Nowadays, product recycling has become an effective strategy for manufacturing industries to achieve sustainable development due to the scarcity of natural resources, waste management, and greenhouse gas emissions. This study considered an imperfect production-based competitive supply chain model for product recycling in an emission-reduction environment under a cap-and-trade scheme. The manufacturer invests in green technology to restrict carbon emissions during production. The recycler collects used items at a recovery rate depending on the buy-back price and environmental awareness effort. The rival retailers compete against each other for the retail price and promotional effort. The linear type of market demand depends on the retail price, promotional effort, and green level of the product. The proposed model was analyzed analytically and numerically under one centralized system, five decentralized systems, three Stackelberg, and two Nash game structures. Numerical examples and sensitivity analysis of the key parameters were studied to justify the feasibility of the proposed model. The present study revealed that the centralized scenario is mostly preferable for supply chain profit. The manufacturer-Stackelberg 1 scenario is most profitable for the manufacturer, whereas the two retailers collect maximum individual profit in the vertical Nash 2 model, where they jointly play the game. Moreover, retail price plays a crucial role in optimizing individual retailers' profits in the competitive market. In connection with the environmental aspects, the government should offer lower carbon caps to curtail excessive emissions and restrict the selling of excess carbon quotas.
Citation: Brojeswar Pal, Anindya Mandal, Shib Sankar Sana. A closed-loop green supply chain with retailers' competition and product recycling in the green environment under the cap-and-trade policy[J]. Green Finance, 2024, 6(1): 117-161. doi: 10.3934/GF.2024006
[1] | Luigi Montoro, Berardino Sciunzi . Qualitative properties of solutions to the Dirichlet problem for a Laplace equation involving the Hardy potential with possibly boundary singularity. Mathematics in Engineering, 2023, 5(1): 1-16. doi: 10.3934/mine.2023017 |
[2] | Juan-Carlos Felipe-Navarro, Tomás Sanz-Perela . Semilinear integro-differential equations, Ⅱ: one-dimensional and saddle-shaped solutions to the Allen-Cahn equation. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(5): 1-36. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021037 |
[3] | Francesca G. Alessio, Piero Montecchiari . Gradient Lagrangian systems and semilinear PDE. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(6): 1-28. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021044 |
[4] | Filippo Gazzola, Gianmarco Sperone . Remarks on radial symmetry and monotonicity for solutions of semilinear higher order elliptic equations. Mathematics in Engineering, 2022, 4(5): 1-24. doi: 10.3934/mine.2022040 |
[5] | Elena Beretta, M. Cristina Cerutti, Luca Ratti . Lipschitz stable determination of small conductivity inclusions in a semilinear equation from boundary data. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(1): 1-10. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021003 |
[6] | Huyuan Chen, Laurent Véron . Weak solutions of semilinear elliptic equations with Leray-Hardy potentials and measure data. Mathematics in Engineering, 2019, 1(3): 391-418. doi: 10.3934/mine.2019.3.391 |
[7] | Marco Cirant, Kevin R. Payne . Comparison principles for viscosity solutions of elliptic branches of fully nonlinear equations independent of the gradient. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(4): 1-45. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021030 |
[8] | Yuzhe Zhu . Propagation of smallness for solutions of elliptic equations in the plane. Mathematics in Engineering, 2025, 7(1): 1-12. doi: 10.3934/mine.2025001 |
[9] | Antonio Greco, Francesco Pisanu . Improvements on overdetermined problems associated to the p-Laplacian. Mathematics in Engineering, 2022, 4(3): 1-14. doi: 10.3934/mine.2022017 |
[10] | Italo Capuzzo Dolcetta . The weak maximum principle for degenerate elliptic equations: unbounded domains and systems. Mathematics in Engineering, 2020, 2(4): 772-786. doi: 10.3934/mine.2020036 |
Nowadays, product recycling has become an effective strategy for manufacturing industries to achieve sustainable development due to the scarcity of natural resources, waste management, and greenhouse gas emissions. This study considered an imperfect production-based competitive supply chain model for product recycling in an emission-reduction environment under a cap-and-trade scheme. The manufacturer invests in green technology to restrict carbon emissions during production. The recycler collects used items at a recovery rate depending on the buy-back price and environmental awareness effort. The rival retailers compete against each other for the retail price and promotional effort. The linear type of market demand depends on the retail price, promotional effort, and green level of the product. The proposed model was analyzed analytically and numerically under one centralized system, five decentralized systems, three Stackelberg, and two Nash game structures. Numerical examples and sensitivity analysis of the key parameters were studied to justify the feasibility of the proposed model. The present study revealed that the centralized scenario is mostly preferable for supply chain profit. The manufacturer-Stackelberg 1 scenario is most profitable for the manufacturer, whereas the two retailers collect maximum individual profit in the vertical Nash 2 model, where they jointly play the game. Moreover, retail price plays a crucial role in optimizing individual retailers' profits in the competitive market. In connection with the environmental aspects, the government should offer lower carbon caps to curtail excessive emissions and restrict the selling of excess carbon quotas.
The notion of intuitionistic fuzzy normed subring and intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal was characterized by Abed Alhaleem and Ahmad in [10], after that the necessity has arisen to introduce the concepts of intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideals and intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideals. Following the work of Emniyent and Şahin in [17] which outlined the concepts of fuzzy normed prime ideal and maximal ideal we implement the conception of intuitionistic fuzzy to prime and maximal normed ideals. After the establishment of fuzzy set by Zadeh [28] which showed that the membership of an element in a fuzzy set is at intervals [0, 1], many researchers investigated on the properties of fuzzy set because it handles uncertainty and vagueness, and due to its applications in many fields of studies. A lot of work has been done on various aspects and for the last 50 years, the relation betwee maximal and prime ideals has become the core of many researchers work. Swamy and Swamy in 1988 [27] presented the conceptions of fuzzy ideal and fuzzy prime ideal with truth values in a complete lattice fulfilling the infinite distributive law. Later, many researchers studied the generalization of fuzzy ideals and fuzzy prime (maximal) ideals of rings: Dixit et al [16], Malik and Mordeson in [22] and Mukherjee and Sen in [24]. The notion of intuitionistic fuzzy set was initiated by Atanassov [6], as a characterization of fuzzy set which assigned the degree of membership and the degree of non-membership for set elements, he also delineated some operations and connections over basic intuitionistic fuzzy sets. In [5], Atanassov introduced essential definitions and properties of the interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy sets and the explanation of mostly extended modal operator through interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy sets were presented in [4], and some of its main properties were studied. Banerjee and Basnet [13] investigated intuitionistic fuzzy rings and intuitionistic fuzzy ideals using intuitionistic fuzzy sets. In 2005 [20], an identification of intuitionistic fuzzy ideals, intuitionistic fuzzy prime ideals and intuitionistic fuzzy completely prime ideals was given. In [14], Bakhadach et al. implemented the terms of intuitionistic fuzzy ideals and intuitionistic fuzzy prime (maximal) ideals, investigated these notions to show new results using the intuitionistic fuzzy points and membership and nonmembership functions. The paper comprises the following: we begin with the preliminary section, we submit necessary notations and elementary outcomes. In Section 3, we characterize some properties of intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals and identify the image and the inverse image of intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals. In Section 4, we describe the notions of intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideals and intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideals and we characterize the relation between the intuitionistic characteristic function and prime (maximal) ideals. In Section 5, the conclusions are outlined.
We first include some definitions needed for the subsequent sections:
Definition 2.1. [25] A linear space L is called a normed space if for any element r there is a real number ‖r‖ satisfying:
∙‖r‖≥0 for every r∈L, when r=0 then ‖r‖=0;
∙‖α.r‖=|α|.‖r‖;
∙‖r+v‖≤‖r‖+‖v‖ for all r,v∈L.
Definition 2.2. [18] A ring R is said to be a normed ring (NR) if it possesses a norm ‖‖, that is, a non-negative real-valued function ‖‖:NR→R such that for any r,v∈R,
1)‖r‖=0⇔r=0,
2)‖r+v‖≤‖r‖+‖v‖,
3)‖r‖=‖−r‖, (and hence ‖1A‖=1=‖−1‖ if identity exists), and
4)‖rv‖≤‖r‖‖v‖.
Definition 2.3. [1] Let ∗:[0,1]×[0,1]→[0,1] be a binary operation. Then ∗ is a t-norm if ∗ conciliates the conditions of commutativity, associativity, monotonicity and neutral element 1.
We shortly use t-norm and write r∗v instead of ∗(r,v).
Two examples of continuous t-norm are: r∗v=rv and r∗v=min{r,v} [26].
Proposition 2.4. [21] A t-norm T has the property, for every r,v∈[0,1]
T(r,v)≤min(r,v) |
Definition 2.5. [19] Let ⋄:[0,1]×[0,1]→[0,1] be a binary operation. Then ⋄ is a s-norm if ⋄ conciliates the conditions of commutativity, associativity, monotonicity and neutral element 0.
We shortly use s-norm and write r⋄v instead of ⋄(r,v).
Two examples of continuous s-norm are: r⋄v=min(r+v,1) and r⋄v=max{r,v} [26].
Proposition 2.6. [21] A s-norm S has the property, for every r,v∈[0,1]
max(r,v)≤S(r,v) |
Definition 2.7. [28] A membership function μA(r):X→[0,1] specifies the fuzzy set A over X, where μA(r) defines the membership of an element r∈X in a fuzzy set A.
Definition 2.8. [6] An intuitionistic fuzzy set A in set X is in the form IFSA={(r,μA(r),γA(r):r∈X}, such that the degree of membership is μA(r):X→[0,1] and the degree of non-membership is γA(r):X→[0,1], where 0≤μA(r)+γA(r))≤1 for all r∈X. We shortly use A=(μA,γA).
Definition 2.9. [7] Let A be an intuitionistic fuzzy set in a ring R, we indicate the (α,β)-cut set by Aα,β={r∈R:μA≥α and γA≤β} such that α+β≤1 and α,β∈[0,1].
Definition 2.10. [23] The support of an intuitionistic fuzzy set A, is denoted by A∘ and defined as A∘={r:μA(r)>0 and γA(r)<1}.
Definition 2.11. [2] The complement, union and intersection of two IFSA=(μA,γA) and B=(μB,γB), in a ring R, are defined as follows:
1)Ac={⟨r,γA(r),μA(r)⟩:r∈R},
2)A∪B={⟨r,max(μA(r),μB(r)),min(γA(r),γB(r))⟩:r∈R},
3)A∩B={⟨r,min(μA(r),μB(r)),max(γA(r),γB(r))⟩:r∈R}.
Definition 2.12. [12] Let NR be a normed ring. Then an IFS A={(r,μA(r),γA(r)):r∈NR} of NR is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed subring (IFNSR) of NR if:
i. μA(r−v)≥μA(r)∗μA(v),
ii. μA(rv)≥μA(r)∗μA(v),
iii. γA(r−v)≤γA(r)⋄γA(v),
iv. γA(rv)≤γA(r)⋄γA(v).
Definition 2.13. [9] Let NR be a normed ring. Then an IFS A={(r,μA(r),γA(r)):r∈NR} of NR is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal (IFNI) of NR if:
i. μA(r−v)≥μA(r)∗μA(v),
ii. μA(rv)≥μA(r)⋄μA(v),
iii. γA(r−v)≤γA(r)⋄γA(v)),
iv. γA(rv))≤γA(r)∗γA(v)}.
Definition 2.14. [3] If A and B are two fuzzy subsets of the normed ring NR. Then the product A∘B(r) is defined by:
A∘B(r)={⋄r=vz(μA(v)∗μB(z)),ifr=vz0,otherwise |
Definition 2.15. [22] A fuzzy ideal A (non-constant) of a ring R is considered to be a fuzzy prime ideal if B∘C⊆A for a fuzzy ideals B, C of R indicates that either B⊆A or C⊆A.
In this section, we characterize several properties of intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals and elementary results are obtained.
Definition 3.1. [8] Let A and B be two intuitionistic fuzzy subsets of the normed ring NR. The operations are defined as:
μA⊛B(r)={⋄r=vz(μA(v)∗μB(z)),ifr=vz0,otherwise |
and
γA⊗B(r)={∗r=vz(γA(v)⋄γB(z)),ifr=vz1,otherwise |
Therefore, the intrinsic product of A and B is considered to be the intuitionistic fuzzy normed set A∘B=(μA⊛B,γA⊗B)=(μA⊛μB,γA⊗γB).
Theorem 3.2. [10] Let A and B be two intuitionistic fuzzy ideals of a normed ring NR. Then A∩B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Example 3.1. Let NR=Z the ring of integers under ordinary addition and multiplication of integers.
Define the intuitionistic fuzzy normed subsets as A=(μA,γA) and B=(μB,γB), by
μA(r)={0.7,ifr∈5Z0.2,otherwiseandγA(r)={0.1,ifr∈5Z0.4,otherwise |
μB(r)={0.8,ifr∈5Z0.3,otherwiseandγB(r)={0.2,ifr∈5Z0.7,otherwise |
As μA∩B(r)=min{μA(r),μB(r)} and γA∩B(r)=max{γA(r),γB(r)}. Then,
μA∩B(r)={0.7,ifr∈5Z0.2,otherwiseandγA∩B(r)={0.2,ifr∈5Z0.7,otherwise |
It can be verified that A, B and A∩B are intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of NR.
Lemma 3.3. Let A and B be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed right ideal and an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal of a normed ring NR, respectively, then A∘B⊆A∩B i.e, A⊛B(r)≤A∩B(r)≤A⊗B(r), where
A∩B(r)={(r,μA∩B(r),γA∩B(r)):r∈NR}={(r,min{μA(r),μB(r)},max{γA(r),γB(r)}):r∈NR}. |
Proof. Let A∩B be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR. Assume that A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed right ideal and B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal. Let μA⊛B(r)=⋄r=vz(μA(v)∗μB(z)) and let γA⊗B(r)=∗r=vz(γA(v)⋄γB(z)).
Since, A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed right ideal and B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal, we have
μA(v)≤μA(vz)=μA(r)andμB(z)≤μB(vz)=μB(r) |
and
γA(r)=γA(vz)≥γA(v)andγB(r)=γB(vz)≥γB(z). |
Thus,
μA⊛B(r)=⋄r=vz(μA(v)∗μB(z))=min(μA(v),μB(z))≤min(μA(r),μB(r))≤μA∩B(r) | (3.1) |
and
γA⊗B(r)=∗r=vz(γA(v)⋄γB(z))=max(γA(v),γB(z))≥max(γA(r),γB(r))≥γA∩B(r). | (3.2) |
By (3.1) and (3.2) the proof is concluded.
Remark 3.4. The union of two intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of a ring NR needs not be always intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal.
Example 3.2. Let NR=Z the ring of integers under ordinary addition and multiplication of integers.
Let the intuitionistic fuzzy normed subsets A=(μA,γA) and B=(μB,γB), define by
μA(r)={0.85,ifr∈3Z0.3,otherwiseandγA(r)={0.2,ifr∈3Z0.4,otherwise |
μB(r)={0.75,ifr∈2Z0.35,otherwiseandγB(r)={0.3,ifr∈2Z0.5,otherwise |
It can be checked that A and B are intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of NR.
As μA∪B(r)=max{μA(r),μB(r)} and γA∪B(r)=min{γA(r),γB(r)}. Then,
μA∪B(r)={0.85,ifr∈3Z0.75,ifr∈2Z−3Z0.35,ifr∉2Zorr∉3ZandγA∪B(r)={0.2,ifr∈3Z0.3,ifr∈2Z−3Z0.4,ifr∉2Zorr∉3Z |
Let r=15 and v=4, then μA∪B(15)=0.85, μA∪B(4)=0.75 and γA∪B(15)=0.2, γA∪B(4)=0.3.
Hence, μA∪B(15−4)=μA∪B(11)=0.35≯μA∪B(15)∗μA∪B(4)=min{0.85,0.75} and γA∪B(15−4)=γA∪B(11)=0.4≮γA∪B(15)⋄γA∪B(4)=max{0.2,0.3}. Thus, the union of two intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of NR need not be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal.
Proposition 3.5. Let A=(μA,γA) be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of a ring NR, then we have for all r∈NR:
i. μA(0)≥μA(r) and γA(0)≤γA(r),
ii. μA(−r)=μA(r) and γA(−r)=γA(r),
iii. If μA(r−v)=μA(0) then μA(r)=μA(v),
iv. If γA(r−v)=γA(0) then γA(r)=γA(v).
Proof. i. As A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal, then
μA(0)=μA(r−r)≥μA(r)∗μA(r)=μA(r) |
and
γA(0)=γA(r−r)≤γA(r)⋄γA(r)=γA(r) |
ii. μA(−r)=μA(0−r)≥μA(0)∗μA(r)=μA(r) and μA(r)=μA(0−(−r))≥μA(0)∗μA(−r)=μA(−r).
Therefore, μA(−r)=μA(r)
also,
γA(−r)=γA(0−r)≤γA(0)⋄γA(r)=γA(r) and γA(r)=γA(0−(−r))≤γA(0)⋄γA(−r)=γA(−r).
Therefore, γA(−r)=γA(r).
iii. Since μA(r−v)=μA(0), then
μA(v)=μA(r−(r−v))≥μA(r)∗μA(r−v)=μA(r)∗μA(0)≥μA(r) |
similarly
μA(r)=μA((r−v)−(−v))≥μA(r−v)∗μA(−v)=μA(0)∗μA(v)≥μA(v) |
Consequently, μA(r)=μA(v).
iv. same as in iii.
Proposition 3.6. Let A be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of a normed ring NR, then △A=(μA,μcA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proof. Let r,v∈NR
μcA(r−v)=1−μA(r−v)≤1−min{μA(r),μA(v)}=max{1−μA(r),1−μA(v)}=max{μcA(r),μcA(v)} |
Then μcA(r−v)≤μcA(r)⋄μcA(v).
μcA(rv)=1−μA(rv)≤1−max{μA(r),μA(v)}=min{1−μA(r),1−μA(v)}=min{μcA(r),μcA(v)} |
Then μcA(rv)≤μcA(r)∗μcA(v).
Accordingly, △A=(μA,μcA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proposition 3.7. If A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of a normed ring NR, then ◊A=(γcA,γA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proof. Let r,v∈NR
γcA(r−v)=1−γA(r−v)≥1−max{γA(r),γA(v)}=min{1−γA(r),1−γA(v)}=min{γcA(r),γcA(v)} |
Then γcA(r−v)≥γcA(r)∗γcA(v).
γAc(rv)=1−γA(rv)≥1−min{γA(r),γA(v)}=max{1−μA(r),1−γA(v)}=max{γcA(r),γcA(v)} |
Then γcA(rv)≥γcA(r)⋄γcA(v).
Therefore, ◊A=(γcA,γA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proposition 3.8. An IFSA=(μA,γA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR if the fuzzy subsets μA and γcA are intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of NR.
Proof. Let r,v∈NR
1−γA(r−v)=γcA(r−v)≥min{γcA(r),γcA(v)}=min{(1−γA(r)),(1−γA(v))}=1−max{γA(r),γA(v)} |
Then, γA(r−v)≤γA(r)⋄γA(v).
1−γA(rv)=γcA(rv)≥max{γcA(r),γcA(v)}=max{(1−γA(r)),(1−γA(v))}=1−min{γA(r),γA(v)} |
Then, γA(rv)≤γA(r)∗γA(v).
Consequently, A=(μA,γA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Definition 3.9. Let A be a set (non-empty) of the normed ring NR, the intuitionistic characteristic function of A is defined as λA=(μλA,γλA), where
μλA(r)={1,ifr∈A0,ifr∉AandγλA(r)={0,ifr∈A1,ifr∉A |
Lemma 3.10. Let A and B be intuitionistic fuzzy sets of a normed ring NR, then:
(i) λA∩λB=λA∩B (ii) λA∘λB=λA∘B (iii) If A⊆B, then λA⊆λB
Theorem 3.11. For a non-empty subset A of NR, A is a subring of NR if and only if λA=(μλA,γλA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed subring of NR.
Proof. Suppose A to be a subring of NR and let r,v∈NR. If r,v∈A, then by the intuitionistic characteristic function properties μλA(r)=1=μλA(v) and γλA(r)=0=γλA(v). As A is a subring, then r−v and rv∈A. Thus, μλA(r−v)=1=1∗1=μλA(r)∗μλA(v) and μλA(rv)=1=1∗1=μλA(r)∗μλA(v), also γλA(r−v)=0=0⋄0=γλA(r)⋄γλA(v) and γλA(rv)=0=0⋄0=γλA(r)⋄γλA(v). This implies,
μλA(r−v)≥μλA(r)∗μλA(v)andμλA(rv)≥μλA(r)∗μλA(v),γλA(r−v)≤γλA(r)⋄γλA(v)andγλA(rv)≤γλA(r)⋄γλA(v). |
Similarly we can prove the above expressions if r,v∉A.
Hence, λA=(μλA,γλA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed subring of NR.
Conversely, we hypothesise that the intuitionistic characteristic function λA=(μλA,γλA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed subring of NR. Let r,v∈A, then μλA(r)=1=μλA(v) and γλA(r)=0=γλA(v). So,
μλA(r−v)≥μλA(r)∗μλA(v)≥1∗1≥1,alsoμλA(r−v)≤1,μλA(rv)≥μλA(r)∗μλA(v)≥1∗1≥1,alsoμλA(rv)≤1,γλA(r−v)≤γλA(r)⋄γλA(v)≤0⋄0≤0,alsoγλA(r−v)≥0,γλA(rv)≤γλA(r)⋄γλA(v)≤0⋄0≤0,alsoγλA(rv)≥0, |
then μλA(r−v)=1, μλA(rv)=1 and γλA(r−v)=0, γλA(rv)=0, which implies that r−v and rv∈A. Therefore, A is a subring of NR.
Theorem 3.12. Let I be a non-empty subset of a normed ring NR, then I is an ideal of NR if and only if λI=(μλI,γλI) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proof. Let I be an ideal of NR and let r,v∈NR.
Case I. If r,v∈I then rv∈I and μλI(r)=1, μλI(v)=1 and γλI(r)=0, γλI(v)=0. Thus, μλI(rv)=1 and γλI(rv)=0. Accordingly, μλI(rv)=1=μλI(r)⋄μλI(v) and γλI(rv)=0=γλI(r)∗γλI(v).
Case II. If r∉I or v∉I so rv∉I, then μλI(r)=0 or μλI(v)=0 and γλI(r)=1 or γλI(v)=1. So, μλI(rv)=1≥μλI(r)⋄μλI(v) and γλI(rv)=0≤γλI(r)∗γλI(v). Hence, λI=(μλI,γλI) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
On the hand, we suppose λI=(μλI,γλI) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR. The proof is similar to the second part of the proof of Theorem 3.11.
Proposition 3.13. If A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR, then A∗ is an ideal of NR where A∗ is defined as,
A∗={r∈NR:μA(r)=μA(0)andγA(r)=γA(0)} |
Proof. See [10] (p. 6)
Lemma 3.14. Let A and B be two intuitionistic fuzzy normed left (right) ideal of NR. Therefore, A∗∩B∗⊆(A∩B)∗.
Proof. Let r∈A∗∩B∗, then μA(r)=μA(0), μB(r)=μB(0) and γA(r)=γA(0), γB(r)=γB(0).
μA∩B(r)=min{μA(r),μB(r)}=min{μA(0),μB(0)}=μA∩B(0) |
and
γA∩B(r)=max{γA(r),γB(r)}=max{γA(0),γB(0)}=γA∩B(0) |
So, r∈(A∩B)∗. Thus, A∗∩B∗⊆(A∩B)∗.
Theorem 3.15. Let f:NR→NR′ be an epimorphism mapping of normed rings. If A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of the normed ring NR, then f(A) is also an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR′.
Proof. Suppose A={(r,μA(r),γA(r)):r∈NR},
f(A)={(v,⋄f(r)=vμA(r),∗f(r)=vγA(r):r∈NR,v∈NR′}.
Let v1,v2∈NR′, then there exists r1,r2∈NR such that f(r1)=v1 and f(r2)=v2.
i.
μf(A)(v1−v2)=⋄f(r1−r2)=v1−v2μA(r1−r2)≥⋄f(r1)=v1,f(r2)=v2(μA(r1)∗μA(r2))≥(⋄f(r1)=v1μA(r1))∗(⋄f(r2)=v2μA(r2))≥μf(A)(v1)∗μf(A)(v2) |
ii.
μf(A)(v1v2)=⋄f(r1r2)=v1v2μA(r1r2)≥⋄f(r2)=v2μA(r2)≥μf(A)(v2) |
iii.
γf(A)(v1−v2)=∗f(r1−r2)=v1−v2γA(r1−r2)≤∗f(r1)=v1,f(r2)=v2(γA(r1)⋄γA(r2))≤(∗f(r1)=v1γA(r1))⋄(∗f(r2)=v2γA(r2))≤γf(A)(v1)⋄γf(A)(v2) |
iv.
γf(A)(v1v2)=∗f(r1r2)=v1v2γA(r1r2)≤∗f(r2)=v2γA(r2)≤γf(A)(v2) |
Hence, f(A) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal. Similarly, it can be justified that f(A) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed right ideal. Then, f(A) is a intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR′.
Proposition 3.16. Define f:NR→NR′ to be an epimorphism mapping. If B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of the normed ring NR′, then f−1(B) is also an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Proof. Suppose B={(v,μB(v),γB(v)):v∈NR′}, f−1(B)={(r,μf−1(B)(r),γf−1(B)(r):r∈NR}, where μf−1(B)(r)=μB(f(r)) and γf−1(B)(r)=γB(f(r)) for every r∈NR. Let r1,r2∈NR, then
i.
μf−1(B)(r1−r2)=μB(f(r1−r2))=μB(f(r1)−f(r2))≥μB(f(r1))∗μB(f(r2))≥μf−1(B)(r1)∗μf−1(B)(r2) |
ii.
μf−1(B)(r1r2)=μB(f(r1r2))=μB(f(r1)f(r2))≥μB(f(r2))≥μf−1(B)(r2) |
iii.
γf−1(B)(r1−r2)=γB(f(r1−r2))=γB(f(r1)−f(r2))≤γB(f(r1))⋄γB(f(r2))≤γf−1(B)(r1)⋄γf−1(B)(r2) |
iv.
γf−1(B)(r1r2)=γB(f(r1r2))=γB(f(r1)f(r2))≤γB(f(r2))≤γf−1(B)(r2) |
Therefore, f−1(B) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal of NR. Similarly, it can be justified that f−1(B) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed right ideal. So, f−1(B) is a intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
In what follows, we produce the terms of intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideals and intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideals and we investigate some associated properties.
Definition 4.1. An intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal A=(μA,γA) of a normed ring NR is said to be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR if for an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals B=(μB,γB) and C=(μC,γC) of NR where B∘C⊆A indicates that either B⊆A or C⊆A, which imply that μB⊆μA and γA⊆γB or μC⊆μA and γA⊆γC.
Proposition 4.2. An intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal A=(μA,γA) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal if for any two intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals B=(μB,γB) and C=(μC,γC) of NR satisfies:
i. μA⊇μB⊛C i.e. μA(r)≥⋄r=vz(μA(v)∗μB(z));
ii. γA⊆γB⊗C i.e.γA(r)≤∗r=vz(γA(v)⋄γB(z)).
Theorem 4.3. Let A be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR. Then ∣Im μA∣ = ∣Im γA∣=2; in other words A is two-valued.
Proof. As A is not constant, ∣Im μA∣≥2. assume that ∣Im μA∣≥3. Aα,β={r∈R:μA≥α and γA≤β} where α+β≤1. Let r∈NR and let B and C be two intuitionistic fuzzy subsets in NR, such that: μA(0)=s and k=glb{μA(r):r∈NR}, so there exists t,α∈ Im(μA) such that k≤t<α<s with μB(r)=12(t+α), μC(r)={s,ifr∈Aα,βk,ifr∉Aα,β and γA(0)=c and h=lub{γA(r):r∈NR}, then there exists d,β∈ Im(γA) such that c<β<d≤h with γB(r)=12(d+β) and γC(r)={c,ifr∈Aα,βh,ifr∉Aα,β for all r∈NR. Clearly B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR. Now we claim that C is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
Let r,v∈NR, if r,v∈Aα,β then r−v∈Aα,β and μC(r−v)=s=μC(r)∗μC(v), γC(r−v)=c=γC(r)⋄γC(v). If r∈Aα,β and v∉Aα,β then r−v∉Aα,β so, μC(r−v)=k=μC(r)∗μC(v), γC(r−v)=h=γC(r)⋄γC(v). If r,v∉Aα,β then r−v∉Aα,β so, μC(r−v)≥k=μC(r)∗μC(v), γC(r−v)≤h=γC(r)⋄γC(v). Hence, μC(r−v)≥μC(r)∗μC(v) and γC(r−v)≤γC(r)⋄γC(v) for all r,v∈NR.
Now if r∈Aα,β then rv∈Aα,β, thus μC(rv)=s=μC(r)⋄μC(v) and γC(rv)=c=γC(r)∗γC(v). If r∉Aα,β, then μC(rv)≥k=μC(r)⋄μC(v) and γC(rv)≤h=γC(r)∗γC(v). Therefore C is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR.
To prove that B∘C⊆A. Let r∈NR, we discuss the following cases:
(i) If r=0, consequently
μB⊛C(0)=⋄r=uv(μB(u)∗μC(v))≤12(t+α)<s=μA(0); |
γB⊗C(r)=∗r=uv(γB(u)⋄γC(v))≥12(d+β)>c=γA(0). |
(ii) If r≠0, r∈Aα,β. Then μA(r)≥α and γA(r)≤β. Thus,
μB⊛C(r)=⋄r=uv(μB(u)∗μC(v))≤12(t+α)<α≤μA(r); |
γB⊗C(r)=∗r=uv(γB(u)⋄γC(v))≥12(d+β)>β≥γA(r). |
Since μB(u)∗μC(v)≤μB(u) and γB(u)⋄γC(v)≥γB(u).
(iii) If r≠0, r∉Aα,β. Then in that case u,v∈NR such that r=uv, u∉Aα,β and v∉Aα,β. Then,
μB⊛C(r)=⋄r=uv(μB(u)∗μC(v))=k≤μA(r); |
γB⊗C(r)=∗r=uv(γB(u)⋄γC(v))=h≥γA(r). |
Therefore, in any case μB⊛C(r)≤μA(r) and γB⊗C(r)≥γA(r) for all r∈NR. Hence, B∘C⊆A.
Let a,b∈NR such that μA(a)=t, μA(b)=α and γA(a)=d, γA(b)=β. Thus, μB(a)=12(t+α)>t=μA(r) and γB(a)=12(d+β)<d=γA(r) which implies that B⊈A. Also, μA(b)=α and γA(b)=β imply that b∈Aα,β so, μC(b)=s>α and γC(b)=c<β, so C⊈A. Therefore, neither B⊈A nor C⊈A. This indicates that A could not be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR, so its a contradiction. Thus, ∣Im μA∣ = ∣ImγA∣=2.
Proposition 4.4. If A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR, so the following are satisfied:
i. μA(0NR)=1 and γA(0NR)=0;
ii. Im(μA)={1,α} and Im(γA)={0,β}, where α,β∈[0,1];
iii. A∗ is a prime ideal of NR.
Theorem 4.5. Let A be a fuzzy subset of NR where A is two-valued, μA(0)=1 and γA(0)=0, and the set A∗={r∈NR:μA(r)=μA(0) and γA(r)=γA(0)} is a prime ideal of NR. Hence, A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR.
Proof. We have Im(μA)={1,α} and Im(γA)={0,β}. Let r,v∈NR. If r,v∈A∗, then r−v∈A∗ so, μA(r−v)=1=μA(r)∗μA(v) and γA(r−v)=0=γA(r)⋄γA(v). If r,v∉A∗, then μA(r−v)=α≥μA(r)∗μA(v) and γA(r−v)=β≤γA(r)⋄γA(v).
Therefore, for all r,v∈NR,
μA(r−v)≥μA(r)∗μA(v)γA(r−v)≤γA(r)⋄γA(v) |
Similarly,
μA(rv)≥μA(r)⋄μA(v)γA(rv)≤γA(r)∗γA(v) |
Thus A is an intuitionistic fuzzy ideal of NR.
Assume B and C be fuzzy ideals of NR where B∘C⊆A. Assume that B⊈A and C⊈A. Then, we have r,v∈NR in such a way that μB(r)>μA(r) and γB(r)<γA(r), \mu_{C}(v) > \mu_{A}(v) and \gamma_{C}(r) < \gamma_{A}(r) , so for all a \in A_{\ast} , \mu_{A}(a) = 1 = \mu_{A}(0) and \gamma_{A}(a) = 0 = \gamma_{A}(0) , r \notin A_{\ast} and v \notin A_{\ast} . Since, A_{\ast} is a prime ideal of NR , we have n \in NR in such a way that rnv \notin A_{\ast} . Let a = rnv then \mu_{A}(a) = \mu_{A}(r) = \mu_{A}(v) = \alpha and \gamma_{A}(a) = \gamma_{A}(r) = \gamma_{A}(v) = \beta , now
\begin{equation*} \begin{array}{ll} \mu_{B \circledast C}(a)& = { \diamond \atop a = st}(\mu_{B}(s)\ast \mu_{C}(t))\\ &\geq \mu_{B}(r) \ast \mu_{C}(nv)\\ &\geq \mu_{B}(r) \ast \mu_{C}(v)\\ & > \alpha = \mu_{A}(a) \quad [Since, \mu_{B}(r) \geq \mu_{A}(r) = \alpha \quad and \quad \mu_{C}(nv)\geq \mu_{C}(v)\geq \mu_{A}(v) = \alpha].\\ \end{array} \end{equation*} |
and
\begin{equation*} \begin{array}{ll} \gamma_{B \otimes C}(a)& = { \ast \atop a = st}(\gamma_{B}(s)\diamond \gamma_{C}(t))\\ &\leq \gamma_{B}(r) \diamond \gamma_{C}(nv)\\ &\leq \gamma_{B}(r) \diamond \gamma_{C}(v)\\ & < \beta = \gamma_{A}(a) \quad [Since, \gamma_{B}(r) \leq \gamma_{A}(r) = \beta \quad and \quad \gamma_{C}(nv) \leq \gamma_{C}(v) \leq \gamma_{A}(v) = \beta].\\ \end{array}\\ \end{equation*} |
Which means that B \circ C \not\subseteq A . Which contradicts with the hypothesis that B \circ C \subseteq A . Therefore, either B \subseteq A or C \subseteq A . Then A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal.
Theorem 4.6. Let P be a subset (non-empty) of NR . P is a prime ideal if and only if the intuitionistic characteristic function \lambda_{P} = (\mu_{\lambda_{P}}, \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal.
Proof. presume that P is a prime ideal of NR . So by Theorem 3.12, \lambda_{P} is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR . Let A = (\mu_{A}, \gamma_{A}) and B = (\mu_{B}, \gamma_{B}) be any intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals of NR with A \circ B \subseteq \lambda_{P} while A \nsubseteq \lambda_{P} and B \nsubseteq \lambda_{P} . Then there exist r, v \in NR such that
\mu_{A}(r) \neq 0, \gamma_{A}(r) \neq 1 \quad and \quad \mu_{B}(v) \neq 0, \gamma_{B}(v) \neq 1 |
but
\mu_{\lambda_{P}}(r) = 0, \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(r) = 1 \quad and \quad \mu_{\lambda_{P}}(v) = 0, \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(v) = 1 |
Therefore, r \notin P and v \notin P . Since P is a prime ideal, there exist n \in NR such that rnv \notin P .
Let a = rnv , then \mu_{\lambda_{P}}(a) = 0 and \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(a) = 1 . Thus, \mu_{A \circledast b}(a) = 0 and \gamma_{A \otimes B}(a) = 1 . but
\begin{equation*} \begin{array}{lllll} \mu_{A \circledast B}(a)& = { \diamond \atop a = st}(\mu_{A}(s)\ast \mu_{B}(t))\\ &\geq \mu_{A}(r) \ast \mu_{B}(nv)\\ &\geq \mu_{A}(r) \ast \mu_{B}(v)\\ &\geq min \lbrace \mu_{A}(r), \mu_{B}(v)\rbrace\\ &\neq 0 \quad [Since, \mu_{A}(r) \neq 0 \quad and \quad \mu_{B}(v) \neq 0].\\ \end{array} \end{equation*} |
and
\begin{equation*} \begin{array}{lllll} \gamma_{A \otimes B}(a)& = { \ast \atop a = st}(\gamma_{A}(s)\diamond \gamma_{B}(t))\\ &\leq \gamma_{A}(r) \diamond \gamma_{B}(nv)\\ &\leq \gamma_{A}(r) \diamond \gamma_{B}(v)\\ &\leq max\lbrace \gamma_{A}(r), \gamma_{B}(v)\rbrace\\ &\neq 1 \quad [Since, \gamma_{A}(r) \neq 1 \quad and \quad \gamma_{B}(v) \neq 1].\\ \end{array} \\ \end{equation*} |
This is a contradiction with \mu_{\lambda_{P}}(a) = 0 and \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(a) = 1 . Thus for any intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals A and B of NR we have A \circ B \subseteq \lambda_{P} imply that A \subseteq \lambda_{P} or B \subseteq \lambda_{P} . So, \lambda_{P} = (\mu_{\lambda_{P}}, \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}) is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR .
Conversely, suppose \lambda_{P} is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal. Let A and B be two intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal of NR such that A \circ B \subseteq P . Let r \in NR , suppose \mu_{\lambda_{A} \circledast \lambda_{B}}(r) \neq 0 and \gamma_{\lambda_{A} \otimes \lambda_{B}}(r) \neq 1 , then \mu_{\lambda_{A} \circledast \lambda_{B}}(r) = { \diamond \atop r = cd}(\mu_{\lambda_{A}}(c)\ast \mu_{\lambda_{B}}(d))\neq 0 and \gamma_{\lambda_{A} \otimes \lambda_{B}}(r) = { \ast \atop r = cd}(\gamma_{\lambda_{A}}(c)\diamond \gamma_{\lambda_{B}}(d))\neq 1 . Then we have c, d \in NR such that r = cd , \mu_{\lambda_{A}}(c)\neq 0 , \mu_{\lambda_{B}}(d)\neq 0 and \gamma_{\lambda_{A}}(c)\neq 1 , \gamma_{\lambda_{B}}(d)\neq 1 . Then, \mu_{\lambda_{A}}(c) = 1 , \mu_{\lambda_{B}}(d) = 1 and \gamma_{\lambda_{A}}(c) = 0 , \gamma_{\lambda_{B}}(d) = 0 . Which implies c \in A and d \in B , therefore r = cd \in A \circ B \subseteq P . Then, \mu_{\lambda_{P}}(r) = 1 and \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(r) = 0 . Thus, for all r \in NR , \mu_{\lambda_{A} \circledast \lambda_{B}}(r) \leq \mu_{\lambda_{P}}(r) and \gamma_{\lambda_{A} \otimes \lambda_{B}}(r)\geq \gamma_{\lambda_{P}}(r) . So, \lambda_{A} \circ \lambda_{B} \subseteq \lambda_{P} . Since \lambda_{P} is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal. Then either \lambda_{A} \subseteq \lambda_{P} or \lambda_{B} \subseteq \lambda_{P} . Therefore, either A \subseteq P or B \subseteq P . Hence P is a prime ideal in NR .
Definition 4.7. [15] Given a ring R and a proper ideal M of R , M is a maximal ideal of R if any of the following equivalent conditions hold:
i. There exists no other proper ideal J of R so that M \subsetneq J .
ii. For any ideal J with M \subseteq J , either J = M or J = R .
Definition 4.8. An intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal A of a normed ring NR is said to be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideal if for any intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal B of NR , A\subseteq B , implies that either B_{*} = A_{*} or B = \lambda_{NR} . Intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left (right) ideal are correspondingly specified.
Proposition 4.9. Let A be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left (right) ideal of NR . Then, \mid \rm Im\; \mu_{A}\mid = \mid \rm Im\; \gamma_{A}\mid = 2
Theorem 4.10. Let A be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left (right) ideal of a normed ring NR . Then A_{\ast} = \lbrace r\in NR :\mu_{A}(r) = \mu_{A}(0) and \gamma_{A}(r) = \gamma_{A}(0)\rbrace is a maximal left (right) ideal of NR .
Proof. As A is not constant, A_{\ast} \neq NR . Then using Proposition 4.9, A is two-valued. Let Im (\mu_{A}) = \lbrace 1, \alpha \rbrace and Im (\gamma_{A}) = \lbrace 0, \beta \rbrace , where 0 \leq \alpha < 1 and 0 < \beta \leq 1 . Assume M to be a left ideal of NR in away that A_{\ast} \subseteq M . Take B be an intuitionistic fuzzy subset of NR where if r \in M then \mu_{B}(r) = 1 and \gamma_{B}(r) = 0 and if r \notin M then \mu_{B}(r) = c and \gamma_{B}(r) = d , where \alpha < c < 1 and 0 < d < \beta . Then B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal. Obviously A \subseteq B . As A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left ideal of NR then A_{*} = B_{*} or B = \lambda_{NR} . If A_{*} = B_{*} then A_{*} = M given that B_{*} = M . If B = \lambda_{NR} subsequently M = NR . Therefore, A_{*} is a maximal left ideal of NR .
Theorem 4.11. If A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left (right) ideal of NR , then \mu_{A}(0) = 1 and \gamma_{A}(0) = 0 .
Proof. Suppose \mu_{A}(0)\neq 1 and \gamma_{A}(0)\neq 0 and B to be an intuitionistic fuzzy subset of NR defined as B = \lbrace r\in NR:\mu_{B}(r) = h and \gamma_{B}(r) = k\rbrace , where \mu_{A}(0) < h < 1 and 0 < k < \gamma_{A}(0) . Then, B is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal of NR . We can simply check that A \subset B , B \neq \lambda_{NR} and B_{\ast} = \lbrace r\in NR:\mu_{B}(r) = \mu_{B}(0) and \gamma_{B}(r) = \gamma_{B}(0)\rbrace = NR . Hence, A \subset B but A_{\ast}\neq B_{\ast} and B \neq \lambda_{NR} which contradicts with the assumption that A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideal of NR . Therefore, \mu_{A}(0) = 1 and \gamma_{A}(0) = 0 .
Theorem 4.12. Let A be a intuitionistic fuzzy normed left (right) ideal of NR . If A_{\ast} is a maximal left (right) ideal of NR with \mu_{A}(0) = 1 and \gamma_{A}(0) = 0 , then A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left (right) ideal of NR .
Proof. By Proposition 4.9 A is two-valued. Let Im (\mu_{A}) = \lbrace 1, \alpha \rbrace and Im (\gamma_{A}) = \lbrace 0, \beta \rbrace , where 0 \leq \alpha < 1 and 0 < \beta \leq 1 . Define B to be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left ideal of NR where A \subseteq B . Hence, \mu_{B}(0) = 1 and \gamma_{B}(0) = 0 . Let r \in A_{\ast} . Then 1 = \mu_{A}(0) = \mu_{A}(r)\leq \mu_{B}(r) and 0 = \gamma_{A}(0) = \gamma_{A}(r)\geq \gamma_{B}(r) . Thus \mu_{B}(r) = 1 = \mu_{B}(0) and \gamma_{B}(r) = 0 = \gamma_{B}(0) , hence r \in B_{\ast} then A_{\ast} \subseteq B_{\ast} . Given that A_{\ast} a maximal left ideal of NR , then A_{\ast} = B_{\ast} or B_{\ast} = NR . If B_{\ast} = NR subsequently B = \lambda_{NR} . Therefore, A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal left ideal of NR .
Remark 4.13. Let A \subseteq NR and let 0 \leq \alpha \leq 1 and 0 \leq \beta \leq 1 . Let \lambda_{A_{\alpha, \beta}} be an intuitionistic fuzzy subset of NR where \mu_{\lambda_{A_{\alpha}}}(r) = 1 if r \in A , \mu_{\lambda_{A_{\alpha}}}(r) = \alpha if r \notin A and \gamma_{\lambda_{A_{\beta}}}(r) = 0 if r \in A , \gamma_{\lambda_{A_{\beta}}}(r) = \beta if r \notin A . If \alpha = 0 and \beta = 1 , the \lambda_{A_{\alpha, \beta}} is the intuitionistic characteristic function of A , which identified by \lambda_{A} = (\mu_{\lambda_{A}}, \gamma_{\lambda_{A}}) . If NR is a ring and A is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left (right) ideal of NR , then:
- \mu_{\lambda_{A_{\alpha}}}(0) = 1 , \gamma_{\lambda_{A_{\beta}}}(0) = 0 ;
- ({\lambda_{A_{\alpha, \beta}}})_{\ast} = A , [({\lambda_{A_{\alpha, \beta}}})_{\ast} = \lbrace r \in NR: \mu_{\lambda_{A_{\alpha}}}(r) = \mu_{\lambda_{A_{\alpha}}}(0) , \gamma_{\lambda_{A_{\beta}}}(r) = \gamma_{\lambda_{A_{\beta}}}(0)\rbrace = A] ;
- Im (\mu_{A}) = \lbrace 1, \alpha \rbrace and Im (\gamma_{A}) = \lbrace 0, \beta \rbrace ;
- \lambda_{A_{\alpha, \beta}} is an intuitionistic fuzzy normed left (right) ideal of NR .
In this article, we defined the intrinsic product of two intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals and proved that this product is a subset of their intersection. Also, we characterized some properties of intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideals. We initiated the concepts of intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime ideal and intuitionistic fuzzy normed maximal ideal and we established several results related to these ideals. Further, we specified the conditions under which a given intuitionistic fuzzy normed ideal is considered to be an intuitionistic fuzzy normed prime (maximal) ideal. We generalised the relation between the intuitionistic characteristic function and prime (maximal) ideals.
The author declares no conflict of interest in this paper
[1] |
Adnan Z, Chakraborty K, Bag S, et al. (2023) Pricing and green investment strategies for electric vehicle supply chain in a competitive market under different channel leadership. Ann Oper Res 1–36. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-023-05523-y doi: 10.1007/s10479-023-05523-y
![]() |
[2] |
Asghari T, Taleizadeh AA, Jolai F, et al. (2022) Cooperative game for coordination of a green closed-loop supply chain. J Clean Prod 363: 132371. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.132371 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.132371
![]() |
[3] |
Bai Q, Gong Y, Jin M, et al. (2019) Effects of carbon emission reduction on supply chain coordination with vendor-managed deteriorating product inventory. Int J Prod Econ 208: 83–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2018.11.008 doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2018.11.008
![]() |
[4] |
Behrooz K, Adel G, Kannan G, et al.(2023) Pricing strategies in a dual-channel green closed-loop supply chain considering incentivized recycling and circular economy. J Clean Prod 423: 138738. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2023.138738 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2023.138738
![]() |
[5] |
Cao K, He P, Liu Z (2020) Production and pricing decisions in a dual-channel supply chain under remanufacturing subsidy policy and carbon tax policy. J Oper Res Soc 71: 1199–1215. https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2019.1605471 doi: 10.1080/01605682.2019.1605471
![]() |
[6] |
Cao X, Yuan P, Wen H, et al. (2022) Pricing and recycling decisions of remanufacturing alliances with third-party recycling platform. Ann Oper Res, 1–33. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-05003-9 doi: 10.1007/s10479-022-05003-9
![]() |
[7] |
Daryanto Y, Wee HM, Astanti RD (2019) Three-echelon supply chain model considering carbon emission and item deterioration. Transp Res E Logist Transp Rev 122: 368–383. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2018.12.014 doi: 10.1016/j.tre.2018.12.014
![]() |
[8] |
Dolai M, Banu A, Mondal SK (2023) Analyzing an imperfect production inventory model for green products considering learning effect on screening process under advertisement dependent credit period. J Ind Manage Optim 19: 5486–5514. https://doi.org/10.3934/jimo.2022182 doi: 10.3934/jimo.2022182
![]() |
[9] |
Gao H, Liu S, Xing D, et al. (2018) Optimization strategy of cooperation and emission reduction in supply chain under carbon tax policy. J Discrete Math Sci Cryptogr 21: 825–835. https://doi.org/10.1080/09720529.2018.1479165 doi: 10.1080/09720529.2018.1479165
![]() |
[10] |
Fadavi A, Jolai F, Taleizadeh AA (2022) Green product design in a supply chain with considering marketing under competition and coordination. Environ Dev Sustain 24: 11721–11759. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01917-9 doi: 10.1007/s10668-021-01917-9
![]() |
[11] |
Haijie F, Liying Y, Ziyuan Z (2024) Promoting consumer returns in closed-loop supply chains under cap-and-trade regulation: A cooperative recycling advertising perspective. J Clean Prod 436: 140584. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.140584 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.140584
![]() |
[12] |
Heydari J, Govindan K, Basiri Z (2021) Balancing price and green quality in presence of consumer environmental awareness: a green supply chain coordination approach. Int J Prod Res 59: 1957–1975. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2020.1771457 doi: 10.1080/00207543.2020.1771457
![]() |
[13] |
Hosseini-Motlagh S, Ebrahimi S, Jokar A (2021) Sustainable supply chain coordination under competition and green effort scheme. J Oper Res Soc 72: 304–319. https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2019.1671152 doi: 10.1080/01605682.2019.1671152
![]() |
[14] |
Huang Y, Fang C, Lin Y (2020) Inventory management in supply chains with consideration of Logistics, green investment and different carbon emissions policies. Comput Ind Eng 139: 106207. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2019.106207 doi: 10.1016/j.cie.2019.106207
![]() |
[15] |
Huang H, Ke H, Wang L (2016) Equilibrium analysis of pricing competition and cooperation in supply chain with one common manufacturer and duopoly retailers. Int J Prod Econ 178: 12–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.04.022 doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.04.022
![]() |
[16] |
Jafari H, Hejazi SR, Rasti-Barzoki M (2016) Pricing Decisions in Dual-Channel Supply Chain Including Monopolistic Manufacturer and Duopolistic Retailers: A Game-Theoretic Approach. J Ind Compet Trade 16: 323–343. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-016-0224-1 doi: 10.1007/s10842-016-0224-1
![]() |
[17] |
Jauhari WA, Adam Niimas AFP, Rosyidi CN, et al. (2020) A closed-loop supply chain model with rework, waste disposal, and carbon emissions. Oper Res Perspect 7: 100155. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.orp.2020.100155 doi: 10.1016/j.orp.2020.100155
![]() |
[18] |
Jamali M, Rasti-Barzoki M (2019) A game theoretic approach to investigate the effects of third-party logistics in a sustainable supply chain by reducing delivery time and carbon emissions. J Clean Prod 235: 636–652. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.06.348 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.06.348
![]() |
[19] |
Jiang G, Ji Y, Wu Z, et al.(2021) The optimal strategies in the supply chain with stochastic demand sensitivity to carbon emission. J Control Decis 8: 64–76. https://doi.org/10.1080/23307706.2020.1819451 doi: 10.1080/23307706.2020.1819451
![]() |
[20] |
Jiang X, Zheng Y (2023) Pricing decisions and remanufacturing strategies considering consumer recycling behavior. Ann Oper Res 322: 755–792. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-05115-2 doi: 10.1007/s10479-022-05115-2
![]() |
[21] |
Jianhui C, Yan T, Felix TSC, et al.(2024) Pricing, greening, and recycling decisions of capital-constrained closed-loop supply chain with government subsidies under financing strategies. J Clean Prod 438: 140797. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.140797 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.140797
![]() |
[22] |
Karim R, Nakade K (2021) Modelling a one retailer–one manufacturer supply chain system considering environmental sustainability and disruption. Int J Syst Sci Oper 8: 297–320. https://doi.org/10.1080/23302674.2020.1756006 doi: 10.1080/23302674.2020.1756006
![]() |
[23] |
Li B, Zhu M, Jiang Y, et al. (2016) Pricing policies of a competitive dual-channel green supply chain. J Clean Prod 112: 2029–2042. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.05.017 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.05.017
![]() |
[24] |
Lin J, Zhou S, Gao F (2019) Production and technology choice under emissions regulation: centralized vs decentralized supply chains. IISE Transactions 51: 57–73. https://doi.org/10.1080/24725854.2018.1506193 doi: 10.1080/24725854.2018.1506193
![]() |
[25] |
Liu Y, Huang C, Song Q, et al. (2018) Carbon emissions reduction and transfer in supply chains under A cap-and-trade system with emissions-sensitive demand Syst Sci Control Eng 6: 37–44. https://doi.org/10.1080/21642583.2018.1509398 doi: 10.1080/21642583.2018.1509398
![]() |
[26] |
Mandal A, Pal B (2023) Investigating dual-channel green supply chain considering refurbishing process and product recycling with environmental awareness effort. Math Comput Simul 204: 695–726. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matcom.2022.09.009 doi: 10.1016/j.matcom.2022.09.009
![]() |
[27] |
Mandal A, Pal B (2021) Optimizing profit for pricing and advertisement sensitive demand under unreliable production system. Int J Syst Sci Oper 8: 99–118. https://doi.org/10.1080/23302674.2019.1646835 doi: 10.1080/23302674.2019.1646835
![]() |
[28] |
Mandal A, Pal B (2021) Effects of green innovation and advertisement in an imperfect production-based competitive supply chain under two-tier credit facility. Math Methods Appl Sci 44: 13227–13251. https://doi.org/10.1002/mma.7620 doi: 10.1002/mma.7620
![]() |
[29] |
Modak NM, Panda S, Sana SS (2016) Two-echelon supply chain coordination among manufacturer and duopolies retailers with recycling facility. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 87: 1531–1546. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00170-015-8094-y doi: 10.1007/s00170-015-8094-y
![]() |
[30] |
Mondal C, Giri C (2020) Pricing and used product collection strategies in a two-period closed-loop supply chain under greening level and effort dependent demand. J Clean Prod 265: 121335. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.121335 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.121335
![]() |
[31] |
Mondal C, Giri C (2022) Retailers' competition and cooperation in a closed-loop green supply chain under governmental intervention and cap-and-trade policy. Oper Res Int J 22: 859–894. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12351-020-00596-0 doi: 10.1007/s12351-020-00596-0
![]() |
[32] |
Pal B, Sana S, Chaudhuri KS (2015) Coordination contracts for competitive two-echelon supply chain with price and promotional effort sensitive non-linear demand. Int J Syst Sci Oper 2: 113–124. https://doi.org/10.1080/23302674.2015.1004204 doi: 10.1080/23302674.2015.1004204
![]() |
[33] |
Pal B, Sana S, Chaudhuri KS (2016) Two-echelon competitive integrated supply chain model with price and credit period dependent demand. Int J Syst Sci 47: 995–1007. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207721.2014.911383 doi: 10.1080/00207721.2014.911383
![]() |
[34] |
Pal B, Sarkar A (2021) Optimal strategies of a dual-channel green supply chain with recycling under retailer promotional effort. RAIRO Oper Res 55: 415–431. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2021016 doi: 10.1051/ro/2021016
![]() |
[35] |
Pal B, Mandal A, Sana SS (2021) Two-phase deteriorated supply chain model with variable demand and imperfect production process under two-stage credit financing. RAIRO Oper Res 55: 457–480. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2021008 doi: 10.1051/ro/2021008
![]() |
[36] |
Pal B, Sarkar A (2022) Effects of green improvement and pricing policies in a double dual-channel competitive supply chain under decision-making power strategies. RAIRO Oper Res 56: 931–953. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2022030 doi: 10.1051/ro/2022030
![]() |
[37] |
Panja S, Mondal SK (2023) Integrating online and offline business of a retailer: A customer utility based inventory model. Comput Ind Eng 175: 108888. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2022.108888 doi: 10.1016/j.cie.2022.108888
![]() |
[38] |
Pang Q, Li M, Yang T, et al. (2018) Supply Chain Coordination with Carbon Trading Price and Consumers' Environmental Awareness Dependent Demand. Math Probl Eng. https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/8749251 doi: 10.1155/2018/8749251
![]() |
[39] |
Parsaeifar S, Bozorgi-Amiri A, Naimi-Sadigh A, et al. (2019) A game theoretical for coordination of pricing, recycling, and green product decisions in the supply chain. J Clean Prod 226: 37–49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.03.343 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.03.343
![]() |
[40] |
Ranjbar Y, Sahebi H, Ashayeri J, et al. (2020) A competitive dual recycling channel in a three-level closed loop supply chain under different power structures: Pricing and collecting decisions. J Clean Prod. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122623 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122623
![]() |
[41] |
Rezaei S, Maihami R (2020) Optimizing the sustainable decisions in a multi-echelon closed-loop supply chain of the manufacturing/remanufacturing products with a competitive environment. Environ Dev Sustain 22: 6445–-6471. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-019-00491-5 doi: 10.1007/s10668-019-00491-5
![]() |
[42] |
Taleizadeh AA, Alizadeh-Basban N, Niaki STA (2019) A closed-loop supply chain considering carbon reduction, quality improvement effort, and return policy under two remanufacturing scenarios. J Clean Prod 232: 1230–1250. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.05.372 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.05.372
![]() |
[43] |
Taleizadeh AA, Niaki STA, Alizadeh-Basban N (2021) Cost-sharing contract in a closed-loop supply chain considering carbon abatement, quality improvement effort, and pricing strategy. RAIRO Oper Res 55: S2181–S2219. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2020072 doi: 10.1051/ro/2020072
![]() |
[44] |
Taleizadeh AA, Shahriari M, Sana SS (2021) Pricing and coordination strategies in a dual channel supply chain with green production under cap and trade regulation. Sustainability 13: 12232. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132112232 doi: 10.3390/su132112232
![]() |
[45] |
Tsao Y, Linh V, Lu J, et al. (2018) A supply chain network with product remanufacturing and carbon emission considerations: a two-phase design. J Intell Manuf 29: 693–705. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10845-017-1296-4 doi: 10.1007/s10845-017-1296-4
![]() |
[46] |
Wang L, Song Q (2020) Pricing policies for dual-channel supply chain with green investment and sales effort under uncertain demand. Math Comput Simul 171: 79–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matcom.2019.08.010 doi: 10.1016/j.matcom.2019.08.010
![]() |
[47] |
Wang Z, Wu Q (2020) Carbon emission reduction and product collection decisions in the closed-loop supply chain with cap-and-trade regulation. Int J Prod Res 59: 4359–4383. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2020.1762943 doi: 10.1080/00207543.2020.1762943
![]() |
[48] |
Wei J, Chen W, Liu, G (2021) How manufacturer's integration strategies affect closed-loop supply chain performance. Int J Prod Res 59: 4287–4305. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2020.1762016 doi: 10.1080/00207543.2020.1762016
![]() |
[49] |
Xu J, Chen Y, Bai Q (2016) A two-echelon sustainable supply chain coordination under cap-and-trade regulation. J Clean Prod 135: 42–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.06.047 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.06.047
![]() |
[50] |
Xu X, He P, Xu H, et al. (2017) Supply chain coordination with green technology under cap-and-trade regulation. Int J Prod Econ 183: 433–442. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.08.029 doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.08.029
![]() |
[51] |
Xu L, Wang C, Miao Z, et al. (2019) Governmental subsidy policies and supply chain decisions with carbon emission limit and consumer's environmental awareness. RAIRO Oper Res 53: 1675–1689. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2018094 doi: 10.1051/ro/2018094
![]() |
[52] |
Zhang Z, Liu S, Niu B (2020) Coordination mechanism of dual-channel closed-loop supply chains considering product quality and return. J Clean Prod 248: 119273. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.119273 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.119273
![]() |