 32- 45. doi: 10.2469/faj.v50.n6.32
    [18] Faff R (2001) A multivariate test of a dual-beta CAPM: australian evidence. Fin Rev 36: 157-174. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6288.2001.tb00034.x
    [19] Fassas AP, Kenourgios D, Papadamou S (2020) U.S. unconventional monetary policy and risk tolerance in major currency markets. Eur J Fin, 1-15. doi: 10.1080/1351847X.2020.1775105
    [20] Fassas AP, Papadamou S (2018) Variance risk premium and equity returns. Res Int Bus Fin 46: 462-470. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2018.06.003
    [21] Fassas A, Papadamou S, Philippas D (2020) Investors' risk aversion integration and quantitative easing. Rev Behav Fin 12: 170-183. doi: 10.1108/RBF-02-2019-0027
    [22] Guo G, Jacquier A, Martini C, et al. (2016) Generalized arbitrage-free SVI volatility surfaces. SIAM J Fin Math 7: 619-641. doi: 10.1137/120900320
    [23] Howton S, Peterson D (1999)A cross-sectional empirical test of a dual-state multi-factor pricing model. Fin Rev 34: 47-63. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6288.1999.tb00462.x
    [24] Jarrow R, Rudd A (1982) Approximate option valuation for arbitrary stochastic processes. J Fin Econ 10: 347-369. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(82)90007-1
    [25] Jeon B, Seo SW, Kim JS (2020) Uncertainty and the volatility forecasting power of option-implied volatility. J Fut Mark 40: 1109-1126. doi: 10.1002/fut.22116
    [26] Kaplanis EC (1988) Stability and forecasting of the comovement measures of international stock market returns. J Int Mon Fin 7: 63-75. doi: 10.1016/0261-5606(88)90006-X
    [27] King MA, Wadhwani S (1990) Transmission of volatility between stock markets. Rev Fin Stud 3: 5-33. doi: 10.1093/rfs/3.1.5
    [28] Kizys R, Pierdzioch C (2006) Business-cycle fluctuations and international equity correlations. Glob Fin J 17: 252-270. doi: 10.1016/j.gfj.2006.05.002
    [29] Linders D, Schoutens W (2014) A framework for robust measurement of implied correlation. J Comp App Math 271: 39-52. doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2014.03.026
    [30] Longerstaey J, Spencer M (1996) Riskmetrics-technical document. Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New York 51: 54.
    [31] Longin F, Solnik B (1995) Is the correlation in international equity returns constant: 1960-1990? J Int Mon Fin 14: 3-26. doi: 10.1016/0261-5606(94)00001-H
    [32] Longin F, Solnik B (2001) Extreme correlation of international equity markets. J Fin 56: 649-676. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00340
    [33] Mixon S (2010) What does implied volatility skew Mmeasure? J Deriv 18: 9-25. doi: 10.3905/jod.2010.18.1.009
    [34] Numpacharoen K, Numpacharoen N (2013) Estimating realistic implied correlation matrix from option prices. J Math Fin 3: 401-406. doi: 10.4236/jmf.2013.34041
    [35] Pettengill GN, Sundaram S, Mathur I (1995) The conditional relation between beta and returns. J Fin Quant An 30: 101-116. doi: 10.2307/2331255
    [36] Pettengill G, Sundaram S, Mathur I (2002) Payment for risk: constant beta vs. dual-beta models. Fin Rev 37: 123-135. doi: 10.1111/1540-6288.00008
    [37] Ramchand L, Susmel R (1998) Volatility and cross correlation across major stock markets. J Emp Fin 5: 397-416. doi: 10.1016/S0927-5398(98)00003-6
    [38] Ratner M (1992) Portfolio diversification and the inter-temporal stability of international stock indices. Glob Fin J 3: 67-77. doi: 10.1016/1044-0283(92)90005-6
    [39] Rehman MU (2017) Dynamics of co-movements among implied volatility, policy uncertainty and market performance. Glob Bus Rev 18: 1478-1487. doi: 10.1177/0972150917713060
    [40] Sancetta A, Satchell SE (2007) Changing correlation and equity portfolio diversification failure for linear factor models during market declines. App Math Fin 14: 227-242. doi: 10.1080/13504860600858279
    [41] Schadner W (2020a) An idea of risk neutral momentum and market fear. Fin Res Let 37: 101347. doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.101347
    [42] Schadner W (2020b) Ex-ante risk factors and required structures of the implied correlation matrix. Fin Res Let, 101855.
    [43] Schmalensee R, Trippi RR (1978) Common stock volatility expectations implied by option premia. J Fin 33: 129-147. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1978.tb03394.x
    [44] Schneider P, Wagner C, Zechner J (2020) Low-risk anomalies? J Fin 75: 2673-2718. doi: 10.1111/jofi.12910
    [45] Shaikh I (2019) On the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and the implied volatility index. Sustain 11: 1628. doi: 10.3390/su11061628
    [46] Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Fin 19: 425-442.
    [47] Skintzi V, Refenes APN (2005) Implied correlation index: a new measure of diversification. J Fut Mark 25: 171-197. doi: 10.1002/fut.20137
    [48] Walter CA, Lopez JA (2000) Is implied correlation worth calculating? J Deriv 7: 65-81. doi: 10.3905/jod.2000.319125
    [49] Zhang JE, Xiang Y (2008) The implied volatility smirk. Quant Fin 8: 263-284. doi: 10.1080/14697680601173444
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Lingxi Gao, Bochi Sun, Ziqing Du, Guangming Lv, How Wealth Inequality Affects Happiness: The Perspective of Social Comparison, 2022, 13, 1664-1078, 10.3389/fpsyg.2022.829707
    2. Wenhui Li, Qi Zhu, Fenghua Wen, Normaziah Mohd Nor, The evolution of day-of-the-week and the implications in crude oil market, 2022, 106, 01409883, 105817, 10.1016/j.eneco.2022.105817
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2021 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3649) PDF downloads(258) Cited by(2)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog