This study examines the aftermarket performance of high-green and low-green IPO and how green IPOs can optimize portfolio allocation. We assume the higher level of greenness increases investors' participation in IPOs. To this end, we develop the utility function and determine that investors prefer to participate in new issues when firms account for greenness measures. This study proposes the global aspects of green measure: the desired level of greenness a firm maintains. We find that IPOs in our sample are far below the global standards of greenness. This evidence suggests they must adopt the necessary actions to make the environment green. Another significant contribution of this study is to measure the performance of high and low-green IPOs in short- and long-run horizons. This study reveals that high-green IPOs are less underpriced. This study estimates the effect of greenness on initial returns and finds an inverse relationship suggesting that high-green IPOs are less underpriced due to lower risk associated with new issues. In terms of measuring longer-term performance, this study determines that high-green IPOs underperform less than low-green IPOs.
Citation: Muhammad Zubair Mumtaz, Naoyuki Yoshino. Aftermarket performance of green IPOs and portfolio allocation[J]. Green Finance, 2023, 5(3): 321-342. doi: 10.3934/GF.2023013
[1] | Zhehao Huang, Yingting Miao, Zhenzhen Wang . Free boundary problem pricing defaultable corporate bonds with multiple credit rating migration risk and stochastic interest rate. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(6): 7746-7775. doi: 10.3934/math.2020495 |
[2] | Zhongdi Cen, Jian Huang, Aimin Xu, Anbo Le . An iterative method for solving a PDE with free boundary arising from pricing corporate bond with credit rating migration. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(2): 3286-3302. doi: 10.3934/math.2023169 |
[3] | Wei Gong, Zhanping Wang . Stability of nonlinear population systems with individual scale and migration. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(1): 125-147. doi: 10.3934/math.2023006 |
[4] | Riza Andrian Ibrahim, Sukono, Herlina Napitupulu, Rose Irnawaty Ibrahim . Modeling earthquake bond prices with correlated dual trigger indices and the approximate solution using the Monte Carlo algorithm. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2223-2253. doi: 10.3934/math.2025103 |
[5] | Won-Kwang Park . On the identification of small anomaly in microwave imaging without homogeneous background information. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 27210-27226. doi: 10.3934/math.20231392 |
[6] | Wen Chao . Pricing catastrophe reinsurance under the standard deviation premium principle. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(3): 4472-4484. doi: 10.3934/math.2022249 |
[7] | Meng Pang, Zhe Li . A novel profit-based validity index approach for feature selection in credit risk prediction. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 974-997. doi: 10.3934/math.2024049 |
[8] | Sun-Yong Choi, Donghyun Kim, Ji-Hun Yoon . An analytic pricing formula for timer options under constant elasticity of variance with stochastic volatility. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 2454-2472. doi: 10.3934/math.2024121 |
[9] | Altyeb Taha . A novel deep learning-based hybrid Harris hawks with sine cosine approach for credit card fraud detection. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(10): 23200-23217. doi: 10.3934/math.20231180 |
[10] | Seong-Ho Son, Kwang-Jae Lee, Won-Kwang Park . Real-time tracking of moving objects from scattering matrix in real-world microwave imaging. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 13570-13588. doi: 10.3934/math.2024662 |
This study examines the aftermarket performance of high-green and low-green IPO and how green IPOs can optimize portfolio allocation. We assume the higher level of greenness increases investors' participation in IPOs. To this end, we develop the utility function and determine that investors prefer to participate in new issues when firms account for greenness measures. This study proposes the global aspects of green measure: the desired level of greenness a firm maintains. We find that IPOs in our sample are far below the global standards of greenness. This evidence suggests they must adopt the necessary actions to make the environment green. Another significant contribution of this study is to measure the performance of high and low-green IPOs in short- and long-run horizons. This study reveals that high-green IPOs are less underpriced. This study estimates the effect of greenness on initial returns and finds an inverse relationship suggesting that high-green IPOs are less underpriced due to lower risk associated with new issues. In terms of measuring longer-term performance, this study determines that high-green IPOs underperform less than low-green IPOs.
Credit rating migration risk is an important kind of credit risk, referring to the possibility of potential losses due to changes in credit rating. The phenomenon of rating movements has long attracted the attention of academia and industry and there have been many studies on the performance and patterns of credit rating transitions [1,2,3,4,5,6]. As for the valuation of credit migration risk, the used models are mainly categorized into two types: the reduced-form model and the structural model. The former employs a transition density matrix to characterize the process of credit rating migrations, such as [7,8,9] while the latter utilizes the company's own financial status as the determinant of credit rating changes, such as [10,11,12,13]. Each kind of model has its advantages, but the structural model elucidates the mechanism of credit migration by explicitly linking credit ratings to the company's assets and liabilities.
Liang and Zeng ([10], 2015) constructed the first structural model for assessing credit migration risk by pricing a corporate bond with this risk. By predefining an asset threshold as the boundary for credit migration, the company's asset values are divided into high and low rating regions. In different regions, the asset values follow geometric Brownian motions with different volatilities. The model was derived as an initial value problem of parabolic differential equations which are coupled on a fixed inner boundary. Further, Hu et al. ([11], 2015) took the asset-liability ratio as a threshold for credit migration and deduced the migration boundary as a free boundary. On these bases, more theoretical analyses are provided, such as the asymptotic traveling wave solution [14], convergence rate of the difference scheme [15], multi-credit rating case [16], steady-state solution [17], etc (see also [18,19,20,21,22]). There are also some empirical results for the single threshold model, for instance, the credit migration boundary was identified by pricing long-term bonds in the U.S. corporate bond market [23]. In those models with the fixed boundaries or free boundaries, the thresholds for upgrades and downgrades are the same. However, this single threshold may lead to infinite frequent changes in credit ratings within a short period, due to the assumption that asset values follow Brownian motions which can cross any level infinitely many times within any time interval. Chen and Liang ([12], 2021) made an improvement based on the free boundary model by introducing different asset-liability ratio thresholds for upgrades and downgrades, resulting in a pair of migration boundaries. As a buffer zone is formed between these two boundaries, the frequency of credit rating migrations per unit time becomes finite. Liang and Lin ([13], 2023) made a similar modification, applying a pair of asymmetric asset thresholds to the fixed boundary model, and obtaining a system of partial differential equations coupled with each other on a pair of fixed boundaries. Liang and Lin ([24], 2023) further explored an asymptotic traveling wave solution with a buffer zone for this kind of model.
These structural credit migration models with thresholds are somewhat similar in form to the credit barrier model considered in Albanese and Chen ([3], 2006). A stochastic process with state-dependent volatilities was used to model the credit quality process, which directly indicated the dynamic of credit rating, with barrier crossings corresponding to credit migrations and default events, in Albanese and Chen ([3], 2006). The variable of credit quality might capture the firm's fundamental information but did not articulate specific implications in finance. In the structural models of Liang et al., the credit migrations were delineated by the crossings of the thresholds as well, with the driving factors explicitly identified as the asset value or the asset-liability ratio. Since the asset value was assumed to follow the Brownian motion with different volatilities in different ratings, the distribution of future asset value depends on only the current rating and value of asset, and not on the history of previous states, even in the structural models with buffer zones. Therefore, these models we analyze in this paper cannot capture non-Markov effects in rating transition probabilities, such as those identified in Lando and Skødeberg ([4], 2002), Nickell et al. ([6], 2000), etc.
According to whether or not the upgrade threshold and downgrade threshold are the same, the structural models are classified into the single threshold model and the model with different upgrade and downgrade thresholds. We already know that substituting a pair of asymmetric thresholds for a single threshold avoids high-frequency fluctuations in credit ratings. However a natural question arises: What is the relationship between those two kinds of models? Intuitively, when upgrade threshold and downgrade threshold are very close, the asymmetric threshold model's behavior should be similar to that of a single threshold model. This article attempts to answer this question rigorously within the scope of the credit migration problem with fixed boundaries. We consider two fixed boundary models: one model from [10] with X(X>0) as a critical threshold for credit migration, and the other model from [13] with X as a threshold for downgrades, and Xε:=X+ε (depending on a small parameter ε>0) as a threshold for upgrades. By techniques of partial differential equations, we prove that the solution of the asymmetric threshold problem converges to that of the single threshold problem when the upgrade threshold Xε approaches the downgrade threshold X as ε→0. To our knowledge, it is the first time that the asymptotic relationship between the single threshold and a pair of asymmetric thresholds has been shown in credit migration problems. Therefore, when ε is small enough, the different upgrade and downgrade threshold model can be approximated by a single threshold model, which already has more theoretical and empirical results.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the single threshold and the different downgrade and upgrade threshold model for credit migration problems with fixed boundaries are reviewed. In Section 3, we prove a series of lemmas to establish ε-independent estimates for the solution of the asymmetric threshold problem. In Section 4, a key step is shown that the first-order derivatives of the asymmetric threshold problem's solution on both sides of x=X tend to be equal, as ε approaches zero. It follows that the solution of this model converges to that of a single threshold model by compactness. Section 5 is a summary of this paper.
The structural models with fixed migration boundaries assess credit rating migration risk by pricing a zero-coupon corporate bond.
Let (Ω,F,P) be a complete probability space. Assuming that the company only issues one bond with a face value of 1 and a maturity of T, the bond is considered as a contingent claim of the company's asset value on the space (Ω,F,P). At maturity, the bond will default and pay out the remaining assets if the company's asset value is less than the face value of the bond. Let St denote the company's asset value in the risk-neutral world. It satisfies
dSt={rStdt+σHStdWt, in high rating region, rStdt+σLStdWt, in low rating region, |
where r is the risk-free interest rate, and
σH<σL | (2.1) |
represent volatilities (positive constants) of the company under the high and low credit grades respectively. Wt is the standard Brownian motion which generates the filtration {Ft}. High and low rating regions are determined by the company's asset value. Inequality (2.1) captures the characteristics of the high and low credit ratings, with the volatility of asset return in the lower rating region being greater than the volatility in the higher rating region.
Liang and Zeng ([10], 2015) (referred to as LZ's model hereafter) gave a single predetermined threshold to divide asset value into high and low rating regions. Through a standard variable transformation x=logS and renaming T−t as t, we set the migration boundary as X(X>0) and represented the values of low and high-rated bonds as vL(x,t) and vH(x,t), respectively. The model is derived as the following partial differential equation problem:
{∂vH∂t−12σ2H∂2vH∂x2−(r−12σ2H)∂vH∂x+rvH=0,for x>X,t>0,∂vL∂t−12σ2L∂2vL∂x2−(r−12σ2L)∂vL∂x+rvL=0,for x<X,t>0,vH(x,0)=min{ex,1},for x>X,vL(x,0)=min{ex,1},for x<X,vH(X,t)=vL(X,t),for t>0,∂vH∂x(X,t)=∂vL∂x(X,t),for t>0. | (2.2) |
We define a solution v over the entire region (−∞,∞)×[0,∞) as follows:
v={vH(x,t), forx≥X,t≥0,vL(x,t), forx<X,t≥0. | (2.3) |
Liang and Lin ([13], 2023) (referred to as LL's model hereafter) proposed a pair of asymmetric thresholds for credit migrations: one threshold for downgrades and the other slightly higher threshold for upgrades. After the same change of variables as in Section 2.1, we have set the downgrade threshold as X(X>0) and the upgrade threshold as Xε:=X+ε,ε>0. Denote by uLε(x,t) and uHε(x,t) the bond values in low rating and high rating, respectively. They are captured by the following PDE problem:
{∂uHε∂t−12σ2H∂2uHε∂x2−(r−12σ2H)∂uHε∂x+ruHε=0,for x>X,t>0,∂uLε∂t−12σ2L∂2uLε∂x2−(r−12σ2L)∂uLε∂x+ruLε=0,for x<Xε,t>0,uHε(x,0)=min{ex,1},for x>X,uLε(x,0)=min{ex,1},for x<Xε,uHε(X,t)=uLε(X,t),for t>0,uLε(Xε,t)=uHε(Xε,t),for t>0. | (2.4) |
Note that vLε and vHε overlap in [X,Xε]×[0,∞). To be comparable with v, we rearrange uε over the entire region as the following formula:
uε={uHε(x,t), forx≥X,t≥0,uLε(x,t), forx<X,t≥0. | (2.5) |
Letting the upgrade threshold Xε approach the downgrade threshold X, we find an asymptotic behavior of LL's model, i.e., as ε→0, uε converges to v. This actuallly constructs an asymptotic relationship between LL's model and LZ's model. To prove this, we first establish some ε-independent estimates for the solution (uLε,uHε). Based on this, |uLεx(X−,t)−uHεx(X+,t)| approaching 0 as ε→0 is verified as a key step. Further, we suggest that any convergent subsequence of uε tends to the solution v of LZ's model as ε→0.
Define Li=∂∂t−12σi2∂2∂x2−(r−12σi2)∂∂x+r⋅,i=H,L; QLε=(−∞,Xε)×(0,∞), and QH=(X,∞)×(0,∞).
For any given ε, we iteratively define a sequence {uLεk,uHεk}∞k=0, which is proved to decrease with k and converge to (uLε,uHε) as k→0 in Liang and Lin ([13], 2023). In detail, the sequence satisfies equations
LL[uLεk]=0 in QLε, LH[uHεk]=0 in QH, |
with the initial value min{ex,1}. Starting from uLε0(Xε,t)≡1 and by the induction assumption uHεk(X,t)=uLεk(X,t) and uLε(k+1)(Xε,t)=uHεk(Xε,t), we have completed the definition of the sequence.
The estimations of the maximum norm of (uLε,uHε) and its first-order derivative with respect to time t are carried out by induction on the sequence {uLεk,uHεk}∞k=0. As for the boundary estimate of (uLεx,uHεx), we introduce barrier functions.
Lemma 3.1.
0≤uLε≤min{ex,1} in QLε, 0≤uHε≤min{ex,1} in QH. | (3.1) |
Proof. By the induction and maximum principle, for each k≥0, 0≤uHεk≤min{ex,1} in QH, and 0≤uLεk≤min{ex,1} in QLε.
Lemma 3.2.
−C1≤∂uLε∂t≤0 in QLε∖¯Qρ, −C1≤∂uHε∂t≤0 in QH, | (3.2) |
where Qρ=(−ρ/2,ρ/2)×(0,ρ2/4) and 0<ρ<X.
Proof. We claim that −C1≤uLεkt,uHεkt≤0 for any k∈N and C1 is independent of ε and k.
Differentiating uLεk and uHεk with respect to t, they satisfy
LL[uLεkt]=0 in QLε, LH[uLεkt]=0 in QH. |
On the migration boundaries, uLεkt(Xε,t)=uHε(k−1)t(Xε,t) and uHεkt(X,t)=uLεkt(X,t).
It is also clear that initially
uLεkt(x,0)=0 forx<0,uLεkt(x,0)=−r for0<x<Xε, | (3.3) |
uHεkt(x,0)=−r forx>X. | (3.4) |
At x=0,uLεkxx(x,0) produces a Dirac measure of density −1. Thus, in the distribution sense,
uLεkt(x,0)≤0 forx<Xε. | (3.5) |
From the standard parabolic estimates (see e.g. [25]), there exists constants c1,c2 independent of ε and k, such that
uLεkt≥−c2−c2√texp(−c1x2t) for|x|<ρ2,0<t≤ρ24, |
where 0<ρ<X. Take C1≥r such that
C1≥c2+c2√texp(−c1x2t) on {|x|=ρ2,0<t≤ρ24}∪{|x|<ρ2,t=ρ24}. |
It follows that on {x≤−ρ2,t=0}∪{|x|=ρ2,0<t≤ρ24}∪{|x|<ρ2,t=ρ24}∪{ρ2≤x≤X,t=0},
uLεkt≥−C1. | (3.6) |
When k=0, uε0(Xε,t)=1 and we have uε0t(Xε,t)=0 on x=Xε for t>0.
By further approximating the initial data with smooth functions if necessary, we conclude by (3.5) and maximum principle that
uLε0t≤0 in QLε. |
We conclude by (3.6) and minimum principle that
uLε0t≥−C1 in QLε∖¯Qρ, |
where Qρ=(−ρ/2,ρ/2)×(0,ρ2/4).
We assume that −C1≤uLεkt≤0 in QLε∖¯Qρ holds for k≥1. Since uHεkt(X,t)=uLεkt(X,t) for t>0 and (3.4), we conclude by extremum principle
−C1≤uHεkt≤0 in QH. |
From uLε(k+1)t(Xε,t)=uHεkt(Xε,t) and (3.5), (3.6), applying the extremum principle gives
−C1≤uLε(k+1)t≤0 in QLε∖¯Qρ. |
Thus, by induction, we derive that −C1≤uLεkt≤0 in QLε∖¯Qρ and −C1≤uHεkt≤0 in QH for any k≥0 and C1 is independent of ε and k. The lemma's results can be obtained by taking limits with k.
Lemma 3.3.
|∂uLε∂x|≤C2 in QLε, |∂uHε∂x|≤C3 in QH. | (3.7) |
Proof. We estimate uLεx as an example and the same process works for uHεx.
We fixed ε and first deal with the uLεx(Xε,t). Let K1(ρ<K1<X) be a constant and η=X−K1. Define wLε=uLε−Xε−xXε−K1uLε(K1,t)−x−K1Xε−K1uLε(Xε,t). Thus, wLε(K1,t)=wLε(Xε,t)=0 for t>0 and wLε(x,t)=0 for K1≤x≤Xε. In QLεK1={K1<x<Xε,t>0},
LL0wLε=−ruLε−Xε−xXε−K1uLεt(K1,t)−x−K1Xε−K1uLεt(Xε,t)+(r−12σ2L)uLε(Xε,t)−uLε(K1,t)Xε−K1, |
where Li0=∂∂t−12σi2∂2∂x2−(r−12σi2)∂∂x. Actually, LL0wLε can be bounded by a number G independent of ε,
supQLεK1|LL0wLε|≤rsupQLεK1|uLε|+supQLεK1|uLεt|+2r+σ2LηsupQLεK1|uLε|≤r+C1+2r+σ2Lη≜G. |
In the case σ2L≠2r, we introduce the function
zLε(x,t)=2Cσ2L−2r(1−exp((1−2rσ2L)(x−Xε)))+2Gσ2L−2r(x−Xε), |
where C is a constant to be determined later. Obviously, LL0zLε=G≥LL0wLε in QLεK1 and zLε(Xε,t)=0 for t>0. To make
zLεx=−2Cσ2Lexp((1−2rσ2L)(x−Xε))+2Gσ2L−2r≤0 |
hold for K1<x<Xε,t>0, we choose C=σ2LGσ2L−2rexp((1−2rσ2L)(η+ε)). Thus, on the parabolic boundary of QLεK1 we clearly have zLε≥±wLε. It follows by comparison principle that
zLε≥±wLε in QLεK1. |
Since zLε(Xε,t)=±wLε(Xε,t)=0,
±(wLε(x,t)−wLε(Xε,t))Xε−x≤zLε(x,t)−zLε(Xε,t)Xε−x |
for x<Xε. Letting x→Xε, we have
|wLεx(Xε,t)|≤−zLεx(Xε,t)=−2Gσ2L−2r(1−exp((1−2rσ2L)(η+ε))). |
Then, by uLεx(Xε,t)=wLεx(Xε,t)+[uLε(Xε,t)−uLε(K1,t)]/(Xε−K1) there exists a constant C2>1 independent of ε such that
|uLεx(Xε,t)|≤−2Gσ2L−2r(1−exp((1−2rσ2L)(η+1)))+2/η≤C2, |
when ε<1.
In the case σ2L=2r, we can introduce the function
zLε(x,t)=−Gσ2L(x−Xε)2−2Gσ2L(η+ε)(x−Xε), |
then by a similar analysis as above, we can conclude that there exists a number C2>1 independent of ε such that
|uLεx(Xε,t)|≤2Gσ2L(η+1)+2/η≤C2, |
when ε<1.
It is known that uLεx(x,0)=ex for x<0 and uLεx(x,0)=0 for 0<x<Xε. Thus it follows by maximum principle that |uLεx(x,t)|≤C2 in QLε when ε<1.
Lemma 3.4.
|∂2uLε∂x2|≤C4 in QLε∖¯Qρ, |∂2uHε∂x2|≤C5 in QH. | (3.8) |
Proof. The corollary of Lemmas 3.1–3.3.
In this section, we establish the asymptotic relationship between LL's model and LZ's model, when Xε approaches X. A key lemma is proved to show |uLεx−uHεx|→0 on x=X along ε→0. Then, by compact embedding theorem, we deduce that there exists a subsequence uεj converging a function u which is examined as a solution of the single threshold problem (2.2). By the uniqueness of the solution, we obtain v≡u and uε→v uniformly as ε→0.
Lemma 4.1. As ε→0,
|∂uLε∂x(X−,t)−∂uHε∂x(X+,t)|→0 | (4.1) |
uniformly for 0≤t≤T.
Proof. Let
hε(t)=uLε(X+ε,t)−uLε(X,t)ε=uHε(X+ε,t)−uHε(X,t)ε, |
for 0≤t≤T. By the mean value theorem, there is μ1(t)∈[0,ε] such that hε(t)=uLεx(X+μ1(t),t), then,
|uLεx(X+,t)−hε(t)|=|uLεx(X,t)−uLεx(X+μ1(t),t)|=|uLεxx(X+μ2(t),t)|μ1(t)≤εsupQLε∖¯Qρ|uLεxx|, |
where 0≤μ2(t)≤μ1(t). The second equal sign holds by the mean value theorem. Similarly, we can derive
|uHεx(X+,t)−hε(t)|≤εsupQH|uHεxx|. |
Considering the continuity of uLεx across x=X, we have for 0≤t≤T,
|uLεx(X−,t)−uHεx(X+,t)|=|uLεx(X+,t)−uHεx(X+,t)|=|uLεx(X+,t)−hε(t)+hε(t)−uHεx(X+,t)|≤ε(C4+C5). |
As C4,C5 are independent of the small parameter ε, the result is seen by letting ε→0.
Theorem 4.1. As ε→0, uε(x,t) tends to v(x,t) uniformly in (−∞,∞)×[0,T].
Proof. Treat uLε|x≤X as uLε restricted on (−∞,X]×[0,T]. From Lemmas 3.1–3.4, uLε|x≤X is bounded in W2,1∞((−∞,X)×[0,T]∖¯Qρ). By the compact embedding theorem, there exists uL and a subsequence εj of ε such that, as εj→0,
uLεj|x≤X→uL in C1+α,1+α2(([−A,X]×[0,T])∖Qρ), 0<α<1, | (4.2) |
for any A>1 and ρ<X. Similarly, uHε is bounded in W2,1∞((X,∞)×[0,T]) and there exists uH such that
uHεj→uH in C1+α,1+α2([X,A]×[0,T]), | (4.3) |
along a subsequence of εj if necessary.
Thus, it is clear that
uLεjx(X−,t)→uLx(X−,t), uHεjx(X+,t)→uHx(X+,t), | (4.4) |
uniformly for 0≤t≤T. By Lemma 4.1, we conclude that
uLx(X−,t)=uHx(X+,t). | (4.5) |
It then can be verified that u=(uL,uH) is a solution of the problem (2.2). By the uniqueness of the solution to this problem, we have v≡u. This implies that any convergent subsequence of uLε|x≤X or uHε has the same limit and uLε|x≤X or uHε converges as ε→0.
It follows that as ε→0,
uLε(X−,t)→vL(X−,t), uHε(X+,t)→vH(X+,t), | (4.6) |
uniformly for 0≤t≤T. Since uLε(x,0)|x≤X=vL(x,0) and uHε(x,0)=vH(x,0), implying the maximum norm estimation in their regions, respectively, gives that
uLε|x≤X→vL uniformly in (−∞,X]×[0,T], | (4.7) |
uHε→vH uniformly in [X,∞)×[0,T], | (4.8) |
as ε→0.
By PDE techniques, we showed an asymptotic relationship between two kinds of structural models for credit migration problems with fixed boundaries. When the downgrade threshold was locked and the upgrade threshold approached to it, the solution of the model with a pair of asymmetric thresholds converged to that of the single threshold model in which the downgrade threshold serves as a unique migration threshold. Symmetrically, by fixing the upgrade threshold and moving the downgrade threshold, a similar conclusion will be obtained. As far as we know, it was the first time that the relationship between the single threshold and a pair of asymmetric thresholds was studied in credit migration problems. This may contribute to generalizing existing research results by using a single threshold model to approximate models with different upgrade and downgrade thresholds.
The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.12071349).
All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.
[1] |
Aggarwal R, Rivoli P (1990) Fads in the initial public offering market? Financ Manage 19: 45–57. https://doi.org/10.2307/3665609 doi: 10.2307/3665609
![]() |
[2] |
Anderloni L, Tanda A (2017) Green energy companies: Stock performance and IPO returns. Res Int Bus Financ 39: 546–552. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2016.09.016 doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2016.09.016
![]() |
[3] | Anderloni L, Tanda A (2015) The performance of listed European innovative firms, In: Beccalli, E. Poli, F. (Eds.), Lending Investments and the Financial Crisis, Palgrave Macmillian, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137531018_7 |
[4] |
Belghitar Y, Clark E, Deshmukh N (2014) Does it pay to be ethical? Evidence from the FTSE4Good. J Bank Financ 47: 54–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.06.027 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.06.027
![]() |
[5] |
Beatty R, Ritter JR (1986) Investment Banking Reputation and the Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings. J Financ Econ 15: 213–232. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(86)90055-3 doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(86)90055-3
![]() |
[6] |
Benveniste L, Spindt P (1989) How investment bankers determine the offer price and allocation of new issues. J Financ Econ 24: 343–361. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(89)90051-2 doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(89)90051-2
![]() |
[7] |
Berk A, Peterle P (2015) Initial and long-run IPO returns in Central and Eastern Europe. Emerg Mark Financ Tr 51: 42–60. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496X.2015.1080555 doi: 10.1080/1540496X.2015.1080555
![]() |
[8] |
Cai X, Liu GS, Mase B (2008) The long-run performance of initial public offerings and its determinants: The case of China. Rev Quant Financ Account 30: 419–432. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-007-0064-5 doi: 10.1007/s11156-007-0064-5
![]() |
[9] |
Gompers PA, Lerner J (2003) The really long-run performance of initial public offerings: The pre-NASDAQ evidence. J Financ 58: 1355–1392. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00570 doi: 10.1111/1540-6261.00570
![]() |
[10] | Ibbotson R, Ritter JR (1995) Initial public offerings, In: Jarrow, R. (ed.), Handbook in OR & MS, 993–1016. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0927-0507(05)80074-X |
[11] |
Ji Q, Zhang D (2019) China's crude oil future: Introduction and some stylized facts. Financ Res Lett 24: 151–162. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2018.06.005 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2018.06.005
![]() |
[12] |
Que J, Zhang X (2019) Pre-IPO growth, venture capital, and the long-run performance of IPOs. Econ Model 81: 205–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2019.04.005 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.04.005
![]() |
[13] |
Loughran T, Ritter JR (1995) The new issues puzzle. J Financ 50: 23–51. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05166.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05166.x
![]() |
[14] |
Lowry M, Officer MS, Schwert GW (2010) The variability of IPO initial returns. J Financ 65: 425–465. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01540.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01540.x
![]() |
[15] |
Lyon JD, Barber BM, Tsai CL (1999) Improved methods for tests of long-run abnormal stock returns. J Financ 54: 165–201. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00101 doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00101
![]() |
[16] |
Miller EM (1977) Risk, uncertainty and divergence of opinion. J Financ 32: 1151–1168. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1977.tb03317.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1977.tb03317.x
![]() |
[17] |
Mir KA, Purohit P, Mehmood S (2017) Sectoral assessment of greenhouse gas emissions in Pakistan. Environ Sci Pollut R 24: 27345–27355. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-017-0354-y doi: 10.1007/s11356-017-0354-y
![]() |
[18] | Mumtaz MZ, Smith N (2022) The Blueness Index, Investment Choice, and Portfolio Allocation, ln: Blue Economy and Blue Finance, Asian Development Bank Institute (ADBI), Japan. |
[19] | Mumtaz MZ, Smith ZA (2019) Green finance for sustainable development in Pakistan. Islamabad Policy Res Institute (IPRI) J 18: 78–110. |
[20] | Mumtaz MZ, Smith ZA (2017) Short and intermediate-term price performance of unseasoned issues. Economia Aplicada 21: 549–579. |
[21] |
Mumtaz MZ, Smith ZA, Ahmad AM (2016a) An examination of short-run performance of IPOs using Extreme Bounds Analysis. Estudios de Economia 43: 71–95. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-52862016000100004 doi: 10.4067/S0718-52862016000100004
![]() |
[22] |
Mumtaz MZ, Smith ZA, Ahmed AM (2016b) The aftermarket performance of initial public offerings in Pakistan. Lahore J Econ 21: 23–68. https://doi.org/10.35536/lje.2016.v21.i1.a2 doi: 10.35536/lje.2016.v21.i1.a2
![]() |
[23] |
Ritter JR (1991) The long-run performance of initial public offerings. J Financ 46: 3–27. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb03743.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb03743.x
![]() |
[24] |
Ritter JR (1984) Signaling and the valuation of unseasoned new issues: A comment. J Financ 39: 1231–1237. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03907.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03907.x
![]() |
[25] |
Rock K (1986) Why new issues are underpriced. J Financ Econ 57: 187–212. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(86)90054-1 doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(86)90054-1
![]() |
[26] |
Taghizadeh-Hesary F, Yoshino N (2020) Sustainable solutions for green financing and investment in renewable energy projects. Energies 13: 1–19. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13040788 doi: 10.3390/en13040788
![]() |
[27] |
Taghizadeh-Hesary F, Yoshino N (2019) The way to induce private participation in green finance and investment. Financ Res Lett 31: 98–103. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.016 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.016
![]() |
[28] | Wahid A, Mumtaz MZ, Mantell E (2020) Short-run pricing performance of local and dual class IPOs in alternative investment market. Romanian J Econ Forecast 23: 57–74. |
[29] | Yoshino N, Taghizadeh-Hesary F, Otuka M (2020) Optimal Portfolio Selection for Investment in ESG goal, Facing Issues in ESG Investment, edited by N. Nemoto, ADBI book series (forthcoming). |
[30] |
Yoshino N, Taghizadeh-Hesary F, Nakahigashi M (2019) Modelling the social funding and spill-over tax for addressing the green energy financing gap. Econ Model 77: 34–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.11.018 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2018.11.018
![]() |