Citation: Dimitrios G. Konstantinides. Ruin probabilities for a double renewal risk model with frequent premium arrivals[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 717-732. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.717
[1] | Lianzhang Bao, Guangliang Zhao, Zhuo Jin . A new equilibrium trading model with asymmetric information. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 217-229. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.217 |
[2] | Keming Li . Relative mispricing and takeover likelihood. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(4): 689-715. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021031 |
[3] | Anwen Yin . Equity premium prediction: keep it sophisticatedly simple. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(2): 264-286. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021012 |
[4] | Ludovic Mathys . Valuing tradeability in exponential Lévy models. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(3): 459-488. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020021 |
[5] | Arifenur Güngör, Hüseyin Taştan . On macroeconomic determinants of co-movements among international stock markets: evidence from DCC-MIDAS approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(1): 19-39. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021002 |
[6] | Francesco Audrino, Lorenzo Camponovo, Constantin Roth . Wild multiplicative bootstrap for M and GMM estimators in time series. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(1): 165-186. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.1.165 |
[7] | Donatien Hainaut . Continuous Mixed-Laplace Jump Diffusion Models for Stocks and Commodities. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(2): 145-173. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.2.145 |
[8] | Yinghua Ren, Weiwen Gu . The Impact on RMB Internationalization Process: Exchange Rate Expectation and Foreign Trade. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(1): 114-124. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.1.114 |
[9] | Kuashuai Peng, Guofeng Yan . A survey on deep learning for financial risk prediction. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(4): 716-737. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021032 |
[10] | Per B. Solibakke . Forecasting hourly WTI oil front monthly price volatility densities. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(3): 466-501. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024018 |
We consider the asymptotics of ruin probabilities in the renewal risk model with constant force of interest. In this model the claim sizes,
N1(t)=#{n:τn≤t},t≥0. |
Therefore, the compound renewal process
The premium sizes,
N2(s)=#{n:σn≤s}=N(Λs),s≥0. |
where
Let
˜Uδ(t)=xeδt+∫t0eδ(t−y)dC(y)−∫t0eδ(t−x)dS(x),t≥0. |
Let consider the discounted surplus through the formula
Uδ(t):=˜Uδ(t)e−δt=x+∫t0e−δydC(y)−∫t0e−δxdS(x)=x+N(Λt)∑k=1Yke−δσk−N1(t)∑n=1Zne−δτn, |
for any
Now we introduce a sequence of random variables
Considering as given, that the premium arrivals are much more frequent in comparison with the occurrences of claims, we take as basic time cycle the inter-occurrence times. In practical set up, the premium can be received every week but the claims are expected to occur every year. Let introduce successively the following random variables
X1=Z1−N(Λτ1)∑k=1Y∗keδ(τ1−σk)=Z1−N(Λθ1)∑k=1Y∗keδ(θ1−σk),X2=Z2−N(Λτ2)∑k=N(Λτ1)+1Y∗keδ(τ2−σk),………Xn=Zn−N(Λτn)∑k=N(Λτn−1)+1Y∗keδ(τn−σk), | (1.1) |
through which we obtain
Uδ(t)d=x−N1(t)∑n=1Xne−δτn, | (1.2) |
for any
In the actuarial literature, the probability of ultimate ruin is defined to be the probability that the surplus falls below zero. This probability has been extensively investigated.
Let us define the ultimate ruin probability as
ψδ(x)=P(infs≥0Uδ(s)<0|Uδ(0)=x)=P(M∞>x),x≥0, | (1.3) |
which represents the distribution tail of the supremum
M∞:=supm≥1m∑n=1Xne−δτn=supm≥1Sm, | (1.4) |
with
Here and henceforth, all limit relationships are for
A real-valued random variable
E[eεX]=∫∞−∞eεxF(dx)=∞. |
A distribution
limˉF(x−y)ˉF(x)=1. |
A distribution
lim¯Fn∗(x)ˉF(x)=n, |
where
A distribution
lim supˉF(xy)ˉF(x)<∞. |
The intersection
A distribution
limy↑1lim supˉF(xy)ˉF(x)=1, |
or equivalently the following holds
limy↓1lim supˉF(xy)ˉF(x)=1. |
A distribution
y−α≤lim infˉF(xy)ˉF(x)≤lim supˉF(xy)ˉF(x)≤y−β. |
A distribution
limˉF(xy)ˉF(x)=y−α. |
It is well known that
R−α⊂ERV(−β,−α)⊂C⊂B⊂S⊂L⊂K. |
For a distribution
βF=−limlnMF(x)lnx,αF=−limlnMF(x)lnx, |
where for any
MF(x)=lim supu→∞ˉF(xu)ˉF(u),MF(x)=lim supu→∞ˉF(xu)ˉF(u), |
If
For a subexponential distribution
lim supˉF(vx)ˉF(x)<1. |
If
Let consider the sequence of real-valued random variables
limP[|Xi|∧Xj>x|Xi∨Xj>0]=0. |
Further following the work (Geluk and Tang, 2009) we say that the
limxi∧xj→∞P[|Xi|>xi|Xj>xj]=0. |
We say that the
P[n⋂k=1{Xk≤xk}]≤gL(n)n∏k=1P[Xk≤xk],P[n⋂k=1{Xk>xk}]≤gU(n)n∏k=1P[Xk>xk], |
hold. This dependent structure was introduced in (Wang et al., 2003).
We say that the
P[n⋂k=1{Xk≤xk}]≤Mn∏k=1P[Xk≤xk],P[n⋂k=1{Xk>xk}]≤Mn∏k=1P[Xk>xk], |
hold. This notion was introduced in (Liu, 2009).
When in these two relations the value of the constant is
It is well known the inclusions
NQD⊂END⊂WOD⊂TAI⊂pQAI. |
Now, we study the asymptotic behaviour of the distribution tail of the discounted sums in (1.1). By the total probability formula we obtain
P(N(Λθ1)∑k=1Ykeδ(θ1−σk)>x)=∫∞0∫∞0P(N(qt)∑k=1Ykeδ(t−σk)>x|θ1=t,Λ=q)Q(dq)A(dt)=∫∞0∫∞0∞∑n=1P(n∑k=1Ykeδ(t−σk)>x|θ1=t,Λ=q,N(qt)=n)P(N(qt)=n)×Q(dq)A(dt). |
Next, we employ Theorem 2.3.1 from (Ross, 1983) to express the conditional distribution of the random vector
P(N(Λθ1)∑k=1Ykeδ(θ1−σk)>x)=∫∞0∫∞0∞∑n=1P(n∑k=1YkeδtUk>x|θ1=t,Λ=q,N(qt)=n)P(N(qt)=n)×Q(dq)A(dt)=∫∞0P(N(Λt)∑k=1YkeδtUk>x|θ1=t)A(dt). |
Let us denote
Lemma 2.1. If the random variables
P(N(Λt)∑k=1YkeδtUk>x)∼P(N(Λt)μt>x), |
for any
Proof. We check the conditions of Theorem 4.1 (b) from (Chen et al., 2010). As far the uniform random variables
From the fact that the products are non-negative and non-degenerate, we obtain the positive mean value
Next, from the fact that
N←(yx)N←(x)→y, |
from where we get
limy↑1lim supP[N(Λt)>yx]P[N(Λt)>x]=limy↑1lim supP[Λ>N←(yx)/t]P[Λ>N←(x)/t]=limy↑1lim supP[Λ>yN←(x)/t]P[Λ>N←(x)/t]=1, |
where the last equality comes from
P(YeδtU>x)=o(P[N(Λt)>x]). |
Now we just apply Theorem 4.1 (b) from (Chen et al., 2010) to take the required result.
We observe that
Lemma 2.2. In addition to the other conditions of Lemma 2.1, if
P(N(Λt)∑k=1YkeδtUk>x)∼P(Λt>xμt), |
for any
Proof. Following the expression found in Lemma 2.1, for any
P(N(Λt)>xμt)=∫∞0P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)=(∫x/(μt+ε)0+∫x/(μt−ε)x/(μt+ε)+∫∞x/(μt−ε))P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)=I1+I2+I3. |
Let us observe that the main term is the last one. Indeed, taking into account the SLLN we obtain the convergence
I3=∫∞x/(μt−ε)P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)≥∫∞x/(μt−ε)P(N(q)q>μt−εμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)→P(Λt>xμt−ε), |
as
I3=∫∞x/(μt−ε)P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)≤P(Λt>xμt−ε), |
so after leaving the
I3∼P(Λt>xμt). |
Next, we calculate the asymptotics of
I2=∫x/(μt−ε)x/(μt+ε)P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)≤P(xμt+ε≤Λt≤xμt−ε)=P(Λt≤xμt−ε)−P(Λt≤xμt+ε)∼[(μt+ε)α−(μt−ε)α]P(Λt>x)=o[P(Λt>xμt)], |
as
Next, we consider
I1=∫x/(μt+ε)0P(N(q)>xμt|Λt=q)P(Λt∈dq)≤P[N(xμt+ε)>xμt]=P[⌊x/μt⌋∑i=1ζ′i≤xμt+ε]. |
Now for an arbitrarily chosen variable
I1≤exp{hxμt+ε}E[exp{−h⌊x/μt⌋∑i=1ζ′i}]∼exp{hxμt+ε}(E[e−hζ′1])x/μt∼exp{(hμtμt+ε+lnE[e−hζ′1])xμt}. |
Now we choose some positive value for
v(h):=hμtμt+ε+lnE(e−hζ′1), |
becomes negative. This is possible because for
v′(h):=μtμt+ε−E(ζ′1e−hζ′1)E(e−hζ′1), |
due to the fact that
I1∼exp{v(h)xμt}=o[P(Λt>xμt)], |
which makes the first term also negligible.
Next, consider the case with regular varying tails of distributions of the random variables
¯F(x)=P[X>x]=P(Z−N(Λθ)∑k=1Y∗keδ(θ−σk)>x), | (3.1) |
From Theorem 3.1 in (Tang and Tsitsiashvili, 2003) we can find easily:
Lemma 3.1. If
ˉF(x)=o(x−β),∀β<βF,xαˉF(x)→∞,∀α>αF,0≤βF≤αF<∞, |
hold.
Now we assume that the joint distribution of
1¯B(x)P((Λ,Z)x∈⋅)v→ν(⋅) on [0,∞]d∖{0}. |
In this case, we write
We introduce now the event
Ax,t:={(Z,Λ):Z−Λtμt>x}={(Z,Λ):Z−ΛtE[Y1eδtU1]>x}, |
for any
Lemma 3.2. The following asymptotic relation is true
ˉF(x)∼ˉB(x)E[ν(A1,θ)]. |
Proof. Through Lemma 3.1 we find that
¯F(x)=∫∞0P[N(Λθ)∑m=1Y∗meδ(θ−σm)<z−x]B(dz)=∫∞0(1−∫∞0P[N(Λt)∑m=1Y∗meδtUm≥z−x|θ=t]A(dt))B(dz)∼∫∞0(1−∫∞0P[Λtμt≥z−x|θ=t]A(dt))B(dz)=∫∞0P[Λtμt<z−x|θ=t]A(dt)B(dz)=∫∞0P[Z−Λtμt>x|θ=t]A(dt). |
Now we employ the multivariate regular variation of the
¯F(x)=∫∞0P[Λθ∑m=1Y∗meδ(θ−σm)<z−x]B(dz)∼∫∞0¯B(x)ν[A1,t]A(dt)=¯B(x)E(ν[A1,θ]). |
Proposition 3.3. Let the real-valued random variables
ψδ(x)∼∞∑n=1P[e−δτnXn>x], |
holds if either of the following conditions are true:
(i) If
∞∑n=1(E[e−αδτn]+E[e−βδτn])<∞. |
(ii) If
∞∑n=1(E[e−αδτn]+E[e−βδτn])1/α<∞. |
Proof. We follow the argument developed in Theorem 2 from (Yi et al., 2011). However, we omit the condition
We begin with the lower asymptotic bound. For any
ψδ(x)=P[supn≥1n∑k=1e−δτkXk>x]≥P[sup1≤n≤mn∑k=1e−δτkXk>x]m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]≳lim infx→∞m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]=lim infx→∞(∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]−∞∑k=m+1P[e−δτkXk>x])=∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x](1−lim supx→∞∞∑k=m+1P[e−δτkXk>x]∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]), |
where in the second line we used Theorem 2.1 from (Ignataviciute et al., 2018) in combination with Theorem 1 from (Yi et al., 2011). Further by Theorem 3.3 from (Cline and Samorodnitksy, 1994) we have
ψδ(x)≳∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x](1−C∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])). |
Next, letting
For the upper asymptotic bound we see that for any
ψδ(x)≤P[sup1≤n≤mn∑k=1e−δτkXk>(1−v)x]+P[∞∑k=m+1e−δτkX+k>vx]=P1+P2. |
For the first term we find
P1≲lim supP[sup1≤n≤mn∑k=1e−δτkXk>(1−v)x]m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>(1−v)x]m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>(1−v)x]m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]×m∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]≤MF(1−v)∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]. |
For the second term we can obtain
P2≲CMF1(v)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]. |
Indeed, from the elementary inequality
P2≤∞∑k=m+1P[e−δτkX+k>vx]+P[∞∑k=m+1e−δτkX+k1{e−δτkX+k≤vx}>vx]≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+1(vx)α(E[∞∑k=m+1e−δτkX+k1{e−δτkX+k≤vx}])α≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+1(vx)α∞∑k=m+1E[(e−δτkX+k1{e−δτkX≤kvx})α]≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+C2∞∑k=m+1P[e−δτkXk>vx]≤(C1+C2)ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk]). |
Hence, using again the weak equivalence
P2≲(C1+C2)MF(v)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]. |
After substitution we have
ψδ(x)≲(MF(1−v)+(C1+C2)MF(v)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk]))×∞∑k=1P[e−δτkXk>x]. |
Now letting
Under the condition
P2≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+1(vx)α(E[∞∑k=m+1e−δτkX+k1{e−δτkX+k≤vx}])α≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+1(vx)α∞∑k=m+1E[(e−δτkX+k1{e−δτkX≤kvx})α]≤C1ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk])+C2∞∑k=m+1P[e−δτkXk>vx]≤(C1+C2)ˉF(vx)∞∑k=m+1(E[e−αFδτk]∨E[e−βFδτk]). |
Remark 3.4. We observe that given that
E[e−αδτn]=(E[e−αδθ1])n,E[e−βδτn]=(E[e−βδθ1])n, |
and taking into account that
Hence, using the property of class
Corollary 3.5. If the sequence
N(Λθn)∑k=1e−δσkY∗k≤C, | (3.2) |
holds almost surely, and the positive random variables
ψδ(x)∼∞∑n=1P[e−δτnZn>x]. | (3.3) |
Proof. Since we have the sequence
e−δτnXn=e−δτnZn−N(Λθn)∑k=1e−δσkY∗k, |
Therefore, from the condition
Now from the double inequality
Now, we are ready to provide the final asymptotic expression for the ruin probability
Theorem 3.6. Let the random variables
ψδ(x)∼E[e−αδθ]1−E[e−αδθ]E[ν(A1,θ)]¯B(x). | (3.4) |
Proof. From the formulas (1.2) and (1.3) we conclude that
x−∞∑n=1Xne−δτn≤˜Uδ(t)≤x−∞∑n=1Xne−δτn1{τn≤t}, | (3.5) |
and further taking into account the regular variation of the distribution
ψδ(x)≤P[∞∑n=1Xne−δτn>x]=¯F(x)∞∑n=1E[Xne−αδτn]=¯F(x)E[e−αδθ]1−E[e−αδθ]. | (3.6) |
Next, for the lower bound we find
ψδ(x)≥P[supt≥0∞∑n=1Xne−δτn1{τn≤t}>x]=P[∞∑n=1Xne−δτn>x]∼¯F(x)∞∑n=1E[e−αδτn]=¯F(x)E[e−αδθ]1−E[e−αδθ]. |
So with combination of the previous bounds we have
ψδ(x)∼¯F(x)E[e−αδθ]1−E[e−αδθ]. | (3.7) |
Finally after substitution from Lemma 3.2 we conclude the result.
Remark 3.7. For
I would like to thank Prof. S. Kou for the suggestion of this topic and to two anonymous referees for their several constructive comments.
The author declares no conflict of interest.
[1] | Bingham NH, Goldie CM, Teugels JL (1987) Regular Variation, New York: Cambridge University Press. |
[2] | Chen Y, Chen A, Ng KW (2010) The strong law of large numbers for extended negatively dependent random variables. J Appl Probab 46: 908–922. |
[3] |
Chen Y, Yuen KC (2009) Sums of pairwise quasi-asymptotically independent random variables with consistent variation. Stoch Models 25: 76–89. doi: 10.1080/15326340802641006
![]() |
[4] |
Chistyakov VP (1964) A theorem on sums of independent positive random variables and its applications to branching random processes. Theory Probab Appl 9: 640–648. doi: 10.1137/1109088
![]() |
[5] |
Cline DBH, Samorodnitksy G (1994) Subexponentiality of the product of independent random variables. Stochast Proc Appl 49: 75–98. doi: 10.1016/0304-4149(94)90113-9
![]() |
[6] | Ignataviciute E, Ragulina O, Siaulys J (2018) Expectation of the truncated randomly weighted sums with dominatingly varying summands. Lithuanian Math J (submitted). |
[7] |
Gao Q, Wang Y (2010) Randomly weighted sums with dominated varying-tailed increments and application to risk theory. J Korean Stat Society 39: 305–314. doi: 10.1016/j.jkss.2010.02.004
![]() |
[8] | Geluk J, Tang Q (2009) Asymptotic tail probabilities of sums of dependent subexponential random variables. J Teoret Probab 22: 871–882. |
[9] |
Goldie CM (1978) Subexponential distributions and dominated-variation tails. J Appl Probab 15: 440–442. doi: 10.2307/3213416
![]() |
[10] | Konstantinides DG (2017) Risk Theory: A Heavy Tail Approach., New Jersey: World Scientific. |
[11] |
Liu L (2009) Precise large deviations for dependent random variables with heavy tails. Stat Probab Lett 79: 1290–1298. doi: 10.1016/j.spl.2009.02.001
![]() |
[12] | Nelsen RB (2006) An Introduction to Copulas, Berlin: Springer. |
[13] | Resnick SI, Willekens E (1991) Moving averages with random coe_cients and random coefficient autoregressive models. Stoch Models 7: 511–525. |
[14] |
Robert CY, Segers JH (2008) Tails of random sums of a heavy-tailed number of light-tailed terms. Insur Math Econ 43: 85–92. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.10.001
![]() |
[15] | Ross SM (1983) Stochastic Processes, New York: Wiley. |
[16] |
Schmidli H (1999) Compound sums and subexponentiality. Bernoulli 5: 999–1012. doi: 10.2307/3318556
![]() |
[17] | Tang QH (2005) Asymptotic ruin probabilities of the renewal model with constant interest force and regular variation. Scand Actuar J 1: 1–5. |
[18] | Tang QH, Tsitsiashvili G (2003a) Precise estimates for the ruin probability in finite horizon in a discrete-time model with heavy-tailed insurance and financial risks. Stochastic Process Appl 108: 299–325. |
[19] | Tang QH, Tsitsiashvili G (2003b) Randomly weighted sums of subexponential random variables with application to ruin theory. Extremes 6: 171–188. |
[20] | Wang KY, Wang YB, Gao QW (2003) Uniform asymptotics for the finte-time ruin probability of a dependent risk model with a constant interest rate. Methodol Comput Appl Probab 15: 109–124. |
[21] |
Yi L, Chen Y, Su C (2011) Approximation of the tail probability of randomly weighted sums of dependent random variables with dominated variation. J Math Anal Appl 376: 365–372. doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2010.10.020
![]() |
1. | Hao Dong, Zhenghui Li, Pierre Failler, The Impact of Business Cycle on Health Financing: Subsidized, Voluntary and Out-of-Pocket Health Spending, 2020, 17, 1660-4601, 1928, 10.3390/ijerph17061928 |