Processing math: 100%
Research article

A naive justification of hyperbolic discounting from mental algebraic operations and functional analysis

  • Received: 09 July 2023 Revised: 27 August 2023 Accepted: 08 September 2023 Published: 14 September 2023
  • JEL Codes: C02, D91, G40

  • Background 

    Intertemporal decision-making, which involves making choices between outcomes at different time points, is a fundamental aspect of human behavior. Understanding the underlying mental processes is vital for comprehending the complexities of human decision-making and choice behavior.

    Objective 

    The main objective of this study is to investigate the interplay of mental processes, specifically cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation, and comparison, in the context of intertemporal decision-making, with a specific focus on understanding the discounting process.

    Methodology 

    Development of a mathematical representation of the discounting process that incorporates the mental processes associated with intertemporal decision-making.

    Result 

    Our findings indicate that hyperbolic discounting aligns well with the cognitive processes underlying intertemporal decision-making. Subsequent research will employ qualitative questionnaires to establish the discount function relevant to specific groups, thereby enhancing our comprehension of the discounting process within intertemporal decision-making.

    Citation: Salvador Cruz Rambaud, Jorge Hernandez-Perez. A naive justification of hyperbolic discounting from mental algebraic operations and functional analysis[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(3): 463-474. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023023

    Related Papers:

    [1] Salvador Cruz Rambaud, Piedad Ortiz Fernández, Javier Sánchez García, Paula Ortega Perals . A proposal of concentration measures for discount functions. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 347-363. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024013
    [2] Shilong Li, Xia Zhao, Chuancun Yin, Zhiyue Huang . Stochastic interest model driven by compound Poisson process and Brownian motion with applications in life contingencies. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 246-260. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.246
    [3] Michael Stutzer . Style investing and the ICAPM. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 702-716. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.702
    [4] Juan Carlos Matallín-Sáez, Amparo Soler-Domínguez . Cost and performance of carbon risk in socially responsible mutual funds. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(1): 50-73. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023003
    [5] Firdos Karim, Sudipa Chauhan, Joydip Dhar . On the comparative analysis of linear and nonlinear business cycle model: Effect on system dynamics, economy and policy making in general. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 172-203. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020008
    [6] Kazuo Sano . New concept for the value function of prospect theory. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(4): 733-756. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024028
    [7] Filipe Sardo, Zélia Serrasqueiro . Intellectual capital and high-tech firms' financing choices in the European context: a panel data analysis. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(1): 1-18. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021001
    [8] Ramzi Drissi, Jamel Boukhatem . A nonlinear adjustment in real exchange rates under transaction costs hypothesis in developed and emerging countries. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 220-235. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020010
    [9] Rita Shakouri, Maziar Salahi, Sohrab Kordrostami . Stochastic p-robust approach to two-stage network DEA model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(2): 315-346. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.2.315
    [10] Gerasimos Rigatos, Pierluigi Siano, Taniya Ghosh, Deborah Sarno . A nonlinear optimal control approach to stabilization of a macroeconomic development model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(2): 373-387. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.2.373
  • Background 

    Intertemporal decision-making, which involves making choices between outcomes at different time points, is a fundamental aspect of human behavior. Understanding the underlying mental processes is vital for comprehending the complexities of human decision-making and choice behavior.

    Objective 

    The main objective of this study is to investigate the interplay of mental processes, specifically cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation, and comparison, in the context of intertemporal decision-making, with a specific focus on understanding the discounting process.

    Methodology 

    Development of a mathematical representation of the discounting process that incorporates the mental processes associated with intertemporal decision-making.

    Result 

    Our findings indicate that hyperbolic discounting aligns well with the cognitive processes underlying intertemporal decision-making. Subsequent research will employ qualitative questionnaires to establish the discount function relevant to specific groups, thereby enhancing our comprehension of the discounting process within intertemporal decision-making.



    Intertemporal decision-making, the process of making choices between outcomes occurring at different points in time, is a fundamental aspect of human behavior (Ainslie, 1975; Green and Myerson, 2004). For instance, Cadena and Keys (2015) point out that discounting also plays a very important role in the domain of education. In effect, usually impatient people make dynamically inconsistent decisions such as starting an educational program but failing to complete it or dropping out of college. In the same vein, Golsteyn et al. (2013) show a significant negative relationship between high discount rates and school performance, health, labor supply, and lifetime income. Specifically, males and high ability children gain significantly more from being future-oriented. Analogously, Backes-Gellner et al. (2018) show that a low degree of long-term patience is a key determinant of dropping out of upper-secondary school. Finally, one month before termination of their programs, loos averse students are more likely to have a definite job offer. This is because, usually, individuals face some situations where they must weigh the costs and benefits of immediate versus delayed rewards. Understanding the mental processes underlying intertemporal decision-making is essential for unraveling the complexities of human choice behavior.

    This article aims to explore the interplay of mental processes, namely cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation, and comparison, involved in intertemporal decision-making, with a particular focus on the discounting process. Cognitive evaluation refers to the initial assessment of the attributes, features, and characteristics of the rewards under consideration (Loewenstein and Prelec, 1992). Subsequently, subjective valuation occurs when individuals assign subjective values to the rewards based on their personal preferences, goals, and priorities (Loewenstein, 1996; Lempert et al., 2016; Friedel et al., 2014). Furthermore, individuals engage in a comparison process to determine the equivalence of the rewards (Malkoc and Zauberman, 2006; Zauberman et al., 2009a; Franco-Watkins et al., 2016).

    The discounting process is a crucial component of intertemporal decision-making, involving the mental devaluation or discounting of future rewards relative to immediate rewards. Two types of discounting functions have been formulated: exponential and hyperbolic discounting. These functions play a critical role in shaping decision-making behavior and have implications for various domains, including financial decisions (Cruz Rambaud, 2014; Muñoz et al., 2018), health-related choices (Scharff, 2009; Cheung et al., 2022), and self-control (Bickel et al., 2008; Steward et al., 2017).

    Recent research suggests that the hyperbolic discounting function better captures the mental processes involved in intertemporal choices compared to exponential discounting. The hyperbolic function accounts for the tendency of individuals to heavily discount immediate rewards in favor of delayed rewards, with the discount rate decreasing as the delay increases (Berns et al., 2007). This finding supports a growing body of evidence favoring hyperbolic discounting as a more accurate representation of human decision-making behavior.

    This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a comprehensive review of the existing literature on the mental and discounting processes involved in intertemporal decisions. In Section 3, specifically Subsection 3.1, the development of the subjective discount rate is described. Subsection 3.2 focuses on the mental algebraic operations used to determine the discounted amount equivalent to a future reward in an intertemporal choice, leading to the derivation of the mathematical expression of the discounting process based on the assumptions presented in Section 2, which supports the concept of hyperbolic discounting. Section 4 derives the hyperbolic discount function using functional analysis. Finally, Section 5 provides a summary and concluding remarks.

    When an individual is faced an intertemporal choice and needs to determine the reward equivalent to another one, several mental processes come into play. These mental processes involve cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation, and comparison (Frederick et al., 2002; Loewenstein, 1988).

    Initially, the individual engages in cognitive evaluation, which implies assessing the attributes, features, and characteristics of the rewards under consideration (Loewenstein and Prelec, 1992). This evaluation may include factors such as the magnitude or size of the rewards, and the timing or delay associated with each reward which influence the decision-making process (Malkoc and Zauberman, 2019).

    A set of psychological processes may be involved in the process of evaluating the magnitude and time of rewards such as temporal framing (deferral or expedite) (Loewenstein, 1988; Malkoc and Zauberman, 2006), attentional processing (Franco-Watkins et al., 2016; Malkoc et al., 2010), perception of time (Kim and Zauberman, 2009; Zauberman et al., 2009a), or retrieval of memories (Zauberman et al., 2009b).

    After that, subjective valuation occurs when the individual assigns a subjective value or importance to each reward based on their personal preferences, goals, and priorities. This valuation process is influenced by various psychological factors, such as emotions (Loewenstein, 1996; Lempert et al., 2016), or past experiences (Harris, 2012), and individual differences (Keidel et al., 2021) such as impulsivity (Friedel et al., 2014; Moreira and Barbosa, 2019; Liu et al., 2022) in decision-making tendencies.

    Finally, the individual engages in a comparison process, where they mentally weigh and compare the rewards against each other to determine their equivalence. This comparison may involve evaluating the trade-offs between immediate gratification and delayed rewards (Malkoc and Zauberman, 2006), considering the potential benefits and drawbacks of each option (Zauberman et al., 2009a), and weighing the perceived value of the rewards over time (Franco-Watkins et al., 2016). Bias may affect this process, such as loss aversion (Tversky and Kahneman, 1991) and relative risk aversion (Dyer and Sarin, 1982).

    The process of discounting refers to the tendency of individuals to devalue or discount future rewards relative to immediate rewards. This process involves the evaluation of the subjective value of rewards over time giving rise to different mathematical models to describe discounting. However, the main objective of this paper is to describe the underlying process leading to the temporal devaluation of rewards.

    One model used to describe the process of discounting is exponential discounting, which assumes a constant rate of discounting over time. According to this model, the value of a future reward is discounted exponentially as a function of its delay (Frederick et al., 2002). However, the exponential discounting assumes that people have a fixed time horizon beyond which they do not discount the value of rewards, which is inconsistent with real-life behavior (Laibson, 1997).

    Another widely used model is hyperbolic discounting, which suggests that the subjective value of a delayed reward decreases more rapidly in the short-term compared to the long-term (Ainslie, 1975). This process leads to impulsive decision-making behavior, where individuals prioritize immediate rewards over delayed ones.

    A new model called "arithmetic discounting" has been used used to explain the process of discounting. This model is a specific instance of Killeen's model (2009). The analogy of the excess wages needed for waiting, rather than analogies of simple (hyperbolic discounting) or compound interest (exponential discounting), underpins the underlying behavioral model (Doyle and Chen, 2010).

    Whilst the arithmetic model is simpler to calculate than the hyperbolic or exponential model, hyperbolic discounting has been found to provide a more accurate description of real-life decision-making behaviors. This is due to its ability to account for the observation that individuals discount the value of future rewards more heavily as the time to receipt approaches (Mazur, 1987; Green and Myerson, 2004).

    Moreover, hyperbolic discounting has been found to have evolutionary advantages over exponential discounting (Kable and Glimcher, 2007). It has been argued that hyperbolic discounting may have evolved as an adaptation to decision-making in a changing environment, where immediate rewards are more certain and long-term rewards are more uncertain (Stevens and Stephens, 2010). This is consistent with the idea that hyperbolic discounting may be a more accurate model for explaining decision-making behaviors in real-life situations than exponential discounting (Cruz Rambaud, 2014).

    In addition, hyperbolic discounting has been shown to better explain choices related to health behaviors, such as smoking and exercise (Chapman and Weber, 2006). Similarly, hyperbolic discounting has been found to be a better predictor of impulsive consuming behaviors compared to exponential discounting (Zauberman et al., 2009b). These findings suggest that hyperbolic discounting may provide a more accurate model for predicting and understanding intertemporal decision-making phenomena in real-life situations. However, hyperbolic discounting may be influenced by social and cultural factors, which may vary across different populations (Muñoz et al., 2018).

    The process of discounting is influenced by various factors, including cognitive, affective, and situational factors. Therefore, the discounting process is closely intertwined with the cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation, and comparison of different rewards in the context of intertemporal decisions (see Figure 1).

    Figure 1.  A diagram of intertemporal decisions.

    Within the cognitive evaluation process, mental discounting occurs as individuals mentally weigh the value of immediate rewards against delayed rewards. They assess how the delay to receive a reward affects its perceived value and the trade-offs between immediate gratification and delayed but potentially larger rewards.

    For example, mental processes such as mental representation and framing play a role in discounting. Malkoc and Zauberman (2006) propose that the temporal frame and mental concreteness of an intertemporal choice can explain individuals' discounting rates. The way individuals mentally represent and frame the options affects their valuation and decision-making. Attentional processing also participates in discounting process. Franco-Watkins et al. (2016) conclude that individuals with attentional biases towards immediate rewards are more likely to exhibit present-biased preferences and choose immediate rewards over delayed rewards. Additionally, perception of time is involved in discounting process. Individuals tend to discount the value of delayed rewards more steeply when there is a greater discrepancy between their subjective perception of time and the objective duration of the rewards (Kim et al., 2009). Additionally, memories, as valuable assets, participate in discounting. Zauberman et al. (2009b) suggest that the discounting process in intertemporal decision-making is influenced by individuals' strategic use of memories. By leveraging positive memories, individuals can attenuate the negative impact of temporal discounting and make more patient choices that align with their long-term goals. Additionally, language has a role in the process of discounting. According to Chen (2013), languages requiring future-time reference cause their speakers to process future-oriented decisions differently than speakers of languages requiring present-time reference. This was confirmed by Sutter et al. (2015; 2018) and Herz et al. (2021) after controlling for cultural variables.

    The discounting process is an integral part of subjective valuation as individuals assign different values to immediate and delayed rewards. The discounting process involves devaluing the subjective worth of delayed rewards compared to immediate rewards due to factors like time preference, uncertainty, and impatience. For example, Loewenstein (1996) highlights the role of emotions in discounting, suggesting that individuals may have a positively-valenced arousal response toward immediate rewards compared to delayed ones. In the other hand, impulsivity, as a trait associated with impulsive decision-making, also influences the discounting process in different context such as smoking. In effect, smokers demonstrate higher levels of impulsivity compared to non-smokers. Furthermore, smokers exhibit steeper discounting of both monetary rewards and consumable outcomes (e.g., cigarettes) compared to non-smokers (Friedel et al., 2014).

    In the process of comparing different rewards, mental discounting comes into play. Individuals consider the temporal aspects, such as the delay to receive a reward, and apply discounting functions or mental heuristics to adjust the perceived value of rewards based on their temporal distance. This comparison helps individuals make trade-offs between immediate rewards and delayed rewards. However, bias may influence this process, such as through loss aversion (Tversky and Kahneman, 1991) and relative risk aversion (Dyer and Sarin, 1982). Whilst individuals tend to prefer avoiding losses rather than acquiring equivalent gains (loss aversion), the subjective value of a gain or loss decreases as the size of the gain or loss increases in the comparison process. In uncertain situations, people tend to decrease their risk tolerance as their wealth increases (relative risk aversion). Consequently, individuals with greater risk aversion are more reluctant to undertake risky ventures, even if they have the potential for significant gains.

    Most experiments are designed as follows. An individual is asked about the amount equivalent today to another reward available at a future time. The individual assesses the attributes, features, and characteristics of the rewards under consideration. After that, the individual assigns a subjective value or importance to reward based on their personal preferences, goals, and priorities. Based on both processes (cognitive evaluation and subjective valuation), the individual determines a fixed discount percentage r (see Figure 1).

    First assumption. In the comparison process, the subject tends to use elemental algebraic operations (sums, subtractions, multiplications and divisions) only. More specifically, her mental discounting process will be to subtract r from the initial reward (see Figure 1). Thus, if the initial delayed reward is A, the successive discounted amounts are shown in Table 1.

    Table 1.  First arithmetic operations done by a decision maker.
    Delay Initial amount Discounted amount
    1 A ArA
    2 A A2rA
    3 A A3rA

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Therefore, for the sake of simplicity, if the initial reward is A=fanxiexianmyfh1 at time t, the discounted amount will be the subjective discount function, ˜F(t). Thus, under this assumption, ˜F(t) will be linear discounting:

    ˜F(t)=1rt. (1)

    Nevertheless, despite this initial assumption is logical, the subject has to slightly correct her first assumption in the following way.

    Second assumption. The subject realizes that, after a certain number of the experiment replications, the chosen reward can reach the value 0 and even negative records. Thus, she proposes the following expression for the subjective discount function:

    ˜F(t)=1r(t)t, (2)

    where r(t) is decreasing and r(1)=r is the initial percentage chosen by the decision maker. Observe that this requirement is in line with Harvey(1986, 1994). In effect, Harvey (1992) states: "We have in mind any method with positive discount rates that decrease and tend to zero as time tends to infinity. Such a method will be called slow discounting. We will not argue that people should have values in accord with slow discounting. Rather, we will argue that if people do have such values, then a slow discounting model can be reasonable and insightful as part of a public policy study".

    Third assumption. Taking into account Equation (2), although r(t) is decreasing, r(t)t must be increasing as it represents the discount of fanxiexian_myfh1 and this amount must be increasing with t.

    Fourth assumption. The discounted amount must vanish at infinity. Therefore, the following identity holds:

    limt+[r(t)t]=1. (3)

    This is the most difficult question to be checked because the involved time is infinity. However, in Subsection 3.3, we will show that this is a necessary and sufficient condition to derive a discounting model with a single parameter, similarly to constant discounting. This feature is relevant in Harvey (1994) when defining the so-called proportional discounting, improving the tractability of the model.

    A summary of the assumptions is the following:

    1. ˜F(t)=1r(t)t.

    2. r(t) is decreasing.

    3. r(0)<+.

    4. r(1)=r.

    5. limt+[r(t)t]=1.

    As indicated in Section 2, it is assumed that the subject is only willing to do elemental algebraic operations. Therefore, she must start from the expression of the type r(t)=ab+ct which, as formerly indicated, only includes elemental operations. Thus, the requirements #4 and #5 proposed in Section 2 lead to the following equations:

    ab+c=r.

    a=c.

    Observe that a=c becomes r(t) an expression depending on a single parameter, as formerly indicated in the proportional discounting (Harvey, 1994): r(t)=1m+t where m=ba. Consequently,

    r(t)=r(1r)+rt (4)

    and

    ˜F(t)=1r(1r)+rtt=11+it, (5)

    where i=r1r, which is the well-known expression of the hyperbolic discounting.

    Traditionally, the paradigm of discounting models has been the exponential discount function. The use of this model has been justified from different points of view. One of them has been that the exponential function is the solution of the functional equation:

    F(r)F(s)=F(r+s). (6)

    The idea underlying to this functional equation is that the individual uses the same rate independently of the instant at which she chooses the equivalent reward. Based on this approach, we can think about a discounting model which successively applies a lesser interest rate. In effect, let us consider a generic interval [r,r+s], where r>0 is variable and s>0 is fixed. If decreasing impatience (or, equivalently, increasing patience) holds, then the financial factor in the interval [r,r+s]

    F(r+s)F(r)

    must be increasing with respect to r (Cruz Rambaud and Muñoz Torrecillas, 2016). Indeed, an easy way to propose a function of r and s, increasing with respect to r, is

    F(sF(r)),

    from which:

    F(r+s)F(r)=F(sF(r)),

    giving rise to the following functional equation:

    F(r)F(sF(r))=F(r+s). (7)

    It can be shown that the solution of Equation (7) is (Aczél, 1987):

    F(t)=11+αt, α>0, (8)

    which is the well-known hyperbolic discounting model.

    Finally, an immediate generalization of Equation (7) is:

    [F(r]k[F(s[F(r)]k)]k=[F(r+s)]k,k>0, (9)

    whose solution is (Aczél, 1987):

    [F(t)]k=11+αt, α>0, (10)

    which is the well-known generalized hyperbolic discount:

    F(t)=1(1+αt)s, α>0,s>0. (11)

    The objective of this paper has been to identify the three stages of mental processes in intertemporal choice environments. In effect, these phases (cognitive evaluation, subjective valuation and comparison) have been concreted in a series of logical rules which individuals use to determine the discounting of a delayed reward. As a result, we have found that the hyperbolic discounting better fits the mental processes involved in intertemporal choices. This reinforces the wide set of arguments in favor of hyperbolic instead of exponential discounting.

    This objective has been also treated by transforming the thoughts of individual about discounting into a functional equation whose solution aldo leads to hyperbolic discounting.

    As a future research line, our aim is to administer suitable questionnaires in order to determine the discount function to be applied by a group of individuals. Specifically, our aim is to convert the traditional quantitative experiments into a qualitative questionnaire able to elucidate the four assumptions discussed in Section 2. In effect, most experiments deduce the concrete expression of a discount function asking for a significant number of amounts equivalent to another constant reward at different dates. This methodology presents a noteworthy inconvenience: the only meditated answer could be the corresponding to the first questions, and the rest of answers can be "the first thing that comes into her head". In this way, our proposal is to find a set of tendencies and mental processes of the group, and then to deduce the mathematical expression of the function that better fits the intertemporal choices.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    We would like to thank the financial support from the Mediterranean Research Center for Economics and Sustainable Development (CIMEDES).

    All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Aczél J (1987) A Short Course on Functional Equations, Dordrecht: D. Reidel.
    [2] Ainslie G (1975) Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. Psychol Bull 82: 463–496. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0076860 doi: 10.1037/h0076860
    [3] Backes-Gellner U, Herz H, Kosfeld M, et al. (2018) Do preferences and biases predict life outcomes? Evidence from education and labor market entry decisions. Eur Econ Rev 134: 103709. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2021.103709 doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2021.103709
    [4] Berns GS, Laibson D, Loewenstein G (2007) Intertemporal choice - toward an integrative framework. Trends Cogn Sci 11: 482–488. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2007.08.011 doi: 10.1016/j.tics.2007.08.011
    [5] Bickel WK, Yi R, Kowal BP, et al. (2008) Cigarette smokers discount past and future rewards symmetrically and more than controls: Is discounting a measure of impulsivity? Drug Alcohol Depen 96: 256–262. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.drugalcdep.2008.03.009 doi: 10.1016/j.drugalcdep.2008.03.009
    [6] Cadena BC, Keys BJ (2015) Human capital and the lifetime costs of impatience. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7: 126–153. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20130081 doi: 10.1257/pol.20130081
    [7] Chapman GB, Weber BJ (2006) Decision biases in intertemporal choice and choice under uncertainty: Testing a common account. Mem Cognition 34: 589–602. https://doi.org/10.3758/BF03193582 doi: 10.3758/BF03193582
    [8] Cheung SL, Tymula A, Wang X (2022) Present bias for monetary and dietary rewards. Exp Econ 25: 1202–1233. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09749-8 doi: 10.1007/s10683-022-09749-8
    [9] Cruz Rambaud S (2014) A new argument in favor of hyperbolic discounting in very long term project appraisal. Int J Theor Appl Financ 17: 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219024914500496 doi: 10.1142/S0219024914500496
    [10] Cruz Rambaud S, Muñoz Torrecillas MJ (2016) Measuring impatience in intertemporal choice. PLoS ONE 11: e0149256. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0149256 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0149256
    [11] Doyle J, Chen CH (2010) Time is money: Arithmetic discounting outperforms hyperbolic and exponential discounting. Available from: SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract = 1609594 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1609594.
    [12] Dyer JS, Sarin RK (1982) Relative risk aversion. Manage Sci 28: 875–886. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.28.8.875 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.28.8.875
    [13] Franco-Watkins AM, Mattson RE, Jackson MD (2016) Now or later? Attentional processing and intertemporal choice. J Behav Decis Making 29: 206–217. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.1895 doi: 10.1002/bdm.1895
    [14] Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O'Donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. J Econ Lit 40: 351–401. https://doi.org/10.1257/002205102320161311 doi: 10.1257/002205102320161311
    [15] Friedel JE, DeHart WB, Madden GJ, et al. (2014) Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: Discounting of monetary and consumable outcomes in current and non-smokers. Psychopharmacology 231: 4517–4526. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00213-014-3597-z doi: 10.1007/s00213-014-3597-z
    [16] Green L, Myerson J (2004) A discounting framework for choice with delayed and probabilistic rewards. Psychol Bull 130: 769–792. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.130.5.769 doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.130.5.769
    [17] Golsteyn BHH, Grönqvist H, Lindahl L (2013) Time preferences and lifetime outcomes. IZA Discussion Papers 7165, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2210825
    [18] Harris CR (2012) Feelings of dread and intertemporal choice. J Behav Decis Making 25: 13–28. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.709 doi: 10.1002/bdm.709
    [19] Harvey CM (1986) Value functions for infinite-period planning. Manage Sci 32: 1123–1139. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.32.9.1123 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.32.9.1123
    [20] Harvey CM (1994) The reasonableness of non-constant discounting. J Public Econ 53: 31–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(94)90012-4 doi: 10.1016/0047-2727(94)90012-4
    [21] Herz H, Huber M, Maillard-Bjedov T, et al. (2021) Time preferences across language groups: Evidence on intertemporal choices from the Swiss language border. Econ J 131: 2920–2954. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueab025 doi: 10.1093/ej/ueab025
    [22] Kable JW, Glimcher PW (2007) The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice. Nat Neurosci 10: 1625–1633. https://doi.org/10.1038/nn2007 doi: 10.1038/nn2007
    [23] Keidel K, Rramani Q, Weber B, et al. (2021) Individual differences in intertemporal choice. Front Psychol 12: 643670. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2021.643670 doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2021.643670
    [24] Killeen PR (2009) An additive-utility model of delay discounting. Psychol Rev 116: 602–619. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0016414 doi: 10.1037/a0016414
    [25] Kim BK, Zauberman G (2009) Perception of anticipatory time in temporal discounting. J Neurosci Psychol E 2: 91–101. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0017686 doi: 10.1037/a0017686
    [26] Laibson D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ 112: 443–478. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555253 doi: 10.1162/003355397555253
    [27] Lempert KM, Johnson E, Phelps EA (2016) Emotional arousal predicts intertemporal choice. Emotion 16: 647–656. https://doi.org/10.1037/emo0000168 doi: 10.1037/emo0000168
    [28] Liu X, Turel O, Xiao Z, et al. (2022) Impulsivity and neural mechanisms that mediate preference for immediate food rewards in people with vs without excess weight. Appetite 169: 105798. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.appet.2021.105798 doi: 10.1016/j.appet.2021.105798
    [29] Loewenstein G (1988) Frames of mind in intertemporal choice. Manage Sci 34: 200–214. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.34.2.200 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.34.2.200
    [30] Loewenstein G (1996) Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organ Behav Hu Dec 65: 272–292. https://doi.org/10.1006/obhd.1996.0028 doi: 10.1006/obhd.1996.0028
    [31] Loewenstein G, Prelec D (1992) Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Q J Econ 107: 573–597. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118482 doi: 10.2307/2118482
    [32] Malkoc SA, Zauberman G (2006) Deferring versus expediting consumption: The effect of outcome concreteness on sensitivity to time horizon J Marketing Res XLIII: 618–627. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.43.4.618
    [33] Malkoc SA, Zauberman G (2019) Psychological analysis of consumer intertemporal decisions. Consum Psychol Rev 2: 97–113. https://doi.org/10.1002/arcp.1048 doi: 10.1002/arcp.1048
    [34] Malkoc SA, Zauberman G, Bettman JR (2010) Unstuck from the concrete! Carryover effect of abstract mindsets in intertemporal preferences. Organ Behav Hu Dec 113: 112–126. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2010.07.003 doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2010.07.003
    [35] Mazur JE (1987) An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement, In: Commons ML, Mazur JE, Nevin JA, Rachlin H (Eds.) Quantitative Analyses of Behavior, The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates: Hillsdale, NJ, 5: 55–73.
    [36] Moreira D, Barbosa F (2019) Delay Discounting in Impulsive Behavior: A systematic review. Eur Psychol 24: 312–-321. https://doi.org/10.1027/1016-9040/a000360 doi: 10.1027/1016-9040/a000360
    [37] Muñoz Torrecillas MJ, Takahashi T, Gil Roales-Nieto J, et al. (2018) Impatience and inconsistency in intertemporal choice: An experimental analysis. J Behav Financ 19: 190–198. https://doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2017.1374274 doi: 10.1080/15427560.2017.1374274
    [38] Scharff RL (2009) Obesity and hyperbolic discounting: Evidence and implications. J Consumer Policy 32: 3–21. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-009-9090-0 doi: 10.1007/s10603-009-9090-0
    [39] Stevens JR, Stephens DW (2010) The adaptive nature of impulsivity. In: Madden GJ, Bickel WK (Eds.), Impulsivity: The behavioral and neurological science of discounting, American Psychological Association, 361—387. https://doi.org/10.1037/12069-013
    [40] Steward T, Mestre-Bach G, Fernández-Aranda F, et al. (2017) Delay discounting and impulsivity traits in young and older gambling disorder patients. Addict Behav 71: 96–103. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.addbeh.2017.03.001 doi: 10.1016/j.addbeh.2017.03.001
    [41] Sutter M, Angerer S, Glätzle-Rützler D, et al.(2015) The effect of language on economic behavior: Experimental evidence from children's intertemporal choices. CESifo Working Paper Series, 5532. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2681024
    [42] Sutter M, Angerer S, Glätzle-Rützler D, et al. (2018) Language group differences in time preferences: Evidence from primary school children in a bilingual city. Eur Econ Rev 106: 21–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2018.04.003 doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2018.04.003
    [43] Tversky A, Kahneman D (1991) Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. Q J Econ 106: 1039–1061. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937956 doi: 10.2307/2937956
    [44] Zauberman G, Kim BK, Malkoc SA, et al. (2009) Discounting time and time discounting: Subjective time perception and intertemporal preferences. J Marketing Res 46: 543–556. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.46.4.543 doi: 10.1509/jmkr.46.4.543
    [45] Zauberman G, Ratner RK, Kim BK (2009) Memories as assets: Strategic memory protection in choice over time. J Consumer Res 35: 715–728. https://doi.org/10.1086/592943 doi: 10.1086/592943
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Kun Liu, Chunming Tang, Privacy-preserving Naive Bayes classification based on secure two-party computation, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 28517, 10.3934/math.20231459
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1569) PDF downloads(96) Cited by(1)

Figures and Tables

Figures(1)  /  Tables(1)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog