Research article

The inequality-credit linkage

  • Received: 15 October 2024 Revised: 28 February 2025 Accepted: 31 March 2025 Published: 08 April 2025
  • JEL Codes: G21, D63, G01, E52

  • In this paper, I analyzed the underlying mechanisms of the interaction between credit expansion and income inequality—inequality-credit interaction—and its influence on the economy. For this purpose, System and Difference GMM models were applied to assess the influence of the interaction on the triggering of banking crises 212 economies between 1970 and 2017. Furthermore, a Granger-Causality panel data test was applied, employing a maximum sample size of 216 world countries for the 1960–2021 period and balanced subsamples. The interaction was negatively related with risk of unchaining banking crises and led to economic growth. Robustness checks were applied, confirming the results.

    Citation: Guillermo Peña. The inequality-credit linkage[J]. National Accounting Review, 2025, 7(2): 143-176. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2025007

    Related Papers:

    [1] Hua Zhong, Zijian Feng, Zifan Wang, Yougui Wang . Revisiting the monetary transmission mechanism via banking from the perspective of credit creation. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 116-147. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024006
    [2] Guillermo Peña . VAT experience as an influence on banking crises. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 53-65. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020003
    [3] Joana Cobbinah, Tan Zhongming, Albert Henry Ntarmah . Banking competition and stability: evidence from West Africa. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(3): 263-284. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020015
    [4] Van Hoa Tran, Quang Thao Pham . Growth and poverty reduction in Vietnam: A strategic policy modelling study. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(3): 449-464. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024020
    [5] Shengyin Ouyang, Ziqing Du, Meiling Cai . Statistical measurement of the impact of monetary policy on price levels. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 188-203. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020011
    [6] Miguel Á. Martínez-García, Ángeles Cámara . How the 2008 financial crisis affected the Spanish economy due to household income. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(4): 465-479. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024021
    [7] Giorgio Colacchio, Anna Serena Vergori . GDP growth rate, tourism expansion and labor market dynamics: Applied research focused on the Italian economy. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 310-328. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022018
    [8] Jawad Saleemi . COVID-19 and liquidity risk, exploring the relationship dynamics between liquidity cost and stock market returns. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(2): 218-236. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021011
    [9] Mahinur Begum Mimi, Md. Ahasan Ul Haque, Md. Golam Kibria . Does human capital investment influence unemployment rate in Bangladesh: a fresh analysis. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 273-286. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022016
    [10] Serhii Shvets . Public investment as a growth driver for a commodity-exporting economy: Sizing up the fiscal-monetary involvement. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 95-115. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024005
  • In this paper, I analyzed the underlying mechanisms of the interaction between credit expansion and income inequality—inequality-credit interaction—and its influence on the economy. For this purpose, System and Difference GMM models were applied to assess the influence of the interaction on the triggering of banking crises 212 economies between 1970 and 2017. Furthermore, a Granger-Causality panel data test was applied, employing a maximum sample size of 216 world countries for the 1960–2021 period and balanced subsamples. The interaction was negatively related with risk of unchaining banking crises and led to economic growth. Robustness checks were applied, confirming the results.



    Abbreviations: GMM: Generalized Method of Moments; SYS: System; DIF: Differences; GDP: Gross Domestic Product; VCEs: Two-step variance-covariance matrix estimators; ATMs: Automatic Teller Machines; ECA: Europe and Central Asia

    The interest on the analysis of the association of income inequality with the development of the financial sector has increased in recent years, especially since the unchaining of the Great Recession and even more after a relatively long period of high inflation exceeded the most adverse economic impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic. Thus, the reason may be the widening of income inequality for most developed and developing economies. In this paper, I deal with the question about how the inequality-credit interaction influences the risk of triggering banking crises. Many researchers have analyzed this interaction (of, inter alia, Galor and Zeira 1993, Benabou 2000; Easterly 2007; Kavya and Shijin, 2020) and the relationships between the inequality of income and different measures of the development of the financial sector, and most have studied its correlation with the growth rates of the economies. Thus, the question of how this link influences economic activity is a subject of much debate. For instance, Braun et al. (2019) studied the influence of the interaction between inequality and credit on economic growth. However, to my knowledge, there is a lack of research that involves empirically testing the effects on banking crises of the explicit interaction between credit expansions and income inequality (inequality-credit linkage), and I contribute to this topic by filling the gap. Therefore, the key new contribution of this paper is adapting the empirical exercise of Braun et al. (2019) to banking crises instead of economic growth. This is done by employing dynamic panel data models. Furthermore, another novelty is the completion of the results of the other authors who made on income inequality by adding a new result by studying the Granger-causality of the above-mentioned inequality-credit linkage on per capita income. Finally, the third main contribution, in contrast to other papers, such as Fischer et al. (2019) Chang et al. (2020), and Magwedere (2023), is the proposal of a new theoretical framework where the influence of the linkage on the likelihood of a banking crisis can be observed. This is also used for discussing the empirical results.

    Empirical results are developed for the above purpose. A model is estimated explaining the risk of banking crises by inequality–credit interaction and controlling by the major determinants of the literature for the 212 worldwide countries in the 1970–2017 period, according to the widest available data of banking crises. The analysis is performed using System and Difference panel data models of Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) since the former models are strongly advised for the high degree of persistence in the explained variable and the avoidance of endogeneity (Roodman, 2009), and the last models are employed as a robustness check. There is no need to focus on potential endogenous variables, since, as Ullah et al. (2018) state, the two-step System GMM (employed in this paper) "relies on internal instruments (lagged values, internal transformation) to address the different sources of endogeneity" (p.4). Two additional robustness checks are performed: Providing different specifications of the inequality and credit variables and incorporating a temporal dummy that includes the five immediate years before the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) that occurred on 2007–2009, so 2002–2006, denominated the "lax period", including two economic and geographical dummy variables.

    A significant and beneficial negative effect of the interaction—measured as a combination, i.e., the product of both variables—on the probability of unchaining banking crises is found, smoothing an individual positive influence on the banking crisis of income inequality (Mo, 2000) and financial development (Cecchetti and Kharroubi, 2021), separately. The interaction negatively alleviates the individual effect on the risk of triggering banking crises; therefore, a beneficial-collateral consequence of the raise in the inequality of income and development of the financial institutions emerges. On the other hand, if policy-makers seek to reduce income inequality and a possible excessive size of the financial sector, this interaction would collaborate on triggering banking crises. These results are also consistent with theoretical expectations. To my knowledge, nobody has directly studied the joint-interacted-impact of credit booms and income inequality on banking activity. Last, it is checked that the interaction leads to Gross Domestic Product per capita (GDPpc) by employing a novel technique of Granger Causality for panel datasets, found by the econometricians Juodis et al. (2021). Additionally, a robustness check is provided where a country-by-country test is applied to different measures of the nexus.

    Therefore, I seek to shed further light on the inequality-credit interaction. This paper is divided as follows. In Sections 2 and 3, I show a brief literature review of the inequality-credit interaction and the determinants of the crises in the banking sector, jointly with theoretical expectations of the effects of the interaction on the of banking crisis triggering. In Section 4, I explain the data and methodology applied in this paper and expose the econometric results and checks of robustness. Finally, in Section 5, I discuss results and provide some policy measures as well as concluding remarks.

    Much debate has arisen about the linkage between the development of the financial system and economic inequality measured by income, and overall, its relation with economic activity, such as the Braun's et al. (2019) paper. If we focus on whether income inequality slows or accelerates economic growth, there are arguments for both directions at the theoretical level. While there is a tradition in modeling saving rates as a function positively correlated with wealth, leading to a positive relationship (Bourguignon, 1981; Kaldor, 1957; Keynes, 1919; Lewis, 1954; Smith, 1776), other researchers consider loan restrictions in investment on human capital lead to a link through which income equality would improve the growth of GDP (Benabou 2000; Galor and Zeira 1993). At the empirical level, there is neither consensus. On the one side, several studies support a negative association between the inequality of income and economic growth variables (Alesina and Rodrick 1994; Easterly 2007; Panizza 2002). On the other side, other authors suggest a positive effect (Forbes, 2000; Li and Zou, 1998).

    Regarding the previous expected linear influences, it is worth mentioning that Kuznets (1955) suggested an inverted "U" shape linkage between the development of the economies and inequality of income, since inequality seemed to be positively correlated with development but until a maximum, and the relationship would become negative. Tan and Law (2012) empirically observed a U-shape relationship in the inequality–credit nexus. In fact, there is literature suggesting the nonlinearity in the relation inequality-growth (Barro, 2000; Castelló-Climent, 2010; Kim and Lin, 2011 and Brueckner and Lederman, 2015, Kavya and Shijin, 2020, Ghosh et al., 2022). Kruger (2008) reviewed the literature in which high inequality might not be good for an economy. On the other hand, there are arguments for a positive and a negative correlation of the development of the financial sector variable with the inequality one. The key is the way in which the increase of financial services provided by an expansion of financial development may benefit low-income households.

    Among the literature of the association of the interaction with growth, Braun et al. (2019) is the closest one to this paper, since they have the same target variables (credit, income inequality, and the interaction) but on a different dependent variable; economic growth instead of the banking crisis probability in this paper. They show the theoretical expectations by an analytical model and empirically analyze the expectations by estimating System GMM models with those variables and controlled by other factors. They obtain that several of the prejudicial influences of income inequality over economic growth may be reduced by enhancing access and entry to loans.

    The previous expectations for economic growth can be easily adapted for banking crises. As will be seen later, our results on banking crises will be similar to those on reducing economic growth but for the case of triggering these crises (opposite sign). Other researchers have dealt with the topic of the influence of income inequality and financial development on triggering banking crises. Nonetheless, this interaction has never, to my knowledge, directly considered the interacted effects of both variables on banking crises as Braun et al. (2019) performed for growth of income as a dependent variable.

    According to authors, such as as Büyükkarabacak and Valev (2010), private loan booms are a relevant prelude to later banking crises. They argue that the household credit growth raises liability levels without a significant impact on the income in the long-run. While fast household loan expansions may exacerbate vulnerabilities, probably unchaining banking crises and rising business loans can hold similar influences; those vulnerabilities are tempered by the related income increase. Mathonnat and Minea (2018) delved on this issue by analyzing different disaggregation levels, finding by a panel of more than one hundred of crises in the banking sector and 112 economies where the M3/GDP growth and the ratio of the credits/deposits from the financial institutions trigger banking crises, and sometimes varying bank asset ratios over the total assets from the banking sector and the Central Bank are factors that reduce it. Finally, they did not empirically observe any significant influence of credits/GDP from financial institutions. Furthermore, Binici and Ganioglu (2021) found that net external position and financial development significantly affect the economy's risk of a banking crisis. We show that influence on the latter appears when interacted effects are considered.

    Rhee and Kin (2018) used data for 68 economies for the 1973–2010 period. They found that developing economies holding a higher level of income inequality usually have a greater amount of domestic loan capital and that excessive domestic credit expansions raise the unchaining of a banking crisis. Finally, their results also showed that these countries display direct mechanisms from income inequality to the likelihood of a banking crisis with no underlying linkage with credit booms. In this paper, I show that this does not occur for middle-income countries where this channel is relevant. Regarding this direct effect, El Herradi and Leroy (2022) quantified distributional effects of the triggering of a crisis in the banking sector for a panel with 132 economies during 1970–2017. Their results provide evidence on the risk of a banking crisis steadily decreasing the share of income from rich households and positively impacting middle-income families. Finally, they obtained that the inequality of income rises prior to triggering banking crises.

    Regarding the inequality-credit interaction, Rajan (2010) and Kumhof et al. (2015) proposed that a higher level of inequality leads to an excessive credit expansion and eventually to a banking crisis in the US at the beginning of the 21st century as well as in the 1920s. Moreover, Bordo and Meissner (2012) employed a dataset from 14 developed economies for the 1920–2000 period, finding that these are not significant general relationships. They suggest that excessive credit expansions intensify the risk of banking crises, but they do not find any evidence that rising top income proportions trigger loan booms. Nonetheless, Gu and Huangre (2014) observed evidence of an inequality-leverage–crisis interaction for financialized countries using a similar database. Their implications point back that credit can hardly be maintainable under a rising income inequality.

    Some authors have also found an econometric association between credit and income inequality correlated with crises in the financial sector (Perugini et al., 2015). These authors analyze, sequentially, the effects of loan growth on financial crises and then the influence of income inequality on the credit expansion. However, the consequences of the interaction between credit growth and inequality on banking crises is not investigated by these authors. On the one hand, Perugini et al. (2015) studied a panel data of 18 OECD economies during 1970–2007, and they found a positive association of income distribution with private sector leverage and income inequality. The major implications of their results are refusing the traditional view of considering that income inequality is irrelevant to macroeconomic stability and suggest taking into account the effects on income distribution as an instrument to strengthen the financial system, not only using monetary policy and regulatory reforms as instruments.

    Regarding the determinants on GDP growth, additional ones are analyzed. Chirwa and Odhiambo (2016) performed a literature review of the topic. The major facts are that the determinants depend on the degree of development of the country. While there are common factors as fiscal and monetary policy, trade, and financial factors, there are others that are specific for developed or developing countries as natural resources for developing countries and technological factors for developed economies. Here, I consider the common factors mainly concerning policy. Nonetheless, the differences in economic growth are not only a matter of space but also of time, as Bruns and Ioannidis (2020) suggest after dividing a dataset of developed and developing economies in different periods, showing, through a Bayesian model, that the most important factors are demography and education. Additionally, Pal et al. (2021) found that inflows of remittances spur income growth in both developed and developing countries.

    The rural areas have less access to financial services (Schreiner and Colombet, 2001), and this fact increases the income and population inequalities in countries such as China (Song et al., 2020). The authors proposed to improve the access to digital finance as a way to promote consumption with larger effects in rural areas. Nonetheless, a greater financial access could also lead to detrimental effects, overall, when low-income families have access to the services from financial institutions. A reason is the possible excessive indebtedness, higher interests, and possible defaults. Even if I focus on the inequality-credit linkage and its association with banking crises, and the determinants of banking crises in general are not my target, the key determinants are collected in the next section. Previously, the linkage between income inequality and financial development is dealt briefly with enough depth.

    In the last decades, it is well known that the inequality of income has risen in many developed countries. Some authors have pointed out financial causes to this origin. Xu et al. (2018) used state-level data from the United States during 1970–2000, two state-level indicators of income inequality, and applied a System GMM dynamic panel data analysis. They found that branching deregulation in the United States has increased inequality. Other authors have empirically found that financial liberalization increases income inequality and poverty. Zhang and Naceur (2019) and Dabla-Norris et al. (2015) highlight financial globalization as one of the causes. Globalization leads to a more efficient international allocation on capital and promotes risk sharing among countries. In particular, portfolio flows and foreign direct investment (FDI) have led to an increase in inequality in developed and developing countries (Freeman, 2010). Another cause suggested by Dabla-Norris et al. (2015) is financial deepening because it can facilitate higher-income households to meet their financial needs. Financial deepening with inclusive financial systems might reduce inequality by allocating the resources better. Nonetheless, other authors consider that financial development could help high-income households to progress more in the early steps of financial deepening (Greenwood and Javanovic, 1990) or increase the inequality since high-income households have improved their access to a higher return to capital (Claessens and Perotti, 2007).

    Furthermore, authors recognize the need for a reform of the financial sector in order to reduce income inequality and then promote economic growth. It is worth mentioning Claessens and Perotti (2005, p. 3) when they state that:

    "The lack of success of financial reform may be the consequence itself of a highly skewed distribution of wealth and power. Inequality itself can be a hinder to productive financial reform and financial development when powerful interests block or manipulate reforms so as to capture the benefits and avoid the costs."

    They also affirm on p. 6 that there is a link for the interaction between financial development and income inequality as a factor for economic growth:

    "So a central role for a financial system, and thus financial reform, should be helping the diffusion of economic opportunities and thereby reducing inequality. Lack of financial access can be both a direct and an indirect entry barrier to growth."

    Despite the emerging interest and debate on the inequality-credit interaction, the empirical research is limited, as Perugini et al. (2015) state. In order to clarify the topic, it is important to consider the major determinants of financial instability. The authors highlight the role of government, deregulation of the financial system, accommodative monetary policy (Peña, 2017), fast economic growth, and foreign flows. I consider these factors in this paper.

    The main question is whether financial services are extending to poor people after financial development: If low-income consumers can have better access to financial services, then income inequality would improve (Claessens & Perotti, 2007), while if they cannot access these services, income inequality would rise (Clarke et al., 2006). According to Huizinga's (2002, p.520) findings, "higher-income households are seen to be more frequent users of all bank financial instruments". Furthermore, Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine (2009) consider that financial development can also impact those who are not financial service consumers. The reason is that financial development leads to higher economic development and this would raise the labor demand, may widen income inequality according to the rise in demand of skilled or not skilled labor. Empirically, while some authors obtain that financial development reduces income inequality (Clarke et al., 2006; Beck et al., 2007; Zhang and Naceur, 2019), others find the opposite result (Jauch and Watzka, 2016; De Haan and Sturm, 2017). Finally, it is worth highlighting that Frost et al. (2022) found a positive association between financial development and financial technology with households' financial wealth and returns.

    Prior to the study of determinants, it is worth asserting a definition of banking crisis that is used in the empirical section of this paper. According to Laeven and Valencia (2020), "we define a banking crisis as an event that meets two conditions: 1) Significant signs of financial distress in the banking system (as indicated by significant bank runs, losses in the banking system, and/or banking liquidations). 2) Significant banking policy intervention measures in response to significant losses in the baking system. We consider the first year that both criteria are met to be the year when the crisis became systemic."

    The major determinants of banking crises are several and can be divided into policy, macroeconomic, banking, and institutional origins. Regarding the policy determinants, Gavin and Hausmann (1996) highlight the sources of banking crises as the volatile fiscal policy or incorrect monetary policy, as mentioned, highlighting the effects of money supply or interest rates (Frankel and Saravelos, 2012). Large fiscal deficits can precede crises while central bank independency prevents them (Kauko, 2014). Regarding the macroeconomic factor, macroeconomic volatility measured by inflation can be sources of the problem (Frankel and Saravelos, 2012), in addition to the terms of trade or world rates of interest (Gavin and Hausmann, 1996) or in exports (Peña, 2020). Furthermore, low Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and a high level of debt can also be roots of banking crises (Pereira et al., 2018). Finally, high secondary enrollment can reduce poverty, where financial inclusion is associated with lower financial instability (Neaime and Gaysset, 2018).

    With respect to the banking factors, significant determinants include excessive lending expansions (Peña, 2017; Bouvatier and Ouardi, 2023) and asset price collapses, and surges in capital flows are (Goldstein and Turner, 1996) serious credit crunches, bank leverage or illiquidity (Gavin and Hausmann, 1996), equity returns or debt composition (Frankel and Saravelos, 2012), excessive banking competition (Kauko, 2014), and, probably, excessively high interest rates (Laeven, 2011). These issues are related to the first point of the definition provided by Laeven and Valencia (2020) when there is financial distress in the banking system. Finally, among the institutional roots, as Goldstein and Turner (1996) state, the incorrect preparation for financial liberalization and financialization or the weaknesses in the bank supervision and regulation are in the accounting and legal frameworks. This is related with the second point of the definition given by Laeven and Valencia (2020) when there are significant banking policy intervention measures.

    As seen, Mathonnat and Minea (2018) found that the raise in M3/GDP and the level of credit/deposit of banks increase the likelihood of banking crises. According to these authors, some measures of financial development could lead to banking crises but not others. Therefore, we can deduct from these results that accommodative monetary policy could be associated with economic crises or recessions. Nonetheless, Lee and Werner (2018) found that official interest rates follow GDP growth, and not the opposite.

    Researchers acknowledge the presence of redistributive consequences of monetary policy (Ibrahim, 2020). The consideration that lax monetary policy may raise income and wealth inequality has become extremely popular, and one of the ways is by increasing asset prices (Albert et al., 2021). According to Taylor (2012), years prior to the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) of the 2007–2009 period and after the Great Moderation period, a period of economic growth, financial stability, and certainty dated by Peña (2017) from 1987 to 2001, there was a denominated "lax period" of accommodative monetary policies that ended up following the Taylor's (1993) rule, which could lead to the GFC, and these policies may continue even during the GFC. The reason may be that, also in this period and according to Cruz-García et al. (2020), Central Banks applied lax monetary policies to reduce the pernicious impact of the crisis.

    Rhee and Kim (2018) econometrically explored whether a raising inequality of income leads to banking crises with a panel dataset of 68 economies during 1973–2010. The findings displayed that low-income countries with a greater inequality usually benefit greater amounts of domestic loan capital. Furthermore, domestic loan booms lead to a higher probability of a bank crisis. Low-income economies show direct channels that go from income inequality to triggering a banking crisis with no linkage with loan booms. On the other hand, for advanced economies, they do not obtain any consistent econometric evidence that this inequality unchains a crisis. In low-income economies, the banking crisis risk raises sharply at the same time that inequality raises.

    Destek and Koksel (2019) verified whether the Rajan hypothesis can be confirmed. The hypothesis argues that raising income inequality is crucial in the unchaining of crises on the financial sector. The researchers examined the correlation between 10 developed countries. For that, a procedure of bootstrap rolling-window estimate was applied to find any causality regarding the linkage of inequality with loan booms for several financial crises' sub-sample periods. The findings showed that the Rajan hypothesis is supported for some crises, such as the 1989 crisis in Australia, those of 1991 and 2007 for the United Kingdom, and the 1929 and 2007 crises for the United States. Thus, raising income inequality holds a predictive power on the loan booms for some Anglo-Saxon economies. Nonetheless, there is no confirmation of the hypothesis for some countries in Scandinavian and the continental European ones. The researchers contributed in the use of a procedure rolling-window bootstrapping. This enables us to find potential relationships between income inequality and credit booms for financial crises.

    Moreover, Wang (2023) sustains that there is a non-linear nexus between the triggering of banking crises and income inequality. They empirically obtained a U-shaped linkage between these crises and inequality for a dataset of 172 countries over fifty years. Additionally, they found that income inequality maintains a non-linear effect on growth conditioned to the stage of economic development, playing also a non-linear role for crises models. In the next section, I show the expected effects of the inequality-credit linkage on banking crises after providing a new model that illustrates it.

    The theoretical framework starts with the works of López-Laborda and Peña (2018) for introducing the value added of the financial sector, and the work of Peña (2022) for dealing with the risk of a banking crisis. The former authors consider that the value added of the financial sector can be expressed as a proportion ρ of interest receipts and payments, respectively, the lending interest rate r times the loan amounts C and the deposit interest rate R times the deposit amounts D. The pure interests are the pure interest rates ε0 times the capital, B. The optimal pure interest rate is derived as follows:

    VAC:ρrC=rCε0BVAD:ρrD=ε0BRD}ε0=2rCRD(rC+RD)B (1)

    Nonetheless, there can be distortions in the economy, and the financial sector sometimes has to provide extraordinary provisions, P0=P(C), measured as a function regarding the probability of default and the credit amounts. In this case, the new pure interest rate is given as follows, with γC and γD being the shares of provisions for loans and deposits, respectively (Peña, 2022):

    VAC:ρrC=rCε0BγCP(C)VAD:ρrD=ε0BRDγDP(C)}ε0=2rCRD+P0(rCRD)(rC+RD)B (2)

    Peña (2022) also identifies a criteria for the occurrence of risk of a banking crisis, Φ. Inspired by this author, the next indicator, Φ, is provided, measuring the risk of a banking crisis as the difference between the current pure interest rate and the optimal one:

    ε0ε0Φ>0Φ0=ε0ε0 (3)

    The zero superscript of Φ indicates the period 0. Starting from the previous situations observed in the literature, I go further and propose a new view that checks whether the risk of a banking crisis increases when there is a period 1 after a raise in income inequality (i) or, alternatively, a raise of the size of the financial sector (ii), and a period 2 after when both variables raise at the same time. The raise on income inequality is provided, for instance, after an increase in g in income for higher-income people and, thus, of loans and deposits, and a decrease gd in the need of extraordinary provisions.

    i:ΔY,ε1i0=2rCRD(1+g)2+P0(rCRD)(1gP)(1+g)(rC+RD)B(1+g)
    Φ1i=ε1i0ε0Φ1iΦ0=2rCRDg+P0(rCRD)(gP)(rC+RD)B?0 (4)

    The sign can be positive or negative. For the (ii) case, we raise g of the banking sector measured by the increase of capital, B:

    ii:ΔB,ε1ii0=2rCRD+P0(rCRD)(rC+RD)B(1+g)Φ1ii=ε1ii0ε0
    Φ1iiΦ0=g[2rCRD+P0(rCRD)](rC+RD)B(1+g)<0ifg>0 (5)

    The sign is always negative if there is an increase in income of higher-income households. For the period 2, it holds that,

    2:ΔY,ΔB,ε20=2rCRD(1+g)2+P0(rCRD)(1gP)(1+g)(rC+RD)B(1+g)2
    Φ2=ε20ε0{Φ2Φ1i=g[2rCRD+1gP1+gP0(rCRD)](rC+RD)B(1+g)?0Φ2Φ1ii=g2rCRDgPP0(rCRD)(rC+RD)B(1+g)?0 (6)

    The hypothesis for the effect of the inequality–credit interaction on banking crises is provided:

    Hypothesis: The inequality-credit linkage (target independent variable) hampers the individual separate effect on the risk of triggering a banking crisis (dependent variable).

    The inequality-credit linkage is the interaction between income inequality and financial sector size, measured as a product. The individual effect is the separate effect of each one of those variables. There are, at least, two reasons for the effect proposed in the Hypothesis: One on the demand side and the other on the supply side. First, if I consider only the first-round effects of a raise in the demand of financial services by low-income households, as they pay a higher lending interest rate than high-income households, this would increase at the same time as income inequality and financial development, leading to higher profits to the banks and a lower probability of a banking crisis in the current period. Second, if the supply side is seen, a joint effect of a change in both income inequality and financial sector size would mitigate the reduction of economic distortions provided by the individual effects, leading to a higher risk of banking crisis.

    The second-round effects or possible secondary effects on the demand side could be related to applying higher interest rates to the low-income households than to the other customers, and with the possible defaults associated with those higher interests. There is a reduction in the demand due to both facts since they generate lower available income and a higher awareness of a higher risk of default, respectively. This lower demand would attenuate the above-mentioned first-round effects. The predominant effect is known in the empirical section.

    Therefore, the expectations are as follows if there is a raise on the size of the financial sector:

    Case1a: Higher-income raise:Φ1iΦ0<0,Φ2Φ1>0Case1b: Higher-income decrease:Φ1iΦ0>0,Φ2Φ1<0Case2a: Lower-income raise:Φ1iΦ0>0,Φ2Φ1<0Case2b: Lower-income decrease:Φ1iΦ0<0,Φ2Φ1>0 (7)

    The cases of raising income inequality are 1a and 2b, while the decrease in income inequality appears in cases 1b and 2a. In Equation (7), the opposite inequality can also be found, where the key is that the period 2 effect (the linkage) hampers the period 1 (isolated) effect. Therefore, it is considered that the lower economic distortions and the reduced likelihood of suffering a banking crisis, which is provoked by the isolated higher income inequality and greater financial sector size, are hampered by the opposite effect on the risk of a banking crisis that is led by an increase in both inequality and financial size.

    In this section, I specify the impact of the interaction between credit and income inequality on the probability of banking crises. An unbalanced data sample with 108 world countries for the period between 2002 and 2017 is managed.

    I estimate models using the two-step dynamic System and Difference GMM methods (Arellano and Bover, 1995 and Blundell and Bond, 1998) since the instruments in the level regression are efficient predictors for endogenous variables (Blundell and Bond, 1998) and since these models are strongly advised for the high degree of persistence in the explained variable (Roodman, 2009). All models apply a bias-corrected robust estimator used for two-step variance-covariance matrix estimators (VCEs) and the WC-robust estimator of Windmeijer (2005). The specification of the GMM models follows Perugini et al. (2015) and Braun et al. (2019), with some modifications:

    bcrisisi,t=β0+β1bcrisisi,t1+β2interi,t+β3inequalityi,t+β4crediti,t+Xi,tβX+εi,t (8)

    where i = 1, …, N and, for the panel data estimations, the total of countries is N = 212, t = 1, …, T, and T = 48 is the total of temporal periods. The dependent variable is the probability of suffering a systemic banking crisis, the interaction variable is the product between the variables of income inequality (inequality), and credit (credit) and X are the control variables. In addition, β0 is the constant, β1β4 are the coefficients of the temporal lag and target variables, βX is the vector of coefficients of control variables, and εi,t is the error term.

    The bcrisis variable of systemic banking crises, provided by Laeven and Valencia (2013), takes 1 if there is a banking crisis in the country or 0 otherwise, using the definition of banking crisis from the previous authors. This variable is directly obtained from the World Bank, beginning with data in 1970 and ending in 2017 due to the availability of the variable in the World Bank Development Indicators Database for the dependent variable.

    The target variables, in addition to the interaction, are the following depending on the model: The measures of income inequality are the Gini Index from the World Bank for giniwb, which reflects the way the distribution of income (or consumption expenditure) among persons within a country deviates from an equal distribution and the top income shares of the 1% richest people by the World Income Inequality Database for top1. The credit variable is measured by cdpv and cdbs and they are the percentage of domestic private credit provided by the financial sector and the banks over total GDP, respectively, which includes all credits to several public and private sectors. The inter variable constitutes, depending on the model, the product of the variables giniwb and cdpv, and top1 and cdbs, respectively. The years and countries of the different samples and subsamples appear in Tables 12, using the classification codes developed by the World Bank.

    The control variables of this model are the major targets of public policy. The GDP per capita is measured by the gpc variable, while in growth rates, it is expressed by gpcgr as a percentage. The public expenditure, ps, is measured by the expenditure of the public sector over the total of GDP and considers the public sector affairs. The macroeconomic issues are collected, initially, in tbr, reflecting the treasure bill rates calculated as the lending rate minus the risk premium. The deviation from the ideal inflation is provided by dinfl, which is the deviation between inflation and its optimum, measured as the absolute value of the difference between the inflation rate and the desirable inflation, which is considered to be 2% (OECD database). This variable takes into account the target of monetary policy. The variable xgdp considers the international influence and is measured as the quotient between the exports divided by the GDP; and the atm variable reflects the number of Automated Teller Machines (ATMs) over 100,000 adults for showing the banking factors.

    Concerning the institutional issues, sec measures the rate of secondary school enrollment and the percentage of cities over total towns. The unem variable measures the unemployment rate. These variables have been constructed from the World Bank. Finally, a set of dummies is included for checking robustness: Laxity is a binary dummy used for the robustness check and reflects the period after the Great Moderation, 1987–2001, and previous to the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), 2007–2009; thus, it shows the period of similar lax monetary policy in most countries from 2002 to 2006 (taking 1 for the 2002–2006 period and 0 otherwise) as Peña (2017) points, where most countries began to apply accommodative policies and finished the Great Moderation period of high stability and certainty. There are two additional binary variables concerning economic and geographical issues: oecd and eca, which measure whether a country belongs to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) or the Europe and Central Asia (ECA) region according to the World Bank, 1, or 0, otherwise, respectively.

    The data sample is based on the countries that appear in Tables 12. An unbalanced panel is used, with data from 1970 to 2017 of 212 world countries considered for the panel data estimations, while data from 1960 to 2021 of the 216 world countries is handled for the country-by-country Granger-causality test, with three different sub-samples for the panel Granger-causality tests since a balanced dataset is required.

    Table 1.  Countries and territories (216) of the full sample (1960–2021) of the Granger-causality test.
    Full sample: 216 countries for 1960–2021
    ABW BRB DZA HKG LBR MUS QAT THA
    AFG BRN ECU HND LBY MWI ROU TJK
    AGO BTN EGY HRV LCA MYS RUS TKM
    ALB BWA ERI HTI LIE NAM RWA TLS
    AND CAN ESP HUN LKA NCL SAU TON
    ARE CHE EST IDN LSO NER SDN TTO
    ARG CHI ETH IMN LTU NGA SEN TUN
    ARM CHL FIN IND LUX NIC SGP TUR
    ASM CHN FJI IRL LVA NLD SLB TUV
    ATG CIV FRA IRN MAC NOR SLE TZA
    AUS CMR FRO IRQ MAF NPL SLV UGA
    AUT COD FSM ISL MAR NRU SMR UKR
    AZE COG GAB ISR MCO NZL SOM URY
    BDI COL GBR ITA MDA OMN SRB USA
    BEL COM GEO JAM MDG PAK SSD UZB
    BEN CPV GHA JOR MDV PAN STP VCT
    BFA CRI GIB JPN MEX PER SUR VEN
    BGD CUB GIN KAZ MHL PHL SVK VGB
    BGR CUW GMB KEN MKD PLW SVN VIR
    BHR CYM GNB KGZ MLI PNG SWE VNM
    BHS CYP GNQ KHM MLT POL SWZ VUT
    BIH CZE GRC KIR MMR PRI SXM WSM
    BLR DEU GRD KNA MNE PRK SYC XKX
    BLZ DJI GRL KOR MNG PRT SYR YEM
    BMU DMA GTM KWT MNP PRY TCA ZAF
    BOL DNK GUM LAO MOZ PSE TCD ZMB
    BRA DOM GUY LBN MRT PYF TGO ZWE
    Note: World Bank country codes, for the panel estimations the sample is constrained by the bcrisis variable, so it is for the 1970–2017 period for 212 countries, the previous ones with the exceptions of ATG, MCO, MUS, WSM. All the 212 countries have non-empty data from 1970 to 2017 with the exceptions of 15 countries that ranges from 1971 to 2017: AND, CHI, COD, GRL, GUM, IMN, NRU, PRI, PSE, ROU, SSD, SXM, TCA, TLS, XKX. Note: ABW: Aruba; AFG: Afghanistan; AGO: Angola; ALB: Albania; AND: Andorra; ARE: United Arab Emirates; ARG: Argentina; ARM: Armenia; ASM: American Samoa; ATG: Antigua and Barbuda; AUS: Australia; AUT: Austria; AZE: Azerbaijan; BDI: Burundi; BEL: Belgium; BEN: Benin; BFA: Burkina Faso; BGD: Bangladesh; BGR: Bulgaria; BHR: Bahrain; BHS: Bahamas, The; BIH: Bosnia and Herzegovina; BLR: Belarus; BLZ: Belize; BMU: Bermuda; BOL: Bolivia; BRA: Brazil; BRB: Barbados; BRN: Brunei Darussalam; BTN: Bhutan; BWA: Botswana; CAN: Canada; CHE: Switzerland; CHI: Channel Islands; CHL: Chile; CHN: China; CIV: Cote d'Ivoire; CMR: Cameroon; COD: Congo, Dem. Rep.; COG: Congo, Rep.; COL: Colombia; COM: Comoros; CPV: Cabo Verde; CRI: Costa Rica; CUB: Cuba; CUW: Curacao; CYM: Cayman Islands; CYP: Cyprus; CZE: Czech Republic; DEU: Germany; DJI: Djibouti; DMA: Dominica; DNK: Denmark; DOM: Dominican Republic; DZA: Algeria; ECU: Ecuador; EGY: Egypt, Arab Rep.; ERI: Eritrea; ESP: Spain; EST: Estonia; ETH: Ethiopia; FIN: Finland; FJI: Fiji; FRA: France; FRO: Faroe Islands; FSM: Micronesia, Fed. Sts.; GAB: Gabon; GBR: United Kingdom; GEO: Georgia; GHA: Ghana; GIB: Gibraltar; GIN: Guinea; GMB: Gambia, The; GNB: Guinea-Bissau; GNQ: Equatorial Guinea; GRC: Greece; GRD: Grenada; GRL: Greenland; GTM: Guatemala; GUM: Guam; GUY: Guyana; HKG: Hong Kong SAR, China; HND: Honduras; HRV: Croatia; HTI: Haiti; HUN: Hungary; IDN: Indonesia; IMN: Isle of Man; IND: India; IRL: Ireland; IRN: Iran, Islamic Rep.; IRQ: Iraq; ISL: Iceland; ISR: Israel; ITA: Italy; JAM: Jamaica; JOR: Jordan; JPN: Japan; KAZ: Kazakhstan; KEN: Kenya; KGZ: Kyrgyz Republic; KHM: Cambodia; KIR: Kiribati; KNA: St. Kitts and Nevis; KOR: Korea, Rep.; KWT: Kuwait; LAO: Lao PDR; LBN: Lebanon; LBR: Liberia; LBY: Libya; LCA: St. Lucia; LIE: Liechtenstein; LKA: Sri Lanka; LSO: Lesotho; LTU: Lithuania; LUX: Luxembourg; LVA: Latvia; MAC: Macao SAR, China; MAF: St. Martin (French part); MAR: Morocco; MCO: Monaco; MDA: Moldova; MDG: Madagascar; MDV: Maldives; MEX: Mexico; MHL: Marshall Islands; MKD: North Macedonia; MLI: Mali; MLT: Malta; MMR: Myanmar; MNE: Montenegro; MNG: Mongolia; MNP: Northern Mariana Islands; MOZ: Mozambique; MRT: Mauritania; MUS: Mauritius; MWI: Malawi; MYS: Malaysia; NAM: Namibia; NCL: New Caledonia; NER: Niger; NGA: Nigeria; NIC: Nicaragua; NLD: Netherlands; NOR: Norway; NPL: Nepal; NRU: Nauru; NZL: New Zealand; OMN: Oman; PAK: Pakistan; PAN: Panama; PER: Peru; PHL: Philippines; PLW: Palau; PNG: Papua New Guinea; POL: Poland; PRI: Puerto Rico; PRK: Korea, Dem. People's Rep.; PRT: Portugal; PRY: Paraguay; PSE: West Bank and Gaza; PYF: French Polynesia; QAT: Qatar; ROU: Romania; RUS: Russian Federation; RWA: Rwanda; SAU: Saudi Arabia; SDN: Sudan; SEN: Senegal; SGP: Singapore; SLB: Solomon Islands; SLE: Sierra Leone; SLV: El Salvador; SMR: San Marino; SOM: Somalia; SRB: Serbia; SSD: South Sudan; STP: Sao Tome and Principe; SUR: Suriname; SVK: Slovak Republic; SVN: Slovenia; SWE: Sweden; SWZ: Eswatini; SXM: Sint Maarten (Dutch part); SYC: Seychelles; SYR: Syrian Arab Republic; TCA: Turks and Caicos Islands; TCD: Chad; TGO: Togo; THA: Thailand; TJK: Tajikistan; TKM: Turkmenistan; TLS: Timor-Leste; TON: Tonga; TTO: Trinidad and Tobago; TUN: Tunisia; TUR: Turkiye; TUV: Tuvalu; TZA: Tanzania; UGA: Uganda; UKR: Ukraine; URY: Uruguay; USA: United States; UZB: Uzbekistan; VCT: St. Vincent and the Grenadines; VEN: Venezuela, RB; VGB: British Virgin Islands; VIR: Virgin Islands (U.S.); VNM: Vietnam; VUT: Vanuatu; WSM: Samoa; XKX: Kosovo; YEM: Yemen, Rep.; ZAF: South Africa; ZMB: Zambia; ZWE: Zimbabwe.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 2.  Balanced subsamples for the panel Granger-causality test.
    Balanced Subsample 1 (2005–2019), H0: giniw*bcdpv does not GC gpc
    AUT BEL CRI CYP CZE
    DNK DOM ECU ESP EST
    FIN GRC HND HUN KGZ
    LUX NLD NOR PER PRT
    PRY RUS SLV SVN SWE USA
    Balanced Subsample 2 (1960–2021), H0: top1*cdbs does not GC gpc
    AUS IND JPN NOR SWE USA
    Balanced Subsample 3 (2002–2019), H0: top1*cdbs does not GC gpc
    AGO CHN GHA KHM NER SLV
    AGO CHN GHA KHM NER SLV
    ALB CIV GIN KOR NGA SRB
    ARE CMR GNB KWT NIC STP
    ARG COD GNQ LBR NLD SUR
    ARM COG GRC LBY NOR SWE
    AUS COL GTM LKA NPL SWZ
    AUT COM GUY LSO OMN SYC
    AZE CPV HKG LUX PAK TCD
    BDI CRI HND MAC PAN TGO
    BEL CYP HRV MAR PER THA
    BEN CZE HTI MDA PHL TJK
    BFA DEU HUN MDG PNG TLS
    BGD DJI IDN MDV POL TTO
    BGR DNK IND MEX PRT TUN
    BHS DOM IRL MKD PRY TUR
    BIH DZA ISL MLI PSE TZA
    BLR ECU ISR MMR QAT UGA
    BLZ EGY ITA MNE ROU UKR
    BOL ESP JAM MNG RUS URY
    BRA FIN JOR MOZ RWA USA
    BRN FRA JPN MUS SDN VNM
    BTN GAB KAZ MWI SEN ZAF
    BWA GBR KEN MYS SGP ZMB
    CHL GEO KGZ NAM SLE

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The recent Granger-causality panel data test proposed by Juodis, Karavias, and Sarafidis (2021) and Xiao et al. (2023) follows this function:

    Yi,t=φ0i+Pp=1βpixitp+εit (9)

    Being the X and Y independent and dependent variables, xitp is a scalar of individual i in time t minus the temporal lag p, and the errors are εit and βpi for the Granger-causality parameter. The null hypothesis is that xitp does not Granger-cause (GC) yi,tp, formalized as follows (left), whereas the alternative is (right):

    H0:βpi=0i,p;H1:i,p|βpi0 (10)

    Avoidance of the rejection of the null hypothesis shows that xitp does not GC yi,tp.

    The major characteristics of the variables and the expected signs of the explanatory variables are included in Tables 3 and 4. No significant correlation between each couple of variables is found after applying the matrix of correlation and the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) test1.

    Table 3.  Major characteristics of the variables.
    Variable Source Expected sign Definition. References Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum
    bcrisis (0, 1) World Bank (WB) N/A Variable taking 1 if banking crisis, 0 otherwise 10161 0.04 0.21 0.00 1.00
    giniwb (0–100) WB + Gini Index/Income share of the 1st percentile of richest people. Claessens and Perotti (2005) and Braun et al. (2019) 1665 38.46 9.19 20.70 65.80
    top1 (0–1) WID 6805 0.16 0.06 0.02 0.64
    cdpv (% GDP) WB + Share of private credit. Share of banking sector credit. Claessens and Perotti (2005), Peña (2017), Braun et al. (2019) and Bouvatier and Ouardi (2023) 5609 40.13 38.68 0.01 304.58
    cdbs (% GDP) 6659 37.23 40.47 0.00 525.64
    inter (interaction) WB/WID - giniwb*cdpv/top1*cdbs. By the authors, based on Claessens and Perotti (2005) and Braun et al. (2019) giniwb*cdpv, top1*cdbs
    gpcgr (% growth rate) World Bank - Growth rate of GDP per capita. Pereira et al. (2018) 8040 2.00 6.06 −64.99 140.37
    ps (% GDP) World Bank + Share of public spending. Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (1998) 3564 26.56 12.59 0.00 210.21
    tbr (% rate) World Bank + Treasury bill rate: lending interest rate minus risk spread. Laeven (2011) 2074 9.23 9.81 −0.54 124.03
    dinfl (% growth rate) OECD Database + Deviation between inflation and 2% optimum. Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache 1998, von Hagen and Ho 2007 6871 26.13 364.23 0.00 23771.13
    xgdp (% GDP) World Bank + Share of exports. Peña (2020) 7017 37.25 28.98 0.01 433.84
    atms (per 100000 adults) World Bank - Automated Teller Machines per adults. Gavin and Hausmann (1996) 2623 44.60 45.87 0.01 324.17
    sec (% gross) World Bank - Secondary school enrollment. Neaime and Gaysset (2018) 6150 64.98 34.08 0.19 166.14
    urban (% over total) World Bank ? Share of urban population 10122 52.90 25.24 2.85 100.00
    unem (% rate) World Bank + Unemployment rate. Pereira et al. (2018) 4076 8.19 6.17 0.05 57.00
    lax (0, 1) Own ellaboration + Lax (discretionary) period: 1, 0 otherwise. Taylor (2012), Peña, 2017) 10176 0.10 0.31 0.00 1.00
    oecd (0, 1) Own ellaboration ? OECD member: 1, 0 otherwise 10176 0.18 0.38 0.00 1.00
    eca (0, 1) World Bank ? Europe and Central Asia member: 1, 0 otherwise 10176 0.27 0.45 0.00 1.00

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 4.  Descriptive statistics for the samples used for Granger-causality.
    Full sample
    Variable Obs Mean Std. dev. Min Max
    gpc 10,271 9051.918 17589.54 12.80281 189487.1
    top1*cdbs 6,056 6.174511 5.867718 0.0002167 54.85093
    giniwb*cdpv 1,457 2259.034 1677.736 4.617013 9446.48
    Subsample 1
    Variable Obs Mean Std. dev. Min Max
    gpc 390 29796.21 27208.48 476.552 123679
    giniwb*cdpv 390 2834.955 1786.364 215.3008 9446.48
    Subsample 2
    Variable Obs Mean Std. dev. Min Max
    gpc 372 22919.56 23258.77 82.1886 102913
    top1*cdbs 372 7.70555 5.153445 1.052586 25.26913
    Subsample 3
    Variable Obs Mean Std. dev. Min Max
    gpc 2,574 12885.05 19105.91 113.567 123679
    top1*cdbs 2,574 7.350831 6.636802 0.0002623 54.85093

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    1 Results available upon request.

    The major results are shown, with the robust standard errors in Tables 5 and 6. These tables show the results of the System GMM models (SYS) and Difference GMM models (DIF). The target variables are cdpv and gini for Table 5 and cdbs and top1 for Table 6. The estimations are shown with only interaction (INTER, Models 1–2), with both the credit and inequality variables (BOTH, 3–4), the interaction and inequality measures (INTER & INEQ, 5–6), the interaction and inequality measures (INTER & CRED, 7–8), or with all the variables (INTER & BOTH, 9–10). The models achieve accurate econometric properties, which are confirmed by the no significance of the subjection to serial correlation of order two (fulfilling the Arellano-Bond test) and the no significance of the over-identification of the instruments. These instruments are considered valid by the application of the Sargan test, which is the same as the Hansen's for this two-step model (Roodman, 2009).

    Table 5.  Panel data estimations I.
    MODELS\VARIABLES Dependent variable: crisisb (1) SYS ONLY INTER (2) DIF ONLY INTER (3) SYS BOTH (4) DIF BOTH (5) SYS INTER & INEQ (6) DIF INTER & INEQ (7) SYS INTER & CREDIT (8) DIF INTER & CREDIT (9) SYS INTER & BOTH (10) DIF INTER & BOTH
    crisisbt-1 0.690*** 0.705** 0.694*** 0.824*** 0.672*** 0.797*** 0.903*** 0.914* 0.946*** 0.854***
    (0.226) (0.329) (0.182) (0.239) (0.169) (0.225) (0.328) (0.487) (0.298) (0.225)
    giniwb 0.00707 0.0632* 0.00625 0.0588* −0.0286** −0.0318
    (0.0164) (0.0356) (0.0162) (0.0346) (0.0125) (0.0354)
    cdpv 3.30e-05 −0.00102 −0.0202** −0.0310*** −0.0332*** −0.0364***
    (0.00160) (0.00114) (0.0102) (0.0112) (0.0118) (0.0120)
    intera 3.70e-06 1.72e-05 2.31e-05 7.28e-06 0.000604* 0.000966*** 0.00102*** 0.00115***
    (7.61e-5) (3.79e-05) (5.26e-5) (4.33e-05) (0.000308) (0.000322) (0.000372) (0.000364)
    gpcgr −0.00684 −0.00768 −0.00650 −0.010*** −0.00651 −0.0097** −0.00915 −0.00766 −0.00791 −0.00513
    (0.00959) (0.00603) (0.00777) (0.00362) (0.00700) (0.00381) (0.00664) (0.00838) (0.00671) (0.00819)
    ps 0.00546 0.00962 0.0105 0.00599 0.00999 0.00637 0.00540 0.00214 0.00156 0.00226
    (0.00400) (0.00775) (0.0156) (0.00480) (0.0150) (0.00507) (0.00904) (0.00239) (0.00320) (0.00240)
    tbr 0.00884 −0.00767 0.00650 −0.0184 0.00610 −0.0192 0.00555 −0.00912 1.74e-05 −0.00888
    (0.0243) (0.0270) (0.0224) (0.0206) (0.0209) (0.0189) (0.0113) (0.0132) (0.0125) (0.0112)
    dinfl 0.0125 0.0111 0.0160 0.00981 0.0153 0.00953 0.00995 0.00624 0.00494 0.00614
    (0.0157) (0.0106) (0.0121) (0.00782) (0.0117) (0.00753) (0.00976) (0.00693) (0.00804) (0.00861)
    xgdp 0.00123 0.00492 0.00102 0.00219 0.00133 0.00292 0.00242 0.00113 0.000668 0.00120
    (0.00376) (0.00415) (0.00266) (0.00426) (0.00293) (0.00434) (0.00332) (0.00454) (0.00289) (0.00448)
    atms 0.000427 0.000837** 0.000601 0.000423 0.000392 0.000368 0.000503 0.000211 −0.00128 0.000190
    (0.00208) (0.000424) (0.00108) (0.000445) (0.00140) (0.000464) (0.00104) (0.000547) (0.00214) (0.000609)
    sec −0.00134 −0.000319 −0.00149 0.000785 −0.00155 0.000854 0.000455 0.00151 0.000763 0.00110
    (0.00292) (0.00197) (0.00300) (0.00243) (0.00316) (0.00240) (0.00245) (0.00242) (0.00287) (0.00201)
    urban −0.00208 −0.0382 −0.00217 −0.00870 −0.00205 −0.0123 0.00193 −0.00369 0.00227 −0.0126
    (0.00332) (0.0393) (0.00561) (0.0362) (0.00443) (0.0351) (0.00569) (0.0316) (0.00331) (0.0248)
    unem −0.00714 −0.0258 −0.0156 −0.0412 −0.0134 −0.0383 −0.0284 −0.0224 −0.0184 −0.0142
    (0.0171) (0.0260) (0.0217) (0.0275) (0.0204) (0.0262) (0.0248) (0.0302) (0.0248) (0.0224)
    constant 0.0370 2.319 −0.251 −1.609 −0.274 −1.357 −0.410 −0.131 0.762 1.508
    (0.246) (2.744) (0.846) (3.147) (0.768) (3.070) (0.656) (2.153) (0.545) (2.517)
    Observations 197 137 197 137 197 137 197 137 197 137
    Number of countries 32 19 32 19 32 19 32 19 32 19
    A-B test 0.2575 0.2923 0.2835 0.5148 0.2622 0.4489 0.4285 0.4969 0.4802 0.5079
    Sargan test 0.9657 0.5191 0.7627 0.6952 0.7844 0.7081 0.9032 0.6647 0.9648 0.6450
    Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Standard errors are in parenthesis. a: inter is obtained as giniwb*cdpv.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 6.  Panel data estimations II.
    MODELS \VARIABLES Dependent variable: crisisb (1) SYS ONLY INTER (2) DIF ONLY INTER (3) SYS BOTH (4) DIF BOTH (5) SYS INTER & INEQ (6) DIF INTER & INEQ (7) SYS INTER & CREDIT (8) DIF INTER & CREDIT (9) SYS INTER & BOTH (10) DIF INTER & BOTH
    crisisbt-1 0.802*** 0.767*** 0.806*** 0.745*** 0.792*** 0.767*** 0.715*** 0.679*** 0.783*** 0.678***
    (0.254) (0.0906) (0.170) (0.0770) (0.302) (0.0816) (0.191) (0.108) (0.137) (0.109)
    top1 −0.964 −1.032 −0.175 0.308 1.317** 1.671***
    (0.995) (0.974) (1.006) (1.216) (0.542) (0.335)
    cdbs −0.00025 −0.000397 0.00289 0.00325 0.00417 0.00482
    (0.00116) (0.00192) (0.00196) (0.00474) (0.00303) (0.00484)
    intera −0.0163 −0.022*** −0.0157 −0.0233** −0.0276*** −0.0331*** −0.0362*** −0.0450***
    (0.0152) (0.00612) (0.0170) (0.00946) (0.0104) (0.00363) (0.00681) (0.00545)
    gpcgr −0.00243 −0.00151 −0.00044 0.000177 −0.00222 −0.00148 −0.00150 0.000231 −0.000692 0.000388
    (0.00212) (0.00545) (0.00193) (0.00309) (0.00219) (0.00542) (0.00584) (0.00598) (0.00982) (0.00476)
    ps 0.00554 0.00655 0.00335 0.00521 0.00528 0.00632 0.00259 0.00467 0.00351 0.00413
    (0.00976) (0.00486) (0.00407) (0.00605) (0.00869) (0.00451) (0.00393) (0.00874) (0.00530) (0.00861)
    tbr 0.00310 −0.000930 −0.00220 −0.00486 0.00269 −0.00114 0.00145 −0.00468 0.000454 −0.00533
    (0.00824) (0.0179) (0.00363) (0.00365) (0.00723) (0.0171) (0.0186) (0.0127) (0.0274) (0.00865)
    dinfl 0.00459 0.00129 0.00464 0.00107 0.00480 0.00153 0.00463 −0.000456 0.00474 −0.000980
    (0.00547) (0.00549) (0.00553) (0.00299) (0.00575) (0.00539) (0.00661) (0.00453) (0.00456) (0.00336)
    xgdp −0.00165 −0.00153 −0.00106 0.000100 −0.00166 −0.00147 −0.00156 −0.000940 −0.00148 −0.000926
    (0.00261) (0.00161) (0.00114) (0.000982) (0.00250) (0.00151) (0.00271) (0.00188) (0.00301) (0.00196)
    atms 0.00110 0.000926 0.000293 0.000537 0.00112 0.000853 0.000553 0.000420 0.000392 0.000110
    (0.00153) (0.000822) (0.00137) (0.000789) (0.00216) (0.000743) (0.000987) (0.00135) (0.00137) (0.00112)
    sec −0.000975 −0.000702 −0.00085 −0.000445 −0.00103 −0.000629 −0.00120 −0.000574 −0.000310 −0.000400
    (0.00259) (0.00127) (0.00197) (0.00123) (0.00323) (0.00134) (0.00166) (0.00159) (0.000871) (0.00158)
    urban −0.00147 −0.00810 −0.00061 −0.0101 −0.00136 −0.00823 −0.000768 −0.0111 −0.00401 −0.0104
    (0.00204) (0.0159) (0.00258) (0.00734) (0.00294) (0.0159) (0.00178) (0.00875) (0.00346) (0.00699)
    unem −0.00445 −0.00617 −0.00488 −0.00530 −0.00480 −0.00647 −0.00379 −0.00629 −0.00330 −0.00588
    (0.00957) (0.0111) (0.00392) (0.00506) (0.00893) (0.0105) (0.00867) (0.00516) (0.00931) (0.00495)
    constant 0.219 0.703 0.292 0.802 0.252 0.684 0.233 0.869 0.127 0.584
    (0.302) (1.242) (0.328) (0.503) (0.383) (1.323) (0.382) (0.559) (0.339) (0.447)
    Observations 329 261 329 261 329 261 329 261 329 261
    Number of countries 40 34 40 34 40 34 40 34 40 34
    A-B test 0.3904 0.4551 0.3493 0.3628 0.3950 0.4587 0.3597 0.4052 0.3354 0.3806
    Sargan test 0.8286 0.4137 0.7456 0.6236 0.7599 0.4158 0.7894 0.4802 0.7549 0.5167
    Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Standard errors are in parenthesis. a: inter is obtained as top1*cdbs

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The results in Tables 5 and 6 show the robustness for most coefficients of the variables that are significant. In particular, the coefficients of the target variables are hardly always significant. The results of the target variables are depicted. As expected, a negative impact of interaction on the dependent variable is obtained, while the Gini and credit variables have a positive individual effect on the probability of a banking crisis, confirming the proposed Hypothesis of Section 3. Therefore, the first-round effects of a raise in the demand of financial services by low-income households with higher lending interest rates leads to a higher income inequality and financial development that raises banks' profits and reduce the likelihood of a banking crisis in the current period. This first-round effect is in the opposite sign than the second-round effects since those high interest rates lead to a lower demand and less profits to the banks.

    The rest of control variables are never significant, except gpcgr and atms. The presence of interactive terms means that the total effect of one variable (the credit or inequality variable) must be computed using the estimated coefficient of that variable plus the estimated coefficient of the interactive variable multiplied by the other variable. Thus, the positive effect of the non-interacted target variables is reduced by the interaction.

    Finally, as it is not possible to identify whether the interaction does not Granger Cause (GC) a binary variable as a dependent variable, as when the risk of a banking crises and Braun et al. (2019) did not check that relationship, I employed the extremely novel technique for checking Granger-causality on GDP per capita in panel data. This was proposed by Juodis et al. (2021) and was developed by Xiao et al. (2023), who solved the so-called 'Neville bias'. As it is useful for balanced panels, I reduced the sample in order to achieve a balanced panel. The results are shown in Table 7.

    Table 7.  Panel data Granger-causality tests with the three subsamples.
    Balanced Subsample 1 (2005–2019, 26 countries), H0: gini*cdpv does not GC gpc
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0 26 14 4982.371
    Balanced Subsample 1 (2005–2019, 26 countries), H0: gpc does not GC gini*cdpv
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0.188 26 14 3399.521
    Balanced Subsample 2 (1960–2021), H0: top1*cdbs does not GC gpc
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0 62 5 3674.653
    Balanced Subsample 2 (1960–2021), H0: does gpc not GC top1*cdbs
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0 62 5 425.4523
    Balanced Subsample 3 (2002–2019), H0: top1*cdbs does not GC gpc
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0 143 17 32846.07
    Balanced Subsample 3 (2002–2019), H0: gpc does not GC top1*cdbs
    p-value Units Obs. per unit BIC
    0 143 17 71.53767
    Note: Obs. means observations.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Checking the null hypothesis as to whether the interaction, specified in two differentiated alternative ways, does not GC gpc, it was found that the null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% level of significance for all the samples and specifications. The opposite direction is non-rejected at the 10% significance level with a p-value of 0.180 for sub-sample 1. Two different additional subsamples have been used with GDP per capita, a different measure of inequality and credit with similar results, and rejecting the null hypothesis for the opposite direction. These results are consistent with the theoretical analysis in Section 3 and follows the Hypothesis developed there.

    The results in Tables 810 show the robustness checks for the panel data estimations. Table 10 shows cdpv and gini (GINI, Models 1–4), and cdbs and top1 (GINI, Models 5–8) as target variables. Different dummy variables are incorporated, such as lax (Models 1–2, 5–6), oecd (Models 3, 7), and eca (Models 4, 8). The results are similar to those in Tables 56.

    Table 8.  Robustness check: Country-by-country Granger-causality test full sample (available tests for 64 countries).
    WB CC p-value Reject? WB CC p-value Reject?
    ALB 0 1 ISR 0.192 0
    ARG 0.761 0 ITA 0.013 1
    ARM 0.025 1 KGZ 0.325 0
    AUT 0.592 0 LTU 0.528 0
    BEL 0.828 0 LUX 0.024 1
    BGR 0.021 1 LVA 0 1
    BLR 0.545 0 MDA 0.095 1
    BOL 0.013 1 MKD 0 1
    BRA 0.128 0 MLT 0.007 1
    CHE 0.239 0 MNE 0.869 0
    CHN 0 1 NLD 0.808 0
    COL 0.24 0 NOR 0.365 0
    CRI 0.074 1 PAN 0 1
    CYP 0.005 1 PER 0 1
    CZE 0.262 0 POL 0.022 1
    DEU 0.014 1 PRT 0.758 0
    DNK 0.016 1 PRY 0.038 1
    DOM 0.101 0 PSE 0 1
    ECU 0 1 ROU 0 1
    ESP 0.624 0 RUS 0.504 0
    EST 0.262 0 SLV 0.038 1
    FIN 0.036 1 SRB 0 1
    FRA 0.005 1 SVK 0.593 0
    GBR 0.969 0 SVN 0.504 0
    GEO 0 1 SWE 0.155 0
    GRC 0 1 THA 0 1
    HND 0.859 0 TUR 0 1
    HRV 0 1 UKR 0.011 1
    HUN 0.011 1 URY 0.702 0
    IDN 0 1 USA 0.062 1
    IRL 0 1 VEN 0.803 0
    ISL 0.03 1 XKX 0.027 1
    AVG 0.22035938 0.59375
    Note: WB CC means World Bank Country Codes, p-value indicates the one of the country-by-country Granger-causality test with H0 gini*cdpv does not GC gpc, Reject? means whether the null hypothesis is rejected for a country (1) or not (0), and AVG means the average. For the meaning of the country codes, see the footnote in Table 2.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 9.  Robustness check: Country-by-country Granger-causality test full sample (available tests for 176 countries).
    WB CC p-value Reject? WB CC p-value Reject? WB CC p-value Reject?
    AFG 0 1 GMB 0.007 1 NIC 0.045 1
    AGO 0.463 0 GNB 0.016 1 NLD 0.034 1
    ALB 0.005 1 GNQ 0.467 0 NOR 0.011 1
    ARE 0.99 0 GRC 0 1 NPL 0.053 1
    ARG 0.287 0 GTM 0 1 NZL 0.001 1
    ARM 0.007 1 GUY 0.402 0 OMN 0.244 0
    AUS 0.002 1 HKG 0 1 PAK 0.448 0
    AUT 0.97 0 HND 0.003 1 PAN 0.13 0
    AZE 0.671 0 HRV 0.25 0 PER 0.07 1
    BDI 0 1 HTI 0.394 0 PHL 0.1 0
    BEL 0.169 0 HUN 0.569 0 PNG 0.004 1
    BEN 0 1 IDN 0 1 POL 0.73 0
    BFA 0.11 0 IND 0 1 PRT 0.086 1
    BGD 0.027 1 IRL 0 1 PRY 0 1
    BGR 0.502 0 IRN 0.003 1 PSE 0.092 1
    BHR 0.8 0 IRQ 0 1 QAT 0.455 0
    BHS 0.112 0 ISL 0.142 0 ROU 0.166 0
    BIH 0.118 0 ISR 0.949 0 RUS 0.004 1
    BLR 0.003 1 ITA 0.011 1 RWA 0 1
    BLZ 0.737 0 JAM 0.251 0 SAU 0 1
    BOL 0.621 0 JOR 0 1 SDN 0.369 0
    BRA 0.081 1 JPN 0 1 SEN 0.001 1
    BRN 0.591 0 KAZ 0 1 SGP 0.051 1
    BTN 0.355 0 KEN 0 1 SLE 0 1
    BWA 0.002 1 KGZ 0.231 0 SLV 0.501 0
    CAN 0 1 KHM 0.002 1 SOM 0.218 0
    CHE 0.209 0 KOR 0 1 SRB 0.307 0
    CHL 0.298 0 KWT 0.001 1 STP 0.002 1
    CHN 0.78 0 LAO 0.003 1 SUR 0.127 0
    CIV 0 1 LBN 0.118 0 SVK 0.001 1
    CMR 0.367 0 LBR 0 1 SVN 0.11 0
    COD 0.003 1 LBY 0.332 0 SWE 0.08 1
    COG 0.017 1 LKA 0.004 1 SWZ 0 1
    COL 0.021 1 LSO 0 1 SYC 0.525 0
    COM 0.026 1 LTU 0.004 1 SYR 0.056 1
    CPV 0.955 0 LUX 0.269 0 TCD 0.376 0
    CRI 0.003 1 LVA 0.708 0 TGO 0.521 0
    CYP 0.173 0 MAC 0.267 0 THA 0.118 0
    CZE 0.46 0 MAR 0.211 0 TJK 0.2 0
    DEU 0.246 0 MDA 0.005 1 TLS 0.006 1
    DJI 0.001 1 MDG 0.005 1 TTO 0 1
    DNK 0.658 0 MDV 0.013 1 TUN 0.361 0
    DOM 0.283 0 MEX 0.683 0 TUR 0 1
    DZA 0.132 0 MKD 0.848 0 TZA 0.396 0
    ECU 0.22 0 MLI 0 1 UGA 0.004 1
    EGY 0 1 MLT 0.427 0 UKR 0.748 0
    ERI 0.005 1 MMR 0 1 URY 0 1
    ESP 0.123 0 MNE 0 1 USA 0.327 0
    EST 0.825 0 MNG 0.007 1 UZB 0 1
    ETH 0 1 MOZ 0.001 1 VEN 0 1
    FIN 0.263 0 MRT 0.004 1 VNM 0 1
    FRA 0.055 1 MUS 0 1 XKX 0.459 0
    GAB 0.189 0 MWI 0 1 YEM 0.161 0
    GBR 0.568 0 MYS 0.973 0 ZAF 0.008 1
    GEO 0.455 0 NAM 0.089 1 ZMB 0.039 1
    GHA 0.278 0 NER 0.089 1 ZWE 0.064 1
    GIN 0.162 0 NGA 0.396 0 AVG 0.19624118 0.53529412
    Note: WB CC means World Bank Country Codes, p-value indicates the one of the country-by-country Granger-causality test with H0 top1*cdbs does not GC gpc, Reject? means whether the null hypothesis is rejected for a country (1) or not (0), and AVG means the average. For the meaning of the country codes, see the footnote in Table 2.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 10.  Robustness of the panel data estimations.
    VARIABLES
    Dependent variable: crisisb
    (1) SYS GINI LAX (2) DIF GINI LAX (3) SYS GINI OECD (4) SYS GINI ECA (5) SYS TOP1 LAX (6) DIF TOP1 LAX (7) SYS TOP1 OECD (8) SYS TOP1 ECA
    crisisbt-1 0.947*** 0.854*** 0.937*** 0.707*** 0.722*** 0.665*** 0.768*** 0.783***
    (0.295) (0.225) (0.271) (0.229) (0.164) (0.118) (0.102) (0.164)
    cdpv 0.00103** 0.00114*** 0.000922** 0.000859***
    (0.000418) (0.000357) (0.000372) (0.000228)
    giniwb −0.0286** −0.0310 −0.0189 −0.00132
    (0.0125) (0.0357) (0.0195) (0.0253)
    inter −0.0337*** −0.0362*** −0.0305*** −0.0283*** −0.0403*** −0.0462*** −0.0363*** −0.0367***
    (0.0130) (0.0119) (0.0116) (0.00706) (0.00728) (0.00410) (0.00625) (0.00669)
    top1 1.361** 1.619*** 1.199* 1.368**
    (0.598) (0.437) (0.679) (0.698)
    cdbs 0.00408*** 0.00466 0.00405 0.00415
    (0.00109) (0.00447) (0.00252) (0.00352)
    gpcgr −0.00817 −0.00519 −0.00703 −0.0136* −0.00149 −0.000386 −0.000666 −0.000694
    (0.00700) (0.00838) (0.00515) (0.00744) (0.00180) (0.00696) (0.00825) (0.00893)
    ps 0.00133 0.00216 0.00123 0.00284 0.00506 0.00447 0.00438 0.00388
    (0.00313) (0.00254) (0.00186) (0.00233) (0.00488) (0.00747) (0.00623) (0.00617)
    tbr −0.00270 −0.00912 0.00378 −0.0116 0.000713 −0.00426 0.000566 0.000177
    (0.0278) (0.0112) (0.0139) (0.0237) (0.00868) (0.0161) (0.0222) (0.0250)
    dinfl 0.00474 0.00613 0.00634 0.00889 0.00220 −0.000537 0.00392 0.00433
    (0.00798) (0.00802) (0.00830) (0.00715) (0.00265) (0.00554) (0.00349) (0.00379)
    xgdp 0.000579 0.00103 0.000269 −0.000493 −0.00156 −0.00130 −0.00129 −0.00156
    (0.00309) (0.00451) (0.00279) (0.00342) (0.00181) (0.00197) (0.00300) (0.00264)
    atms −0.00132 0.000161 −0.000525 −0.000480 0.000488 0.000223 0.000462 0.000399
    (0.00262) (0.000594) (0.00234) (0.00136) (0.000698) (0.00145) (0.00110) (0.00141)
    sec 0.000667 0.00107 0.000912 −0.000323 −0.000855 −0.000520 −0.000396 −0.000328
    (0.00285) (0.00198) (0.00264) (0.00223) (0.00121) (0.00132) (0.000657) (0.00136)
    urban 0.00287 −0.0115 0.00159 0.00240 −0.00456 −0.0141 −0.00365 −0.00426
    (0.00388) (0.0260) (0.00278) (0.00356) (0.00356) (0.00961) (0.00407) (0.00474)
    unem −0.0199 −0.0142 −0.0151 −0.0146 −0.00337 −0.00575 −0.00318 −0.00374
    (0.0251) (0.0218) (0.0231) (0.0208) (0.00694) (0.00620) (0.00884) (0.00816)
    lax −0.00225 −0.0107 −0.0564 −0.0667
    (0.0435) (0.0753) (0.0551) (0.0531)
    oecd 0.143 −0.0372
    (0.209) (0.145)
    eca 0.384 −0.00355
    (0.394) (0.266)
    constant 0.765 1.422 0.360 −0.259 0.225 0.868 0.116 0.144
    (0.629) (2.583) (0.917) (1.201) (0.323) (0.662) (0.344) (0.306)
    Observations 197 137 197 197 329 261 329 329
    Number of countries 32 19 32 32 40 34 40 40
    A-B test 0.4897 0.5140 0.4769 0.5073 0.3930 0.4328 0.3453 0.3397
    Sargan test 0.9688 0.6435 0.9774 0.9775 0.8996 0.4759 0.7570 0.6864
    Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Standard errors are in parenthesis. a: inter is obtained as giniwb*cdpv in models (1)–(4) and as top1*cdbs in models (5)–(8).

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    In order to check the results obtained by Braun et al. (2019) of a positive association of the interaction and income, different univariate OLS, pool, and fixed effects have been developed, showing a positive significant sign in all cases. This confirming their findings but with an additional observation: The interaction may lead to higher GDP. In addition, country-by-country Granger causality tests are performed with the three sub-samples, finding that the inter variable, which is the inequality-credit linkage measured as the product between the income inequality and financial sector size variables, does not GC gpc, so the null hypothesis is rejected in most countries, as shown in Tables 9 and 10 and Figures 1 and 2. Tables 9 and 10 measure the inequality-credit linkage by two alternative ways. Figures 1 and 2 show the results in Tables 9 and 10, respectively.

    Figure 1.  Map showing where the inequality-credit linkage, measured by gini*cdpv, may Granger Cause per capita income.
    Figure 2.  Map showing where the inequality-credit linkage, measured by top1*cdbs, may Granger Cause per capita income.

    The provided conceptual and empirical results lead to some considerations. An increase on income inequality and on the value added of financial services would unchain banking crises. Nonetheless, this negative effect is moderated by the interaction. Furthermore, this leads to reductions in the probability of a banking crisis in world countries even if lax monetary policies implemented by Central Banks in the Ad-Hoc Era (Taylor, 2012) are considered, settling unconventional monetary policies that have resulted in a higher income inequality (Ballabriga and Davtyan, 2021). The isolated effects of the financial development and income inequality variables are positive for banking crises since the coefficients of inequality and credit variables from Tables 5 and 6 are positive and statistically significant. Nonetheless, the coefficient of the interaction has the opposite sign. Thus, the isolated effect of reducing income inequality and the size of the financial sector separately would be beneficial for banking activity but harmful considering the joint association of both variables. This is in line with literature regarding economic growth (Braun et al., 2019, Topuz, 2022, Juuti, 2022). These empirical results also agree with the theoretical expectations in Section 3, concretely, as there is a fulfillment of the Hypothesis proposed in addition to the achievement of Equations (4)–(7).

    The major originalities of this work are, first, the study of the effects of the inequality-credit interaction on the probability of banking crises and, second, the Granger Causality test for panel data on GDP. The results show the beneficial direct effect on banking crises and GDP of reducing income inequality and having a more reasonable financial sector size, while there is an indirect, detrimental collateral effect that originates from the interaction between inequality and credit variables, that is, the inequality–credit interaction. Concerning GDP, a Granger-causality test is checked. The null hypothesis considers the interaction does not GC the GDP expressed in levels and per capita and is rejected with a p-value lower than 0.01 and a positive correlation, while it is not rejected in the opposite direction.

    Therefore, both reasons from the Hypothesis can be valid since the Hypothesis has been empirically checked. The first reason is on the demand side. The inequality-credit linkage could be related with the low-income customers. If there is an increase in the demand of financial services by low-income households, for instance credit, then income inequality rises since these households pay a higher lending rate. Furthermore, and considering only first-round effects, this increase in demand would develop the financial sector more and raise the profits of the financial sector at the current period, reducing the risk of a banking crisis at that time, but maybe not for future periods since there could be a raise on the risk of default from those households. On the other hand, the second-round effects could lead to a reduction in the demand of low-income households due to the high lending interests. The second reason comes from the supply side. While the isolated effects of income inequality and financial sector size may mitigate other economic distortions on the banking sector and reduce the risk of triggering a banking crisis, this effect is hampered by the linkage of both variables, provoking a higher likelihood of unchaining a banking crisis.

    A policy measure would be to design and develop a financial reform to avoid that negative collateral influence of the inequality-credit interaction. For instance, promoting financial services in rural areas—even if they have a lower income—by developing more fin-tech applications and online finance for these regions and promoting financial and technological education would reduce the financial costs for low-income customers, and the interest spread with higher-income customers would be mitigated. The negative effects of inequality and credit expansion on banking crises can be mitigated through policy interventions; for instance, the public sector could subsidize the lower-income defaults given determined conditions, or a new imposition of financial services under VAT can be applied as López-Laborda and Peña (2018) propose. This would help mitigate the negative effects on banking crises of an excessive financial sector.

    In this paper, I develop System and Difference GMM models for analyzing the association of the linkage between financial development and income inequality with the probability of triggering banking crises. An unbalanced panel of 212 countries for the years 1970–2017 is handled. In addition, a recent Granger Causality test for panel data is used with a sample size of 216 countries during the 1960–2021 period and different balanced subsamples. The linkage improves the likelihood of a banking crisis and is associated with a higher economic growth. Robustness checks are applied, confirming the results. It is also found that the individual effect of decreasing income inequality and the financial sector size separately would be an improvement for banking crises, but it would worsen it considering the joint association of both variables. A policy measure is the design and development of a financial reform that avoids negative collateral correlation of the inequality–credit linkage. Jointly fighting for income inequality and the potential excessive size of the financial sector would reduce the collateral effects of the interaction on banking crises.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    Peña, Guillermo, 2025, "Replication Data for: The Inequality–Credit Linkage", https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/J6NWVK, Harvard Dataverse, V1.

    The author expresses his gratitude for the useful comments of the four referees and for the funding received in the "Municipios y serivicios fnancieros: shocks, ratios y efectos" Project, by the Fundación Ibercaja/Universidad de Zaragoza a (JIUZ2022-CSJ-19), the ADETRE Research Group (S39_23R), Interdisciplinary Project on Depopulation (PROY-S15-24) by the Government of Aragon and the research project "CISHO", PID2020-112773GB-I00, by the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Albert JF, Gómez-Fernández N (2021) Monetary Policy and the Redistribution of Net Worth in the US. J Econ Policy Reform, 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1080/17487870.2021.1895778 doi: 10.1080/17487870.2021.1895778
    [2] Alesina AA, Devleeschauwer W, Easterly S, et al. (2003) Fractionalization. J Econ Growth 8: 155–94. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024471506938 doi: 10.1023/A:1024471506938
    [3] Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models. J Econom 68: 29–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
    [4] Ballabriga F, Davtyan K (2021) Distributional impact of monetary policy in the UK: from conventional to unconventional policy. J Econ Policy Reform, 1-16. https://doi.org/10.1080/17487870.2021.1949316 doi: 10.1080/17487870.2021.1949316
    [5] Barro R (2000) Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. J Econ Growth 5: 5–32. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009850119329 doi: 10.1023/A:1009850119329
    [6] Beck T, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Levine R (2007) Finance, inequality and the poor. J Econ Growth 12: 27–49. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-007-9010-6 doi: 10.1007/s10887-007-9010-6
    [7] Benabou R (2000) Unequal Societies: Income Distribution and the Social Contract. Am Econ Rev 90: 96–129. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.1.96 doi: 10.1257/aer.90.1.96
    [8] Binici M, Ganioglu A (2021) Net external position, financial development, and banking crisis. Empir Econ 61: 1225–1251. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01899-z doi: 10.1007/s00181-020-01899-z
    [9] Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models. J Econom 87: 115–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8 doi: 10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
    [10] Bordo MD, Meissner CM (2012) Does inequality lead to a financial crisis. J Int Money Financ 31: 2147–2161. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.05.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.05.006
    [11] Bourguignon F (1981) Pareto Superiority of Unegalitarian Equilibria in Stiglitz' Model of Wealth Distribution with Convex Saving Function. Econometrica 49: 1469–1475. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911412 doi: 10.2307/1911412
    [12] Bouvatier V, El Ouardi S (2023) Credit gaps as banking crisis predictors: a different tune for middle-and low-income countries. Emerg Mark Rev 54: 101001. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ememar.2023.101001 doi: 10.1016/j.ememar.2023.101001
    [13] Braun M, Parro F, Valenzuela P (2019) Does finance alter the relation between inequality and growth?. Econ Inq 57: 410–428. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecin.12581 doi: 10.1111/ecin.12581
    [14] Brueckner M, Lederman D (2015) Effects of Income Inequality on Aggregate Output. Policy Research Working Paper Series 7317, The World Bank. Available from: https://hdl.handle.net/10986/22203.
    [15] Bruns SB, Ioannidis JP (2020) Determinants of economic growth: Different time different answer?. J Macroecon 63: 103185. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2019.103185 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2019.103185
    [16] Büyükkarabacak B, Valev NT (2010) The role of household and business credit in banking crises. J Bank Financ 34: 1247–1256. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.11.022 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.11.022
    [17] Castelló-Climent A (2010) Inequality and Growth in Advanced Economies: An Empirical Investigation. J Econ Inequal 8: 293–321. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10888-010-9133-4 doi: 10.1007/s10888-010-9133-4
    [18] Cecchetti SG, Kharroubi E (2019) Why does credit growth crowd out real economic growth?. Manch Sch 87: 1–28. https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12295 doi: 10.1111/manc.12295
    [19] Chang X, Li G, Gu X, et al. (2020) Does the inequality-credit-crisis nexus exist? An empirical re-examination. Appl Econ 52: 4044–4057. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2020.1730757 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2020.1730757
    [20] Chirwa TG, Odhiambo NM (2016) Macroeconomic determinants of economic growth: A review of international literature. S E Eur J Econ Bus 11: 33–47. https://doi.org/10.1515/jeb-2016-0009 doi: 10.1515/jeb-2016-0009
    [21] Claessens S, Perotti E (2005) The links between finance and inequality: channels and evidence. Available from: https://www.rrojasdatabank.info/wir2006/claessens.pdf.
    [22] Claessens S, Perotti E (2007) Finance and inequality: Channels and evidence. J Comp Econ 35: 748–773. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2007.07.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jce.2007.07.002
    [23] Clarke GRG, Xu LC, Zou H (2006) Finance and income inequality: What do the data tell us?. South Econ J 72: 578–596. https://doi.org/10.2307/20111834 doi: 10.2307/20111834
    [24] Cruz-García P, Forte A, Peiró-Palomino J (2020) On the drivers of profitability in the banking industry in restructuring times: a Bayesian perspective. Appl Econ Anal 28: 111–131. https://doi.org/10.1108/AEA-01-2020-0003 doi: 10.1108/AEA-01-2020-0003
    [25] Dabla-Norris ME, Kochhar MK, Suphaphiphat MN, et al. (2015) Causes and consequences of income inequality: a global perspective. International Monetary Fund. Available from: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Staff-Discussion-Notes/Issues/2016/12/31/Causes-and-Consequences-of-Income-Inequality-A-Global-Perspective-42986.
    [26] De Haan J, Sturm J (2017) Finance and income inequality: A review and new evidence. Eur J Polit Econ 50: 171–195. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.04.007 doi: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.04.007
    [27] Demirgüç-Kunt A, Detragiache E (1998) The Determinants of Banking Crises in Developing and Developed Countries. IMF Staff Papers 45: 81–109. https://doi.org/10.2307/3867330 doi: 10.2307/3867330
    [28] Demirgüç-Kunt A, Levine R (2009) Finance and inequality: Theory and evidence. NBER Working Paper 15275: 1–57. DOI10.3386/w15275
    [29] Easterly W (2007) Inequality Does Cause Underdevelopment. J Dev Econ 84: 755–776. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.11.002
    [30] El Herradi M, Leroy A (2022) The rich, poor, and middle class: Banking crises and income distribution. J Int Money Financ 127: 102695. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102695 doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102695
    [31] Fischer R, Huerta D, Valenzuela P (2019) The inequality-credit nexus. J Int Money Financ 91: 105–125. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.11.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.11.004
    [32] Forbes KJ (2000) A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and Growth. Am Econ Rev 90: 869–887. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.4.869 doi: 10.1257/aer.90.4.869
    [33] Frankel J, Saravelos G (2012) Can leading indicators assess country vulnerability? Evidence from the 2008–09 global financial crisis. J Int Econ 87: 216–231. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.12.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.12.009
    [34] Freeman R (2010) Does Inequality Increase Economic Output?, In: Controversies about Inequality, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
    [35] Frost J, Gambacorta L, Gambacorta R (2022) On the nexus between wealth inequality, financial development and financial technology. J Econ Behav Organ 202: 429–451. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2022.08.011 doi: 10.1016/j.jebo.2022.08.011
    [36] Galor O, Zeira J (1993) Income Distribution and Macroeconomics. Rev Econ Stud 60: 35–52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297811 doi: 10.2307/2297811
    [37] Gavin M, Hausmann R (1996) The Roots of Banking Crises: The Macroeconomic Context, In: Hausmann, R., Rojas-Suárez, L. (Ed.), Banking crises in Latin America, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, D.C., 25–63. http://dx.doi.org/10.18235/0011541
    [38] Ghosh S, Doğan B, Can M, et al. (2022) Does economic structure matter for ıncome ınequality?. Qual Quant 57: 2507–2527. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11135-022-01462-1 doi: 10.1007/s11135-022-01462-1
    [39] Goldstein M, Turner P (1996) Banking crises in emerging economies: origins and policy options, In: Trade Currencies and Finance, 301–363. https://doi.org/10.1142/9789814749589_0008
    [40] Greenwood J, Jovanovic B (1990) Financial Development, Growth, and the Income Distribution. J Political Econ 98: 1076–1107. https://doi.org/10.1086/261720 doi: 10.1086/261720
    [41] Gu X, Huang B (2014) Does inequality lead to a financial crisis? Revisited. Rev Dev Econ 18: 502–516. https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12099 doi: 10.1111/rode.12099
    [42] Huizinga H (2002) A European VAT on financial services?. Econ Policy 17: 497–534. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0327.00095 doi: 10.1111/1468-0327.00095
    [43] Ibrahim MH (2024) Monetary policy, financial development and income inequality in developing countries. Singap Econ Rev 69: 859–889. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0217590821410010 doi: 10.1142/S0217590821410010
    [44] Jauch S, Watzka S (2016) Financial development and income inequality: A panel data approach. Empir Econ 51: 291–314. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1008-x doi: 10.1007/s00181-015-1008-x
    [45] Juodis A, Karavias Y, Sarafidis V (2021) A homogeneous approach to testing for Granger non-causality in heterogeneous panels. Empir Econ 60: 93–112. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01970-9 doi: 10.1007/s00181-020-01970-9
    [46] Juuti T (2022) The role of financial development in the relationship between income inequality and economic growth: an empirical approach using cross-country panel data. Qual Quant 56: 985–1021. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11135-021-01163-1 doi: 10.1007/s11135-021-01163-1
    [47] Kaldor N (1957) A Model of Economic Growth. Econ J 67: 591–624. https://doi.org/10.2307/2227704 doi: 10.2307/2227704
    [48] Kauko K (2014) How to foresee banking crises? A survey of the empirical literature. Econ Syst 38: 289–308. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2014.01.001 doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2014.01.001
    [49] Kavya TB, Shijin S (2020) Economic development, financial development, and income inequality nexus. Borsa Istanb Rev 20: 80–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2019.12.002 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2019.12.002
    [50] Keynes JM (1919) The Economic Consequences of the Peace (1 ed.), London: Macmillan & Co., Limited. p. 279.
    [51] Kim DH, Lin SC (2011) Nonlinearity in the financial development–income inequality nexus. J Comp Econ 39: 3108–325. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2011.07.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jce.2011.07.002
    [52] Kruger JJ (2008) Productivity and structural change: A review of the literature. J Econ Surv 22: 330–363. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2007.00539.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6419.2007.00539.x
    [53] Kumhof M, Rancière R, Winant P (2015) Inequality, leverage, and crises. Am Econ Rev 105: 1217–1245. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20110683 doi: 10.1257/aer.20110683
    [54] Kuznets S (1955) Economic growth and income inequality. Am Econ Rev 45: 1–28.
    [55] Laeven L (2011) Banking crises: A review. Annu Rev Financ Econ 3: 17–40. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-financial-102710-144816 doi: 10.1146/annurev-financial-102710-144816
    [56] Laeven L, Valencia F (2013) Systemic banking crises database. IMF Econ Rev 61: 225–270. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2013.12 doi: 10.1057/imfer.2013.12
    [57] Lewis WA (1954) Economic Development with Unlimited Supply of Labor. Manch Sch 22: 139–191. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.tb00021.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.tb00021.x
    [58] Lee KS, Werner RA (2018) Reconsidering monetary policy: An empirical examination of the relationship between interest rates and nominal GDP growth in the US, UK, Germany and Japan. Ecol Econ 146: 26–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.013 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.013
    [59] Li H, Zou H (1998) Income Inequality Is Not Harmful for Growth: Theory and Evidence. Rev Dev Econ 2: 318–334. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9361.00045 doi: 10.1111/1467-9361.00045
    [60] López-Laborda J, Peña G (2018) A new method for applying VAT to financial services. Natl Tax J 71: 155–182. https://doi.org/10.17310/ntj.2018.1.05 doi: 10.17310/ntj.2018.1.05
    [61] López-Laborda J, Peña G (2022) Financial VAT may improve trade openness. Appl Econ 54: 2148–2160. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2021.1985072 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2021.1985072
    [62] Magwedere MR (2023) Credit-inequality nexus: the role of natural resources. Econ Env 86: 508–526. https://doi.org/10.34659/eis.2023.86.3.646 doi: 10.34659/eis.2023.86.3.646
    [63] Mathonnat C, Minea A (2018) Financial development and the occurrence of banking crises. J Bank Financ 96: 344–354. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2018.09.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2018.09.005
    [64] Mo PH (2000) Income inequality and economic growth. Kyklos 53: 293–315. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6435.00122 doi: 10.1111/1467-6435.00122
    [65] Neaime S, Gaysset I (2018) Financial inclusion and stability in MENA: Evidence from poverty and inequality. Financ Res Lett 24: 230–237. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2017.09.007 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2017.09.007
    [66] Pal S, Villanthenkodath MA, Patel G, et al. (2021) The impact of remittance inflows on economic growth, unemployment and income inequality: an international evidence. Int J Econ Policy Stud 16: 211–235. https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-021-00074-1 doi: 10.1007/s42495-021-00074-1
    [67] Panizza U (2002) Income Inequality and Economic Growth: Evidence from American Data. J Econ Growth 7: 25–41. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1013414509803 doi: 10.1023/A:1013414509803
    [68] Peña G (2017) Money, Lending and Banking Crises. Econ Pap 36: 444–458. https://doi.org/10.1111/1759-3441.12195 doi: 10.1111/1759-3441.12195
    [69] Peña G (2020) VAT experience as an influence on banking crises. Natl Account Rev 2: 53–65. https://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2020003 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020003
    [70] Peña G (2022) Economic Policies for the COVID-19 pandemic: Lessons from the Great Recession, In: Hassan, S.A., Mohamed, A.W., Alnowibet, K.A., Decision Sciences for COVID-19: Learning Through Case Studies, Springer, 425–455. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-87019-5_24
    [71] Pereira Pedro C, Ramalho JJ, da Silva JV (2018) The main determinants of banking crises in OECD countries. Rev World Econ 154: 203–227. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-017-0294-0 doi: 10.1007/s10290-017-0294-0
    [72] Perugini C, Hölscher J, Collie S (2015) Inequality, credit and financial crises. Camb J Econ 40: 227–257. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beu075 doi: 10.1093/cje/beu075
    [73] Rajan R (2010) Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
    [74] Rhee DE, Kim H (2018) Does income inequality lead to banking crises in developing countries? Empirical evidence from cross-country panel data. Econ Sys 42: 206–218. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2017.08.007 doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2017.08.007
    [75] Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J 9: 86–136. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0900900106
    [76] Schreiner M, Colombet HH (2001) From urban to rural: Lessons for microfinance from Argentina. Dev Policy Rev 19: 339-354. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-7679.00138 doi: 10.1111/1467-7679.00138
    [77] Smith A (1776) The Wealth of Nations, New York: Modem Library.
    [78] Song Q, Li J, Wu Y, et al. (2020) Accessibility of financial services and household consumption in China: evidence from micro data. N Am J Econ Financ 53: 101213. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2020.101213 doi: 10.1016/j.najef.2020.101213
    [79] Tan HB, Law SH (2012) Nonlinear dynamics of the inequality–credit nexus in developing countries. J Econ Inequal 10: 551–563. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10888-011-9174-3 doi: 10.1007/s10888-011-9174-3
    [80] Taylor JB (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39: 195–214. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-L doi: 10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-L
    [81] Taylor JB (2012) Monetary policy rules work and discretion doesn't: A tale of two eras. J Money Credit Bank 44: 1017–1032. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2012.00521.x doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4616.2012.00521.x
    [82] Topuz SG (2022) The Relationship Between Income Inequality and Economic Growth: Are Transmission Channels Effective?. Soc Indic Res 162: 1177–1231. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-022-02882-0 doi: 10.1007/s11205-022-02882-0
    [83] Ullah S, Akhtar P, Zaefarian G (2018) Dealing with endogeneity bias: The generalized method of moments (GMM) for panel data. Ind Market Manag 71: 69–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010 doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.11.010
    [84] Von Hagen J, Ho TK (2007) Money market pressure and the determinants of banking crises. J Money Credit Bank 39: 1037–1066. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2007.00057.x doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4616.2007.00057.x
    [85] Wang S (2023) Income inequality and systemic banking crises: A nonlinear nexus. Econ Sys 47: 101123. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2023.101123 doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2023.101123
    [86] Windmeijer F (2005) A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Efficient Two-Step GMM Estimators. J Econom 126: 25–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
    [87] Xiao J, Karavias Y, Sarafidis V, et al. (2023) XTGRANGERT: Stata module for improved Granger non-causality testing in heterogeneous and homogeneous panel data. EconPapers.
    [88] Xu C, Giedeman DC, Compton RA, et al. (2018) Banking and inequality: US state evidence. Soc Sci J 55: 396–403. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.soscij.2018.07.0 doi: 10.1016/j.soscij.2018.07.0
    [89] Zhang R, Naceur SB (2019) Financial development, inequality, and poverty: Some international evidence. Int Rev Econ Financ 61: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2018.12.015 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2018.12.015
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2025 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(154) PDF downloads(21) Cited by(0)

Figures and Tables

Figures(2)  /  Tables(10)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog