Research article Special Issues

Diversification effect of commodity futures on financial markets

  • This paper examines the portfolio diversification effect of commodity futures on financial market products introducing a comprehensive evaluation standard of risk standardization, robustly small correlation, and risk-return tradeo. Regarding risk standardization, we propose a definition of portfolio diversification as how much the distribution of portfolio returns is close to a normal distribution. It is shown by using an ɑ-stable distribution that if commodity price return distribution has the opposite sign of skewness parameter β to financial portfolio's β, commodity diversification e ect exists. The empirical studies using S & P 500, U.S. 10-year treasury notes, and DJ-AIG commodity index are conducted to investigate the portfolio diversification e ects. The parameter estimation results of portfolio return distributions, the conditional correlations using the dynamic conditional correlation model with financial exogenous variables, and the e cient frontier from the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization all suggest that commodity futures have a diversification e ect on financial markets.

    Citation: Takashi Kanamura. Diversification effect of commodity futures on financial markets[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 821-836. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.821

    Related Papers:

    [1] Buerhan Saiti, Abdulnasir Dahiru, Ibrahim Guran Yumusak . Diversification benefits in energy, metal and agricultural commodities for Islamic investors: evidence from multivariate GARCH approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 733-756. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.733
    [2] Kim Hiang Liow, Jeongseop Song, Xiaoxia Zhou . Volatility connectedness and market dependence across major financial markets in China economy. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(3): 397-420. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021018
    [3] Lucjan T. Orlowski, Monika Sywak . Wavering interactions between commodity futures prices and us dollar exchange rates. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(2): 221-243. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.2.221
    [4] Sang Phu Nguyen, Toan Luu Duc Huynh . Portfolio optimization from a Copulas-GJR-GARCH-EVT-CVAR model: Empirical evidence from ASEAN stock indexes. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(3): 562-585. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.3.562
    [5] Joseph Atta-Mensah . Commodity-linked bonds as an innovative financing instrument for African countries to build back better. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(3): 516-541. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021023
    [6] Mitchell Ratner, Chih-Chieh (Jason) Chiu . Portfolio Effects of VIX Futures Index. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(3): 288-299. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.3.288
    [7] David G. McMillan . The information content of the stock and bond return correlation. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 757-775. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.757
    [8] Samuel Kwaku Agyei, Ahmed Bossman . Investor sentiment and the interdependence structure of GIIPS stock market returns: A multiscale approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(1): 87-116. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023005
    [9] Makoto Nakakita, Teruo Nakatsuma . Analysis of the trading interval duration for the Bitcoin market using high-frequency transaction data. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2025, 9(1): 202-241. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2025007
    [10] Zheng Nan, Taisei Kaizoji . Bitcoin-based triangular arbitrage with the Euro/U.S. dollar as a foreign futures hedge: modeling with a bivariate GARCH model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(2): 347-365. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.2.347
  • This paper examines the portfolio diversification effect of commodity futures on financial market products introducing a comprehensive evaluation standard of risk standardization, robustly small correlation, and risk-return tradeo. Regarding risk standardization, we propose a definition of portfolio diversification as how much the distribution of portfolio returns is close to a normal distribution. It is shown by using an ɑ-stable distribution that if commodity price return distribution has the opposite sign of skewness parameter β to financial portfolio's β, commodity diversification e ect exists. The empirical studies using S & P 500, U.S. 10-year treasury notes, and DJ-AIG commodity index are conducted to investigate the portfolio diversification e ects. The parameter estimation results of portfolio return distributions, the conditional correlations using the dynamic conditional correlation model with financial exogenous variables, and the e cient frontier from the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization all suggest that commodity futures have a diversification e ect on financial markets.


    1. Introduction

    Commodity markets are booming during the last decade against the backdrop of sluggish financial markets due to subprime loan problems and soaring real asset demand including demand for oil and iron ore from developing countries, in particular China and India. While commodity trading is generally classified in alternative investments, the classification stems from the alternation to traditional stocks and bonds in financial markets. The attractive characteristics of alternative assets may consist in the robustness including small correlations to financial asset price changes, i.e., the diversification effect. In reality, financial institutions like investment banks tend to increase the portion of commodities on their portfolios in an effort to diversify the portfolio risk during this commodity boom period. This paper highlights the diversification effect of commodities on financial assets.

    Geman (2005) suggests that commodity trading produce high returns because of the diversification effects in the portfolio of stocks and bonds by showing the negative effect of oil prices on stock prices in the constant correlation coefficient over the periods from 1990 to 1999. While Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006) examine the correlations between commodities futures and stock or bond price returns, they assume that the correlations are constant and it may not reflect the time varying property of the correlation. Geman and Kharoubi (2008) employ copula functions to analyze the diversification effects due to crude oil futures on equity portfolios. These studies focus on the linear and nonlinear relation between financial asset and commodity price returns. But they may miss the examination of the portfolio return changes due to the inclusion of commodities. Then, they may not take into account time varying properties of the correlations between financial asset and commodity price returns. Büyükşahin et al. (2010) find time varying correlations of equity-commodity returns using dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) model but they do not examine the time varying correlations affected by financial exogenous variables. Erb and Harvey (2006) explore the diversification effect of commodity futures on a financial portfolio by obtaining the efficient frontier with respect to the mean and variance as the return-risk relation. But the return distribution of commodity prices may be skewed and the risk cannot be captured appropriately by the variance.

    Regarding the recent advance of the dynamic correlation relationship among different asset classes, the relationship between commodities including crude oil and financial assets has recently been investigated by many researchers. Creti et al. (2013) employ the DCC model of Engle (2002) to investigate the links between stock and commodity markets including crude oil, resulting in the key role of the 2007-2008 financial crisis in highlighting the financialization of commodity markets. Büyükşahin and Robe (2014) empirically found that the correlation rises between commodities and equities after 2008 using the Engle's DCC model. Delatte and Lopez (2013) provide a thorough study on equity and commodity dependence and identify stylized facts of both asset classes using copula approaches, resulting in stronger equity-commodity comovement after 2008 financial crisis. Berger and Uddin (2016) provide a comprehensive survey on different dependence schemes between wavelet decomposed return series of stock indices, commodity futures including crude oil, and volatility indices, resulting in strong long-run dependence between S & P 500 and commodity futures returns. Kyrtsou et al. (2016) conduct a multivariate investigation of the dynamic linkage between the S & P 500 index and the petroleum products including the asymmetric Mackey-Glass causality test, resulting in the presence of nonlinear relationship from declining S & P 500 index returns to the crude oil futures-spot price spreads. Cifarelli and Paladino (2010) employ a behavioral ICAPM to investigate whether feedback trading strategies may cause oil price deviations from the fundamental values. Kolodziej et al. (2014) empirically support the argument that it has been more beneficial to hold crude oil as a financial asset than as a real commodity after fall 2008. Cheng et al. (2015) study the joint responses of commodity futures prices and positions of financial traders and hedgers, resulting in convective risk flows that financial traders reduce their net long positions during the 2008 financial crisis while hedgers facilitate this by reducing their short positions. By using commodity-link notes, Henderson et al. (2015) demonstrate the significantly positive and economically meaningful impacts of financial investors on commodity futures prices around the pricing dates of commodity-link notes when the hedge trades are executed while they demonstrate significant negative price impacts around the determination dates when the hedge trades are unwound. These studies are quite insightful to figure out the relationship between commodities including crude oil and financial assets. However these studies do not examine the diversification effect of commodities on financial asset portfolio.

    The paper tries to deepen the understandings of the diversification effect of commodities on financial portfolios shedding lights on the portfolio return distribution changes due to the addition of commodities to the portfolios. Then, the paper tries to fill the gap between existing literature regarding two angles from time varying commodity-financial asset price correlations with financial exogenous variables and the mean-conditional value at risk (CVaR) based efficient portfolio frontier. In the beginning, we propose a method to capture the diversification effect of commodities on financial portfolios using the portfolio return model with an α-stable distribution. Then, the method is applied to the empirical studies using S & P 500, U.S. 10-year treasury notes, and DJ-AIG commodity index. We show that the commodity may have the diversification effect on financial markets according to the estimated βs. As the additional studies to fill the gap between the existing literature, we first address the diversification issue due to commodities by using the dynamic conditional correlation model of Engle (2002) with financial exogenous variables (see Vargas, 2008). It is shown that the diversification effects are supported by small and robust conditional correlations between S & P 500 or U.S. 10-year treasury notes and DJ-AIG commodity index using the DCC model with financial exogenous variables. Second, we compare the efficient frontiers of financial portfolios with and without a commodity obtained from the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization. The results demonstrate that the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio with a commodity can be improved more than the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio without a commodity.

    This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 proposes a portfolio diversification definition from risk standardization using an α-stable distribution, which is helpful to analyze the diversification effect of commodities on financial portfolios. Section 3 conducts empirical studies of the diversification effects of commodity indices on stocks and bonds using the diversification definition in Section 2 as well as using a dynamic conditional correlation model with financial exogenous variables and the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization by introducing a comprehensive evaluation standard of risk standardization as well as robustly small correlation and risk-return tradeoff, respectively. Section 4 concludes and offers the directions for our future research.


    2. Portfolio Diversification from Risk Standardization

    The central limit theorem is used to justify the assumption that most random variables which represent the numerical characteristics of real populations are approximately normally distributed as in e.g., Bickel and Doksum (2001). The theory gives us an idea that the return distribution of equally weighted portfolio made of random variables may be represented by a normal distribution. On the other hand, Ibragimov (2009) demonstrates that the equally weighted portfolio is most diversified than the others if return distributions are moderately heavy-tailed by employing majorization theory. To this end, portfolio diversification can be interpreted as the degree of the closeness of the portfolio return distribution to a normal distribution in the first order approximation. In addition, King and Young (1994) suggest that non normality of real estate returns cannot attain efficient diversification within real estate asset class.

    Non normality of a price return distribution is mainly characterized by its third and fourth moments, i.e., skewness and kurtosis, respectively. The fat tail due to the skewness is problematic for portfolio risk management. We recognize that traditionally the concept of diversification is based on the second moment of the portfolio return: portfolio diversification is defined as an approach to zero of the second moment. But we believe that the other moment like skewness than the second moment is also a key to the diversification effect taking into account that commodities are used for diversification of financial portfolios in practice although commodities have no correlations to financial assets' returns, which may cause the increase of portfolio return volatilities. We start with the definition of the diversification effect of a commodity to a financial portfolio focusing on the skewness of the portfolio return distribution.

    Definition 1. A commodity contributes to the diversification of a financial portfolio, if the return distribution of the integrated financial portfolio with a commodity approaches a normal distribution more than the return distribution of the original financial portfolio in the sense of the skewness.

    In order to examine the usefulness of commodity to help financial portfolio diversified, we need to model the distribution of the price returns. An α-stable distribution is useful to demonstrate how much the distribution is close to a normal distribution by examining the parameters. The log-returns of commodity prices may have high skewness and kurtosis. In that case, it is difficult to model such time series appropriately by using a normal distribution. An α-stable distribution is often introduced as a tool to model such high skewness and kurtosis. Unfortunately, an α-stable distribution does not have its distribution function and density in its closed form. Stable distributions are introduced by their characteristic function as follows (see, e.g., Samorodnitsky and Taqqu, 1994):

    Eexp(itX)={exp{σαtα(1iβsgn(t)tan(πα2))+iμt},α1exp{σt(1+iβ2πsgn(t)logt)+iμt},α=1. (1)

    The parameter α describes the kurtosis of the distribution with 0<α2. The smaller α is, the heavier the tail of the distribution is. The parameter β describes the skewness of the distribution, 1β1. If β is positive (negative), then the distribution is skewed to the right (left, respectively). μ and σ are the shift and scale parameters, respectively. If α and β equal 2 and 0, respectively, then the α-stable distribution is identical to a normal distribution.

    We present the portfolio return model using an α-stable distribution. Assume that the asset price return Xi is iid (independent and identically distributed) and follows the stable distribution Sα(σi,βi,μi), i.e., each parameter α is approximately considered as a constant among the assets in the portfolio. Taking n assets that form the portfolio with each asset weight wi (i=1 to n), the portfolio return X is given by

    XSα(σ,β,μ), (2)
    textwhereσ=(ni=1(wiσi)α)1α, (3)
    β=ni=1(σiwiσ)αβi, (4)
    μ=ni=1(wiμi). (5)

    Note that we assume wi>0 for simplicity. The proof is obtained from (1). Then, we have the following proposition relevant to the portfolio diversification.

    Proposition 1. Suppose that a commodity whose price return distribution possesses the opposite sign of β to a financial portfolio is injected into the portfolio. Then, the commodity injection contributes to the diversification effect of the portfolio.

    Proof (σiwiσ)α in (4) is always positive by definition. It implies that if an asset with the opposite sign of β to a financial portfolio is injected into the financial portfolio, the ex post β of the portfolio approaches zero. Since it makes the distribution of the portfolio more symmetry, we can recognize that the diversification effect is valid injecting a commodity into a financial portfolio by Definition 1.

    The idea is consistent with Goetzmann and Kumar (2008) in the sense that the high volatility and high skewness in stock prices disturb the portfolio diversification. By using this proposition, we empirically examine the diversification effect of the commodity that is often recognized by financial market participants.


    3. Empirical Studies for Commodity Futures


    3.1. Data

    We use Dow Jones-AIG commodity index (DJ-AIG CI), S & P 500, and the US 10-year treasury note rates to represent commodity, stock, and bond markets, respectively. The data starts from January 3, 1991 to May 25, 2007.* We calculate hypothetical bond prices with 10 year maturity where a coupon is equal to the yield (e.g., see Jones et al. 1998). The daily adjusted closing data is provided by yahoo finance. The DJ-AIG CI is comprised of 19 commodity futures including energy, metal, and agricultural. The DJ-AIG CI is considered to represent physical commodity futures markets. The basic statistics of the data are reported in Table 1. Table 1 implies that the price distribution of S & P 500 is skewed to the left, while that of the DJ-AIG CI is skewed to the right. We test whether the skewness of S & P 500 and 10-year treasury note rate statistically significantly differ from zero using D'Agostino skewness test. p-values for S & P 500 and 10-year treasury note rate are obtained as 2.103×105 and 6.465×1012, respectively, implying that the both have skewness. We test whether the kurtosis of the DJ-AIG CI is statistically significantly different from three using Anscombe-Glynn kurtosis test. p-value for the DJ-AIG CI is obtained as 0.04393, implying that the kurtosis of the DJ-AIG CI is not equal to three.

    Table 1. Basic Statistics of DJ-AIG Commodity Index, S & P 500, and U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Rate. The price distribution of S & P 500 is skewed to the left, while that of the DJ-AIG CI is skewed to the right. We test whether the skewness of S & P 500 and 10-year treasury note rate statistically significantly differ from zero using D'Agostino skewness test. p-values for S & P 500 and 10-year treasury note rate are 2.103×105 and 6.465×1012, respectively, implying that the both have skewness. We test whether the kurtosis of the DJ-AIG CI statistically significantly differs from three using Anscombe-Glynn kurtosis test. p-value for the DJ-AIG CI is obtained as 0.04393, implying that the kurtosis of the DJ-AIG CI is not equal to three.
    DJ-AIG CI S & P 500 U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Rate
    Mean 112.70 913.94 5.66
    Median 102.50 989.09 5.66
    Maximum 187.00 1527.46 8.36
    Minimum 74.20 311.49 3.10
    Std. Dev. 27.07 363.22 1.18
    Skewness 1.03 -0.16 0.27
    Kurtosis 2.85 1.57 2.17
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    *After May 2009, DJ-AIG CI was renamed as Dow Jones-UBS Commodity Index (DJ-UBS CI) due to the acquisition of U.S. insurer AIG's stake in the DJ-AIG CI by the Swiss bank UBS.


    3.2. Analysis of risk standardization

    We estimate the parameters of stability α and skewness β for the DJ-AIG commodity index, S & P 500, and US 10-year treasury note price returns, respectively using the regression method of Koutrouvelis (1980). To compare the parameters for the three, we split the observations into 8 periods with 500 observations. The results are reported in Figure 1 and Table 2. Figure 1 shows that the estimated stability parameters (αs) of the three are located from 1.75 to 2.0 within the whole parameter range from 0 to 2. The estimated skewness parameters (βs) are scattered from -1 to 1, which corresponds to the whole parameter range. Comparing to βs, αs are considered constant in the first order approximation. This is consistent with Table 2 where all three αs are close to 1.8571, the average of αs. In Figure 1, the corresponding skewness parameters (βs) for commodity tend to possess the opposite sign to the stock index βs. This is also observed from Table 2 such that the commodity index β is -0.2955 while the stock index β is 0.0916. Setting α=1.8571, the average of αs in Table 2, we reestimate the skewness parameters. The results are reported in Table 3. The commodity index β is -0.3081 while the stock index β is 0.0851. From Proposition 1, commodity index β has the opposite sign to S & P 500 β. The injection of the commodity index into the financial portfolio of stock index can improve the portfolio diversification.

    Figure 1. Scatter Plots of Indices of Stability α and Skewness Parameters β. αs of the three assets are located from 1.75 to 2.0 within the whole parameter range from 0 to 2. βs are scattered from -1 to 1, which corresponds to the whole parameter range. Comparing to βs, αs are considered constant in the first order approximation.
    Table 2. Average Stability and Skewness Parameters (α and β, resp.). We estimate the parameters of stability α and skewness β for the DJ-AIG commodity index, S & P 500, and US 10-year treasury note price returns, respectively. To compare the parameters among the three, we split the observations into 8 periods with 500 observations. The averages of the parameters are calculated. All three αs are close to 1.8571, the average of αs.
    DJ-AIG CI S & P 500 U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Average
    α 1.8891 1.8307 1.8514 1.8571
    β -0.2955 0.0916 -0.3777 -0.1938
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 3. Average Skewness Parameter (β) at Constant Stability α=1.8571. Setting the constant α as 1.8571, the average of αs in Table 2, we reestimate the skewness parameters. β for commodity index has the opposite sign to β for S & P 500.
    DJ-AIG CI S & P 500 U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Average
    β -0.3081 0.0851 -0.2869 -0.1700
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Tables 2 and 3 imply that a commodity does not seem to contribute to the diversification of the bond portfolio because the both βs are negative. But this may come from the influence of the total data period. To examine how the commodity index return distribution simultaneously contributes to the portfolio distribution including bonds, Figure 2 illustrates the estimated β's for equally divided eight periods stemmed from the data. The commodity β's tend to have the opposite sign to stock βs in periods 1 and 5 during four low stock β periods (periods 1, 3, 4 and 5). The commodity β's tend to have the opposite sign to bond βs in periods 1, 3, 4, and 6 during eight periods. Thus, the results may suggest that the commodity be useful for the portfolio diversification both for stocks and bonds in that the distribution skewness approaches zero from Definition 1. That is, as the implication of this study, the third moment of commodity price returns can help to reduce the distortion of the financial portfolio investment risk.

    Figure 2. Skewness Parameter β. The commodity β's tend to have the opposite sign to stock βs in periods 1 and 5 during four low stock β periods (periods 1, 3, 4 and 5). The commodity β's tend to have the opposite sign to bond βs in periods 1, 3, 4, and 6 during eight periods.

    3.3. Analysis of robustly small correlation

    Portfolio diversification is often discussed using price correlations between various assets. Geman (2005) offers the negative effect of oil prices on stock prices in the constant correlation coefficient over the periods from 1990 to 1999 in an attempt to show the diversification effect. However, the correlation structure may demonstrate time-varying property. In addition, whether commodity-financial asset correlations may be affected by financial exogenous variables or not is a key to examine the robustness of the correlations. To examine the diversification effects of commodities on financial assets taking into account the time-varying correlation property affected by financial exogenous variables, we model the log return of the prices yt using the DCC model of Engle (2002) with exogenous variables Xt (DCC-X model of Vargas, 2008).

    yt=ϵtN(0,Ht), (6)
    ϵt=Dtηt, (7)
    Dt=diag[h121,th122,t], (8)

    where yt=(y1,t,y2,t), ϵt=(ϵ1,t,ϵ2,t), and ηt=(η1,t,η2,t). For i=1,2, we have

    hi,t=ωi+αi1ϵ2i,t1+βi1hi,t1, (9)
    E[ϵtϵtFt1]=DtRtDt, (10)
    Rt=Q1tQtQ1t, (11)
    Qt=(1θ1θ2)QKξˉX+θ1ηt1ηt1+θ2Qt1+KξXt1, (12)

    where Qt is the diagonal component of the square root of the diagonal elements of Qt and K is a matrix of ones. (9) represents the GARCH(1, 1) effect for the price returns for each asset. The conditional correlations are calculated using (11) where (12) represents time varying conditional covariance. The scale parameters θ1 and θ2 represent the effects of previous standardized shock and conditional correlation persistence, respectively. If either of the estimates of θ1 or θ2 in (12) is statistically significant, the correlation structure of the pairs demonstrates time varying. The estimation of parameters is conducted using the QMLE. The time-varying conditional correlations are empirically calculated using the errors (ηt) obtained from each GARCH(1, 1) model.

    Define Qt(q11q12q21q22). Then, Qt=(q1100q22).

    θ2 represents the persistence of the conditional covariance matrix. Since the standardized shock ηt is used for the calculation, θ2 is approximately considered as the conditional correlation persistence.

    We estimate the DCC-X model for DJ-AIG commodity index and S & P 500 and calculate the conditional correlations to examine the diversification effect of the commodity on the stock portfolio. Note that U.S. 10-year treasury note price returns are employed as the exogenous variable X. The estimation results and conditional correlations are illustrated in Table 4 and Figure 3, respectively. According to the standard errors in Table 4, α1, β1, α2, and β2 are statistically significant. It implies that there exist the GARCH effects both in the returns of DJ-AIG commodity index and S & P 500. In addition, Table 4 demonstrates that θ2 is statistically significant, meaning that there exist the dynamic conditional correlations. Thus, the conditional correlations between commodity and stock are time varying as in Figure 3. However, judging from Figure 3, the conditional correlations are range bound between the small correlations of 0.2 and -0.2. Thus, the correlations are considered as nearly zero while the correlations are heteroskedastic. This is consistent with the correlation persistency of 0.954 in Table 4, implying that the low correlation structure lives long. It may suggest that there exist the diversification effect due to a commodity on the stock portfolio in that almost no correlated asset of the commodity is combined with the stock index. More importantly, ξ is not statistically significant, implying that U.S. 10-year treasury note price returns do not affect the correlations between DJ-AIG commodity index and S & P 500. It may support the robustness of small commodity-stock correlations in that they are not affected by exogenous U.S. 10-year treasury note price returns.

    Table 4. Parameter Estimates of DCC-X Model for DJ-AIG CI and S & P 500. According to the standard errors, α1, β1, α2, and β2 are statistically significant. It implies that there exist the GARCH effects both in the returns of DJ-AIG commodity index and S & P 500. In addition, θ2 is statistically significant, meaning that there exist the dynamic conditional correlations. More importantly, ξ is not statistically significant, implying that U.S. 10-year treasury note price returns do not affect the correlations between DJ-AIG commodity index and S & P 500. It may support the robustness of small commodity-stock correlations in that they are not affected by exogenous U.S. 10-year treasury note price returns.
    Parameters ω1 α1 β1 ω2 α2 β2 θ1 θ2 ξ
    Estimates 3.405E-07 0.051 0.945 5.935E-07 0.052 0.941 0.014 0.954 0.032
    Std Errors 1.392E-07 0.013 0.012 2.465E-07 0.010 0.011 0.057 0.138 0.022
    Loglikelihood 2.816E+04
    AIC -5.630E+04
    SIC -5.624E+04
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Figure 3. Dynamic Conditional Correlations between DJ-AIG CI and S & P 500. The conditional correlations are range bound between the small correlations of 0.2 and -0.2. The correlations are considered as nearly zero while the correlations are heteroskedastic.

    As the next step, we estimate the DCC-X model for DJ-AIG commodity index and U.S. 10-year treasury note prices and then calculate the conditional correlations to examine the diversification effect of the commodity on the bond portfolio. Note that we assume that the U.S. 10-year treasury note price is calculated using an assumption of a coupon equivalence to the yield and $100 principal for simplicity because we only have U.S. 10-year treasury note rate data. Here S & P 500 returns are employed as the exogenous variable X. The estimation results and conditional correlations are illustrated in Table 5 and Figure 4, respectively. According to the standard errors in Table 5, the parameters except ω2, α2, β2, θ1, and ξ are statistically significant. Thus, there is no GARCH effect in the US 10-year treasury note prices. However, the conditional covariances are still influenced by the previous covariances judging from the significance of estimated θ2 in Table 5. According to Figure 4, the conditional correlations are time varying between about 0.2 and -0.2. Thus, we conclude that such a small correlation gives rise to the diversification effect by commodity on the bond portfolio. More importantly, ξ is not statistically significant, implying that S & P 500 returns do not affect the correlations between DJ-AIG commodity index and U.S. 10-year treasury note prices. It may also support the robustness of small commodity-bond price correlations in that they are not affected by exogenous S & P 500 returns.

    Table 5. Parameter Estimates of DCC-X Model for DJ-AIG CI and U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Prices. According to the standard errors, the parameters except ω2, α2, β2, θ1, and ξ are statistically significant. Thus, there is no GARCH effect in the US 10-year treasury note prices. However, the conditional covariances are still influenced by the previous covariances judging from the significance of estimated θ2. More importantly, ξ is not statistically significant, implying that S & P 500 returns do not affect the correlations between DJ-AIG commodity index and U.S. 10-year treasury note prices. It may also support the robustness of small commodity-bond price correlations in that they are not affected by exogenous S & P 500 returns.
    Parameters ω1 α1 β1 ω2 α2 β2 θ1 θ2 ξ
    Estimates 3.405E-07 0.051 0.945 8.000E-06 0.520 0.480 0.033 0.891 0.000
    Std Errors 1.392E-07 0.013 0.012 1.272E-05 0.553 0.521 0.027 0.088 0.024
    Loglikelihood 2.941E+04
    AIC -5.880E+04
    SIC -5.875E+04
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Figure 4. Dynamic Conditional Correlations of DJ-AIG CI and U.S. 10-Year Treasury Note Prices. The conditional correlations are time varying between about 0.2 and -0.2.

    Obtaining Proposition 1, we assume that commodity, stock, and bond price returns are iid. If it is true, the correlations between price returns should be observed as zero. The results obtained using the DCC-X model may partly correspond to the iid assumption. As the implication, commodities can help to work as robustly defensive assets in the financial portfolios, which stabilize the portfolios.


    3.4. Analysis of risk-return tradeoff

    Erb and Harvey (2006) explore the diversification effect of commodity futures in the financial portfolio by obtaining the mean-variance efficient frontier. Since the returns of commodity futures do not necessarily follow the normal distribution, the variance cannot capture the risk of the portfolio including stocks, bonds, and commodities appropriately. We introduce the CVaR as the risk measure. Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000) show that the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization is consistent with the following optimization:

    minx,αFβ(x,α) (13)
    s.t.xj0 for j=1,...,n,with nj=1xj=1, (14)
    nj=1xjE[yj]μ,whereFβ(x,α)=α+1q(1β)qi=1[xTyiα]+. (15)

    β is the confident level often used as 90%, 95%, or 99%. If the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio with a commodity improves more than the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio without a commodity, there exists the diversification effect of the commodity as in Geman (2005). Using this evaluation criteria, we examine the diversification effect of commodities on a financial portfolio empirically.

    Following Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000), we optimize the two mean-CVaR portfolio: the portfolio of stock and bond and the portfolio of stock, bond, and commodity to observe the diversification effect of commodity on the stock and bond portfolio. We use a constant yield and the U.S. 10-year treasury note rates. First, assuming risk free bond with a constant rate of 0.0005 per trading day, we obtain the efficient frontier of the portfolio of S & P 500 and the risk free bond and that of S & P 500, the risk free bond, and DJ-AIG CI respectively. The result is reported in Figure 5 with the confidence level β=90%. The result implies that the commodity injection into financial portfolio may have the diversification effect from risk-return tradeoff because the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio with a commodity improves more than that without a commodity.

    Figure 5. Mean-CVaR Portfolio Optimization with A Constant Yield. The confidence level β is 90%. The result implies that the commodity injection into financial portfolio may have the diversification effect from risk-return tradeoff because the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio with a commodity improves more than that without a commodity.

    Second, using the U.S. 10-year treasury notes, we also optimize the two mean-CVaR portfolio: the portfolio of S & P 500 and U.S. 10-year treasury notes and the portfolio of S & P 500, U.S. 10-year treasury notes, and DJ-AIG CI to observe the diversification effect of commodity on a stock and bond portfolio. The result is reported in Figure 6 with the confidence level β=90%. The result indicates that the commodity injection into financial portfolio may have the diversification effect from risk-return tradeoff, even if we employ the U.S. 10-year treasury notes. The results are identical to the diversification effect of commodities on the financial portfolio as in Geman (2005). One may think that if the efficient frontier of the portfolio conducted by various stocks can be improved by adding the commodity asset, then the results can be more persuasive. Taking into account that the portfolio conducted by various stocks is considered as the market portfolio of S & P 500, we may safely say that the results are convincing.

    Figure 6. Mean-CVaR Portfolio Optimization with U.S. 10-Year Treasury Notes. The confidence level β is 90%. The result indicates that the commodity injection into financial portfolio may have the diversification effect from risk-return tradeoff, even if using the U.S. 10-year treasury notes.

    Finally, we calculate the stable tail adjusted risk ratio (STARR) defined by the mean over CVaR of the portfolio returns (see Martin et al., 2003).

    STARRβ=E[rrf]CVaRβ(r), (16)

    where β is set to be 90% and rf=0 for simplicity. STARR ratio represents the ratio between the expected excess return and its CVaR. We illustrate the STARR ratios for the two portfolios as in Figure 7 which corresponds to Figure 6 using U.S. 10-year treasury notes. Note that the horizontal axis represents the number of mean-CVaR pairs. Figure 7 implies that the STARR ratio with a commodity is greater than the STARR ratio without a commodity. Considering that the financial portfolio with a commodity can improve its efficient frontier more than the financial portfolio without a commodity, the STARR ratio may be useful to capture the diversification effect in the sense of risk-return tradeoff in the financial portfolios with commodities. As the implication of this study, commodities can help to improve the performance of financial portfolio regarding the advanced risk and return tradeoff.

    Figure 7. STARR Ratios for Financial Portfolios w./w.o. DJ-AIG CI. The STARR ratio with a commodity is greater than the STARR ratio without a commodity. Note that the horizontal axis represents the number of mean-CVaR pairs.

    4. Conclusions and Directions for Future Research

    This paper has examined the portfolio diversification effect of commodity futures on financial market products by introducing a comprehensive evaluation criterion of risk standardization, robustly small correlation, and risk-return tradeoff. Using the portfolio return model with an α-stable distribution we propose a definition of the diversification from risk standardization as how much the distribution of portfolio returns is close to a normal distribution. It has been shown by using an α-stable distribution that if the commodity has the opposite sign β's to the financial portfolio, the diversification effect of commodity exists in that the portfolio return distribution becomes more symmetry than the portfolio return distribution without a commodity. The empirical studies by using S & P 500, U.S. 10-year treasury notes, and DJ-AIG commodity index were conducted to investigate the portfolio diversification effects regarding risk standardization, robustly small correlation, and risk-return tradeoff. The parameter estimation results of α-stable portfolio return distributions have suggested that the commodity have the diversification effect on financial markets according to the estimated βs. Then, we have shown that the diversification effect is also supported by the conditional correlations between S & P 500 or U.S. 10-year treasury notes and DJ-AIG commodity index using the dynamic conditional correlation model with financial exogenous variables in that the correlations are small and robust to exogenous financial price returns. In addition, we have compared the efficient frontiers of the financial portfolios with and without commodity obtained from the mean-CVaR portfolio optimization. The results have illustrated that the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio with a commodity can improve the efficient frontier of the financial portfolio without a commodity. Thus, these results have been identical to the diversification effect of commodities on the financial portfolio as in Geman (2005) in the sense of risk-return tradeoff. Finally, we have shown that the stable tail adjusted risk ratio is useful to capture the diversification effect in the sense of risk-return tradeoff in the portfolio of financial assets and commodity.

    The paper assumes that α of the α-stable distribution is a constant for simplicity. But we recognize that α causing the fat tail distribution also affects the portfolio diversification. In addition, while this paper only employs the DJ-AIG commodity index for the commodity because of the availability of data, the other indices such as Goldman Sachs commodity index and the Commodity Research Bureau index can be applied to this analysis. Furthermore, due to the data availability, we use the data until 2007 but we have to expand the examination using the recent data. We also recognize that introducing several macroeconomic variables exerting impact on the financial market might be of more interest for the examination of robustly small correlations between commodity and financial asset price returns. However macro data is difficult to be incorporated into the examination because price return data used in this study is daily while the macro data is typically longer period of time data like yearly data. We leave these items as the direction for future research.


    Acknowledgments

    This study is conducted as a part of the Project "Economic and financial analysis of commodity markets" undertaken at Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). Views expressed in this paper are those of the author. All remaining errors are mine. The author is grateful for helpful comments and suggestions by Toshiki Honda, Kentaro Iwatsubo, Matteo Manera, Ryozo Miura, Nobuhiro Nakamura, Hiroshi Ohashi, Kazuhiko Ohashi, Tatsuyoshi Okimoto, Yuji Yamada, and Makoto Yano, and Discussion Paper seminar participants at RIETI.


    Conflict of Interest

    The author declares no conflict of interest.


    [1] Berger T, Uddin G.S (2016) On the dynamic dependence between equity markets, commodity futures and economic uncertainty indexes. Energy Econ 56: 374–383. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2016.03.024
    [2] Bickel P, Doksum K (2001) Mathematical Statistics: Basic Ideas and Selected Topics Vol. 1. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
    [3] Büyüks¸ahin B, Robe M.A (2014) Speculators, commodities and cross-market linkages. J Int Money Finan 42: 38–70. doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2013.08.004
    [4] Büyüks¸ahin B, Haigh M. S, Robe M. A (2010) Commodities and equities: Ever a "market of one"? The J of Alternative Investments 12: 76–95.
    [5] Cheng I.-H, Kirilenko A, Xiong W (2015) Convective risk flows in commodity futures markets. Rev Financ 19: 1733–1781. doi: 10.1093/rof/rfu043
    [6] Cifarelli G, Paladino G (2010) Oil price dynamics and speculation: A multivariate financial approach. Energy Econ 32: 363–372.
    [7] Creti A, Joëts M, Mignon V (2013) On the links between stock and commodity markets' volatility. Energy Econ 37: 16–28. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2013.01.005
    [8] Delatte A.L, Lopez C (2013) Commodity and equity markets: Some stylized facts from a copula approach. J Bank Financ 37: 5346–5356. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.06.012
    [9] Engle R.F (2002) Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate GARCH models. J Bus Econ Stat 20: 339–350. doi: 10.1198/073500102288618487
    [10] Erb C, Harvey C (2006) The strategic and tactical value of commodity futures. Financ Anal J 62: 69–97. doi: 10.2469/faj.v62.n2.4084
    [11] Geman H (2005) Commodities and Commodity Derivatives: Modeling and Pricing for Agriculturals, Metals and Energy. West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
    [12] Geman H, Kharoubi C (2008) WTI crude oil futures in portfolio diversification: The time-to-maturity effect. J Bank Financ 32: 2553–2559. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2008.04.002
    [13] Goetzmann W. N, Kumar A (2008) Equity portfolio diversification. Rev Financ 12: 433–463. doi: 10.1093/rof/rfn005
    [14] Gorton G, Rouwenhorst K.G (2006) Facts and fantasies about commodity futures. Financ Anal J 62: 47–68.
    [15] Henderson B. J, Pearson N.D, Wang L (2015) New evidence on the financialization of commodity markets. Rev of Financ Studies 28: 1285–1311. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhu091
    [16] Ibragimov R (2009) Portfolio diversification and value at risk under thick-tailedness. Quant Financ 9: 565–580. doi: 10.1080/14697680802629384
    [17] Jones C. M, Lamont O, Lumsdaine R. L (1998) Macroeconomic news and bond market volatility. J of Financ Econ 47: 315–337. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(97)00047-0
    [18] King D. A, Young M. S (1994) Why diversification doesn't work: Flaws in modern portfolio theory turn real estate portfolio managers back to old-fashioned underwriting. Real Estate Rev 25: 6–12.
    [19] Kolodziej M, Kaufmann R.K, Kulatilaka N, et al. (2014) Crude oil: Commodity or financial asset? Energy Econ 46: 216–223. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2014.09.006
    [20] Koutrouvelis I. A (1980) Regression-type estimation of the parameters of stable laws. J Am Stat Assoc 75: 918–928. doi: 10.1080/01621459.1980.10477573
    [21] Kyrtsou C, Mikropoulou C, Papana A (2016) Does the S&P500 index lead the crude oil dynamics? A complexity-based approach. Energy Econ 56: 239–246.
    [22] Martin D, Rachev S. T, Siboulet F (2003) Phi-alpha optimal portfolios and extreme risk management. Wilmott Magazine of Financ November: 70-83.
    [23] Rockafellar R.T, Uryasev S (2000) Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. J Risk 2: 21–41. doi: 10.21314/JOR.2000.038
    [24] Samorodnitsky G, Taqqu M.S (1994) Stable Non-Gaussian Random Processes. London: Chapman & Hall.
    [25] Vargas G. A (2008) What drives the dynamic conditional correlation of foreign exchange and equity returns? Working Paper, Singapore Management University.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Takashi Kanamura, Portfolio diversification and sustainable assets from new perspectives, 2023, 1470-8272, 10.1057/s41260-023-00336-x
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2018 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4690) PDF downloads(937) Cited by(1)

Article outline

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog