Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article Special Issues

Dynamics of a nonlinear differential advertising model with single parameter sales promotion strategy

  • Advertising and sales promotion are two important specific marketing communications tools. In this paper, nonlinear differential equation and single parameter sales promotion strategy are introduced into an advertising model and investigated quantitatively. The existence and stability of period-nT (n = 1, 2, 4, 8) solutions are investigated. Interestingly, both period doubling bifurcation and inverse flip bifurcation occur at different parameter values in the same advertising model. The results show that the system enters into chaos from stable state through flip bifurcation and enters into stable state from chaos through inverse flip bifurcation. An effective control strategy, which suppresses flip bifurcation and promotes inverse flip bifurcation, is proposed to eliminate chaos. These results have some significant theoretical and practical value in related markets.

    Citation: Junhai Ma, Hui Jiang. Dynamics of a nonlinear differential advertising model with single parameter sales promotion strategy[J]. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(4): 1142-1157. doi: 10.3934/era.2022061

    Related Papers:

    [1] Yuan Tian, Yang Liu, Kaibiao Sun . Complex dynamics of a predator-prey fishery model: The impact of the Allee effect and bilateral intervention. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(11): 6379-6404. doi: 10.3934/era.2024297
    [2] Yichao Shao, Hengguo Yu, Chenglei Jin, Jingzhe Fang, Min Zhao . Dynamics analysis of a predator-prey model with Allee effect and harvesting effort. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(10): 5682-5716. doi: 10.3934/era.2024263
    [3] Jiarui Chen, Aimin Tang, Guanfeng Zhou, Ling Lin, Guirong Jiang . Walking dynamics for an ascending stair biped robot with telescopic legs and impulse thrust. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(11): 4108-4135. doi: 10.3934/era.2022208
    [4] Weiyu Li, Hongyan Wang . Dynamics of a three-molecule autocatalytic Schnakenberg model with cross-diffusion: Turing patterns of spatially homogeneous Hopf bifurcating periodic solutions. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(7): 4139-4154. doi: 10.3934/era.2023211
    [5] Yuan Tian, Hua Guo, Wenyu Shen, Xinrui Yan, Jie Zheng, Kaibiao Sun . Dynamic analysis and validation of a prey-predator model based on fish harvesting and discontinuous prey refuge effect in uncertain environments. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(2): 973-994. doi: 10.3934/era.2025044
    [6] Tian Hou, Yi Wang, Xizhuang Xie . Instability and bifurcation of a cooperative system with periodic coefficients. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(5): 3069-3079. doi: 10.3934/era.2021026
    [7] Yujia Xiang, Yuqi Jiao, Xin Wang, Ruizhi Yang . Dynamics of a delayed diffusive predator-prey model with Allee effect and nonlocal competition in prey and hunting cooperation in predator. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(4): 2120-2138. doi: 10.3934/era.2023109
    [8] Fengrong Zhang, Ruining Chen . Spatiotemporal patterns of a delayed diffusive prey-predator model with prey-taxis. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(7): 4723-4740. doi: 10.3934/era.2024215
    [9] Wenxin Zhang, Lijun Pei . Bifurcation and chaos in N-type and S-type muscular blood vessel models. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(3): 1285-1305. doi: 10.3934/era.2025057
    [10] Xianyi Li, Xingming Shao . Flip bifurcation and Neimark-Sacker bifurcation in a discrete predator-prey model with Michaelis-Menten functional response. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(1): 37-57. doi: 10.3934/era.2023003
  • Advertising and sales promotion are two important specific marketing communications tools. In this paper, nonlinear differential equation and single parameter sales promotion strategy are introduced into an advertising model and investigated quantitatively. The existence and stability of period-nT (n = 1, 2, 4, 8) solutions are investigated. Interestingly, both period doubling bifurcation and inverse flip bifurcation occur at different parameter values in the same advertising model. The results show that the system enters into chaos from stable state through flip bifurcation and enters into stable state from chaos through inverse flip bifurcation. An effective control strategy, which suppresses flip bifurcation and promotes inverse flip bifurcation, is proposed to eliminate chaos. These results have some significant theoretical and practical value in related markets.



    For firms, advertising is a form of promoting goods or providing services and disseminating goods or service information to consumers or users through advertising media, such as newspaper, magazines, television commercial, radio advertisement, outdoor advertising, direct mail, websites, text messages, etc. [1]. As one of the indispensable means in enterprise competitive strategy, advertising's role in developing market, competing for share and creating economic benefits can not be ignored and underestimated. In advertising research, qualitative analysis and quantitative analysis are two main research methods [2]. Qualitative insights can aid empirical analysis in promising new directions, and the gap between the qualitative specialists and the quantitative gurus really needs to be bridged for the most beneficial research to be developed.

    Advertising research has been growing and has been enriched in recent decades. Zhao and Ma [3] discussed dynamics and implications on a cooperative advertising model. By using the theory of nonlinear dynamic system, the authors found four possible Nash equilibrium points and provide the conditions for their existence, analyzed the impacts of key parameters on the stability of the positive Nash equilibrium point and prove that two kinds of bifurcation may occur when this positive Nash equilibrium point becomes unstable. A differential game theory approach is suggested to seek equilibrium trajectories of price and advertising over time. In paper [4], based on chance theory, the optimal control for uncertain stochastic dynamic systems was considered and the principle of optimality is presented by drawing on the dynamic programming method. As an application, an advertising problem is analyzed, the corresponding optimal pricing policies and advertising strategies are provided. Chenavaz, Feichtinger and Hartl et al. [5] investigated the interplay between price, advertising, and quality in an optimal control model. The obtained results generalize the condition of Dorfman-Steiner in a dynamic context.

    There are also many literatures on the models and methods of advertising research, such as artificial neural network approach [6], tourism advertising effects model [7], advertising capital model with analytical and numerical studies [8], etc.

    In the past few decades, the dynamic advertising literature contains a large number of continuous time dynamic optimization models and differential game models in different mathematical forms for diverse advertising problems. Many classical models and their extensions are used to investigate advertising problems, such as Nerlove-Arrow model [9], Vidale-Wolfe model[10], and so on. Most of these continuous time differential game models are described by linear differential equations. Theoretical analysis is easy in a linear differential advertising model, which is an ideal description of advertising in reality.

    As a pulse control strategy [11], sales promotion is a promotional mix variable primarily used to bolster sales in the short run. Sales promotion can be targeted either at the consumer (consumer sales promotion), the distribution channel members (trade promotion), or the sales staff (sales force promotion). Typical examples of consumer sales promotion tools include contests and sweepstakes, branded give-away merchandise, bonus-size packaging, limited-time discounts, rebates, coupons, free trials, demonstrations, and point-accumulation systems.

    Because it can increase the sales of products in a short time, sales promotion has been valued and applied by the company's managers. In recent years, a lot of theoretical research results on sales promotion have been obtained. Previous studies mainly used the methods of data-analysis and quality analysis to discuss the role of sales promotion. For example, from the perspective of empirical research, paper [12] investigated whether various types of sales promotions together with hedonic shopping motivation (value shopping) and positive affect drive impulse buying, and further explored the moderation impact of trait constructs viz deal proneness and impulsive buying tendency in impulse buying. By using three years of super-market scanner data and sales promotions for pound cake, McColl et al. [13] estimated cannibalization effects for two common price reductions, across large, medium and small supermarkets. Almendros [14] assessed which type of online promotional incentive is the most effective at achieving purchase intention for airline tickets, depending on the user's level of Internet experience (characterized as novice or expert user).

    At present, there are few quantitative research results on sales promotion. A linear advertising competition model with sales promotion was constructed and investigated in paper [15]. It is difficult for this sales promotion strategy, which contains two parameters, to ensure the change in sales volume is positive. As mentioned above, most of advertising models are described by linear differential equations. To investigate the complex change process in advertising, nonlinear differential equations should be introduced into advertising models. Motivated by these facts, a nonlinear differential equation and single parameter sales promotion strategy are introduced into an advertising model in this study. This research focuses on the complex dynamics of this model and the effect of sales promotion on sales level and profit.

    The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we build an advertising model by using nonlinear differential equation and single parameter sales promotion strategy. The existence and stability of periodic solutions, and bifurcation of periodic solutions are investigated in Section 3. In Section 4, control measures are taken to eliminate chaos by suppressing flip bifurcation and promoting inverse flip bifurcation. Finally, some conclusions are drawn in section 5.

    Vidale and Wolfe [10] built the following model to investigate the impact of advertising on sales of firm's product.

    ˙S(t)=rMu(t)(MS(t))λS(t), (1)

    where S(t) is sales level at time t, M is the size of the potential market or saturation level, u(t) is advertising expenditure at time t, r is response rate to advertising, λ is decay constant.

    Bass [16] developed a growth model for the timing of initial purchase of new products, which is given by the following nonlinear differential equation.

    ˙S(t)=(p+qS(t))(MS(t)),(1)

    where S(t) is the sales of one new product, p and q are positive parameters, referred to as innovation and imitation parameter, respectively, and M is the fixed market potential of the product.

    The Vidale and Wolfe model (1), which is built by using linear differential equations, simplifies the change of product sales. The influence of advertising on sales is complex, and we consider using nonlinear equation to describe the change of sales. In view of nonlinear differential equation (1*), the advertising effect rMu(t)(MS(t)) is replaced by rMu(t)S(t)(MS(t)) in (1).

    In some cases, it is difficult to estimate the size of the potential market or saturation level M. For example, the size of the potential market or saturation level will change with the change of consumer preferences and the development of emerging industries. The size of the potential market or saturation level is not considered in this paper, and MS(t) is replaced by S(t) in (1). We also assume that the firm advertises at a constant level, that is u(t)=U. So the advertising effect rMu(t)S(t)(MS(t)) is replaced by rUS(t)S(t)=γS2(t) in (1), where γ=rU.

    In order to try to discuss the complex process of product sales, the following nonlinear differential equation is used in this paper.

    dS(t)dt=ρS(t)+γS2(t), (2)

    where S(t) is sales level at time t, ρ is decay constant, and γ is response rate to advertising.

    System (2) can be rewritten as

    dS(t)dt=ρS(t)(1S(t)ργ).

    It's seen that dS(t)dt<0 for S(t)<ργ while dS(t)dt>0 for S(t)>ργ. ργ is considered as the promotion threshold. When the sales level S(t) is greater than ργ, the sales level will continue to increase and no promotion strategy is considered. In the case of S(t)<ργ, the sales level decreases with the increase of time t. So measures are discussed to improve sales of products under the condition S(t)<ργ in this paper.

    In view of the fact sales promotion is an incentive provided to consumers to motivate them to buy immediately, sales promotion strategy is applied to improve sales here. In paper [15], the impulsive promotion effect is ΔS(t)=S(t+)S(t)=(bcS(t))S(t), which contains two parameters b, c, and cannot guarantee that value of ΔS(t) is always greater than 0. To avoid these shortcomings, we consider the following single parameter sales promotion strategy.

    ΔS(t)=S(t+)S(t)=αS(t),   t=nT, (3)

    where α is a promotion coefficient and a>0, n=1, 2, , S(t+)=limτ0+S(t+τ). The measures to promote sales are supposed to be taken at moments t=nT and the sales level S(t) turns from S(nT) to S(nT+), where S(nT+)=S(nT)+αS(nT) and αS(nT) is the increment of sales. It follows from (3) that the increment ΔS(t)>0 for S(t)>0 and a>0, and hence the single-parameter promotion strategy (3) can guarantee that the increment ΔS(t) is always greater than 0.

    When the product sales level of a firm is low, the firm will increase the promotion. The sales level is S1 and the increment is ΔS(t1) at time t=t1 while the sales level is S2 and the increment is ΔS(t2) at time t=t2, where S1=S(t1) and S2=S(t2). If the sales level S2 is less than S1, the firm will increase the promotion at time t=t2 to make the increment ΔS(t2) larger than the increment ΔS(t1), which can be realized through the single parameter sales promotion strategy (3). Figure 1(a) provides a schematic illustration of this sales promotion strategy. It's seen that αS2>αS1 for S2<S1.

    Figure 1.  For system (4), (a) sketch of sales promotion strategy, (b) the solution from the initial point (0, S(0)).

    Now build the following nonlinear advertising model with single parameter sales promotion strategy.

    {˙S=ρS(t)(1S(t)ργ),  tnT,S(t+)=S(t)+αS(t),       t=nT.    (4)

    Figure 1(b) shows one solution to (4). The trajectory originating from the initial point (0, S(0)) reaches the point (T,S(T)) at t=T, next jumps to the point (T, S(T+)) due to the effect of sales promotion, and so on. Hence,

    S(t)=ρS(0)γS(0)(γS(0)ρ)exp(ρt),  0tT,
    S(T+)=S(T)+αS(T),
    S(t)=ρS(T+)γS(T+)(γS(T+)ρ)exp(ρ(tT)),  T<t2T.

    Although product sales will change continuously, the company does not want this change to be disorderly. Therefore, we discuss periodic change of firm's product sales under sales promotion strategy in this section.

    Suppose the solution of (4) arrives at the point (kT, Sk) at moment t=kT, then jumps to point (kT, S+k) due to the effect of sales promotion, reaches the point ((k+1)T, Sk+1) at moment t=(k+1)T, where Sk=S(kT), S+k=S(kT+)=Sk+αSk, Sk+1=S((k+1)T). It follows from (4) that

    S((k+1)T)=ρS(kT+)γS(kT+)(γS(kT+)ρ)exp(ρT),

    and a discrete map

    Sk+1=ρ(Sk+αSk)γ(Sk+αSk)(γ(Sk+αSk)ρ)exp(ρT),

    namely,

    Sk+1=ρ(Sk+αSk)(1exp(ρT))γ(Sk+αSk)+ρexp(ρT). (5)

    If S(kT)=S((k+1)T), then sales level S(t) will change periodically. For this to hold, there must be a fixed point S0 in discrete map (5), that is,

    S0=ρ(S0+αS0)(1exp(ρT))γ(S0+αS0)+ρexp(ρT).

    To avoid the tedious calculation, we set γ=0.1 and

    T=1ρln(1+ργ). (6)

    It follows that (1exp(ρT))γ=ρ. Hence, the discrete map (5) can be written as

    Sk+1=Sk+αSk1+10ρ(Sk+αSk)=f(α, Sk). (7)

    The fixed point S0 of map (7) is the solution of the following equation.

    S=S+αS1+10ρ(S+αS),

    that is

    S310ρS2+aS+a=0. (8)

    Consider function h(S)=S310ρS2+aS+a. For S(, 0), h(S)=3S220ρS+a>0. Since h(0)=α>0 and limSh(S)=, Eq (8) has a unique root for S(, 0).

    In Eq (8), the coefficients are a=1, b=10ρ, c=α, d=α. Now set

    A=b23ac=100ρ23α, B=bc9ad=10ρα9α, C=c23bd=α2+30ρα.

    The discriminant is

    Δ=B24AC=α(12α2+(300ρ2+540ρ+81)α12000ρ3).

    It follows from

    Δ=B24AC=α(12α2+(300ρ2+540ρ+81)α12000ρ3)=0,

    that α1=0,

    α2=100ρ2180ρ27(100ρ2180ρ27)2+64000ρ38<0,

    and

    α3=100ρ2180ρ27+(100ρ2180ρ27)2+64000ρ38>0. (9)

    Hence Δ=B24AC<0 for 0<α<α3 and Δ=B24AC>0 for α>α3, where α3 is shown in (9).

    For α>α3, the discriminant Δ=B24AC>0 and Eq (8) has one real root and two imaginary roots. Together with the fact that Eq (8) has a unique root for S(, 0), we obtain Eq (8) has no positive real roots. So map (7) has no positive real fixed points for α>α3, and system (4) has no period-T solutions. The results is given as follows.

    Proposition 3.1. System (4) has no period-T solutions for α>α3, where α3 is shown in (9).

    For 0<α<α3, the discriminant Δ=B24AC<0 and Eq (8) has the following three different real roots.

    S01=10ρ+100ρ23α(cos(θ3)+3sin(θ3))3, (10)
    S02=10ρ+100ρ23α(cos(θ3)3sin(θ3))3, (11)
    S03=10ρ2100ρ23αcos(θ3)3,

    where θ=arccos(2000ρ3+90ρ2α+27α2(100ρ23α)3).

    The root S03 is negative while S01 and S02 are positive. Map (7) has two positive real fixed points S01 and S02 for 0<α<α3, and system (4) has the following two period-T solutions, which correspond to fixed points S01 and S02.

    S1(t)=ρ(S02+αS02)γ(S02+αS02)(γ(S02+αS02)ρ)exp(ρ(tkT)),  kT<t(k+1)T, (12)
    S2(t)=ρ(S03+αS03)γ(S03+αS03)(γ(S03+αS03)ρ)exp(ρ(tkT)),  kT<t(k+1)T, (13)

    where γ=0.1 and T=1ρln(1+10ρ).

    The eigenvalue of the fixed point S0i is

    λi=f(α, S0i)S0i=(1αS20i)(1+10ρ(S0i+αS0i))(S0i+αS0i)((1αS20i))(1+10ρ(S0i+αS0i))2
    =1+10ρS20i2αS0i3αS20i+α, i=1,2. (14)

    If the initial sales values are S01+αS01 and S02+αS02, the sales level S(t) changes periodically according to (12) and (13). The eigenvalue λi of the fixed point S0i is used to judge the stability of the solution Si(t). The following results are obtained.

    Proposition 3.2. For 0<α<α3, system (4) has two period-T solutions Si(t)(i=1,2), which are shown in (12) and (13). The period-T solution Si(t) is stable for |λi|<1 and unstable for |λi|>1, where λi is shown in (14).

    Set ρ=1.1, one can obtain α325.7298 from (9). Map (7) has two fixed points, which are shown in Figure 2(a), for α(0, 25.7298) and hence system (4) has two periodic solutions. The eigenvalues of these two fixed points S0i(i=1,2) are shown in Figure 2(b). For α(0, 25.7298), λ1>1 and the fixed point S01 is unstable, and hence the corresponding periodic solution S1(t) is unstable. Since |λ2|<1 for α(0, 0.6081)(21.3922, 25.7298) and |λ2|>1 for α(0.6081, 21.3922), the corresponding periodic solution S2(t) of system (4) with ρ=1.1 is unstable for α(0, 0.6081)(21.3922, 25.7298) and unstable for α(0.6081, 21.3922).

    Figure 2.  For system (4) with ρ=1.1, (a) two fixed points S01 and S02, (b) the eigenvalues of fixed points S01 and S02.

    Now set α=0.6, it follows from (10) and (11) that S0110.9401, and S020.2660. Note that S01+αS01=10.9949 and S02+αS02=2.5216, there exist the following two periodic solutions in system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=0.6.

    S1(t)=1110.994910.9949(10.994911)exp(1.1(tkT)),  kT<t(k+1)T,
    S2(t)=112.52162.5216(2.521611)exp(1.1(tkT)),  kT<t(k+1)T,

    where T=1ρln(1+10ρ)=2.2590. These two periodic solutions and their stability are shown in Figure 3. With time increasing, the solution S(t) with the initial point (0, 10.9940) moves away from the periodic solution S1(t) and the solution S(t) with the initial point (0, 8.5) tends to the periodic solution S2(t). So the periodic solution S1(t) is unstable and S2(t) is stable for system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=0.6.

    Figure 3.  For system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=0.6, (a) the periodic solution S1(t) and the solution S(t) with the initial point (0, 10.9940), (b) the periodic solution S2(t) and the solution S(t) with the initial point (0, 8.5).

    It's seen from Figure 2(b) that the eigenvalue λ2 of the fixed point S02 is equal to 1 at α=0.6081 and α=21.3922 for ρ=1.1. An eigenvalue with 1 is associated with a flip bifurcation (or flip bifurcation). So α=0.6081 and α=21.3922 are candidates for flip bifurcation, and a stable period2T solution may occur in the system. Now use the following lemma [17] to discuss the stability and direction of bifurcation of period2T solutions in the case of α=0.6081.

    Lemma 3.1. Let fμ: RR be a one-parameter family of map such that fμ0 has a fixed point x0 with eigenvalue 1. Assume the following conditions:

    (C1) (fμ2fx2+22fxμ)0 at (x0, μ0);

    (C2) g(x, μ)=12(2fx2)2+13(3fx3)0 at (x0, μ0).

    Then, there is a smooth curve of fixed points of fμ passing through (x0, μ0), the stability of which changes at (x0, μ0). There is also a smooth curve γ passing through (x0, μ0) so that γ(x0, μ0) is a union of hyperbolic period-2 orbits.

    It follows from (11) and Figure 4(a) that S02=0.2681 for α=0.6081. One can calculate that (f(α, Sk)α2f(α, Sk)S2k+22f(α, Sk)Skα)0 at (S02, α)=(0.2681, 0.6081). In (C2) the sign of g(x0, μ0) determines the stability and the direction of bifurcation of the orbits of period-2. If g(x0, μ0) is positive, the orbits are stable; if g(x0, μ0) is negative they are unstable. In our case,

    2f(α, Sk)S2k=2(1+10ρ)αS3k+(1αS2k)2(1+10ρ(Sk+αSk))3,
    3f(α, Sk)S3k=2(1+10ρ)(33αS2k)(αS3k+(1αS2k)2)(3αS4k+4αS3k4α2S5k)(1+10ρSkαSk)(1+10ρ(Sk+αSk))4,
    Figure 4.  For system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α(0, 5), (a) the fixed point S02 and its eigenvalue λ2, (b) the function g(Sk, α).

    and g(Sk, α)=12(2f(α, Sk)S2k)2+133f(α, Sk)S3k=4.2326>0 at (S02, α)=(0.2681, 0.6081).

    Hence a flip bifurcation occurs at α=0.6081 and system (4) has a stable period2T solution for α(0.6081, 0.6081+ϵ), where ϵ>0.

    To get the expression of the period-2T solution S3(t), consider the following quadratic iterative map of (7).

    Sk+1=Sk+αSk1+10ρ(Sk+αSk)+αSk+αSk1+10ρ(Sk+αSk)1+10ρ(Sk+αSk1+10ρ(Sk+αSk)+αSk+αSk1+10ρ(Sk+αSk))=f2(α, Sk). (15)

    Map (15) has 6 fixed points S0ij, i=1,2,3, j=1,2, which meet conditions f(α, S0i1)=S0i2 and f(α, S0i2)=S0i1. Similar to the case of map (7), two fixed points, which marked as S021 and S022 here, are stable for α(0.6081, 0.6081+ϵ). Hence system (4) has the following stable period-2T solution.

    S3(t)={ρ(S021+αS021)γ(S021+αS021)(γ(S021+αS021)ρ)exp(ρ(tkT)),     kT<t(k+1)T,ρ(S022+αS022)γ(S022+αS022)(γ(S022+αS022)ρ)exp(ρ(t(k+1)T)),  (k+1)T<t(k+2)T.    (16)

    Set α=4, the solution from the initial points (0, 9.1) is shown in Figure 5(a), which tends to a stable period-2T solution S3(t). Figure 5(b) shows bifurcation of periodic solutions of system (4) with ρ=1.1, α(0, 25.7298), and the initial points (0, 10). A period-T solution S2(t) is stable for α(0, 0.6081) and a flip bifurcation occurs at α=0.6081. A period-2T solution S3(t) is bifurcated from the the period-T solution S2(t) through flip bifurcation at α=0.6081. The period-2T solution S3(t) solution is stable for α(0.6081, 4.8096) in system (4) with ρ=1.1.

    Figure 5.  For system (4) with ρ=1.1, (a) the solution from the initial points (0, 9.1) for α=4, (b) bifurcation diagram for α(0, 25.7298).

    It's also seen from Figure 5(b) that an inverse flip bifurcation occurs at α=21.392 in system (4) with ρ=1.1. There exists a stable period-2T solution for α(17.6824, 21.3922). A stable period-T solution, which bifurcates from the stable period-2T solution through inverse flip bifurcation, is stable for α(21.3922, 25.7298).

    Now we change the value of ρ to discuss periodic solutions and their bifurcation in system (4). Set ρ=0.6, 0.8, 1.26 in system (4). The eigenvalues of the fixed point S02 are shown in Figure 6(a). In the case of ρ=0.6,α3=6.8380 and 0<λ2<1 for α(0, 6.8380), so the fixed point S02 is stable for α(0, 6.8380) (see Figure 6(b)) and hence system (4) has only one stable period-T solution for ρ=0.6.

    Figure 6.  For system (4), (a) eigenvalue λ2 with ρ=0.6, 0.8. 1.26, (b) the stable fixed point S02 with ρ=0.6, (c) bifurcation diagram with ρ=0.8, (d) bifurcation diagram with ρ=1.26.

    In the case of ρ=0.8,α3=12.9098, |λ2|<1 for α(0, 1.2501) and α(8.001, 12.9098). The bifurcation of fixed points is shown in Figure 6(c). The exist a stable period-T solution for α(0, 1.2501)(8.001, 12.9098) and a stable period-2T solution for α(1.2501, 8.001). Except for stable period-T and period-2T solutions, other types of periodic solutions do not exist in system (4) with ρ=0.8.

    In the case of ρ=1.26, α3=34.3965 and |λ2|<1 for α(0, 0.4841)(30.1510, 34.3965). The bifurcation of fixed points is shown in Figure 6(d). A flip bifurcation occurs at α=0.4810 and an inverse flip bifurcation occurs at α=30.1510. It's seen that system (4) with ρ=1.26 has a stable period-4T solution for α=5 and a period-8T solution for α=25.2, which are shown in Figure 7.

    Figure 7.  For system (4) with ρ=1.26, (a) period-4T solution for α=5, (b) period-8T solution for α=25.2.

    In the above section, the existence of flip bifurcation is discussed. As it well known, one path to chaos is the cascade of flip bifurcations. Figure 8(a) shows the cascade of flip bifurcations and the positive Lyapunov exponent in system (4) with ρ=1.1, which illustrate the existence of chaos. A chaotic solution of system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=10 is shown in Figure 8(b).

    Figure 8.  For system (4) with ρ=1.1, (a) bifurcation diagram and Lyapunov exponent for α(0, 25.7298), (b) a chaotic solution for α=10.

    In the state of chaos, the product sales change disorderly and is out of control. To stabilize the market, we should take measures to suppress bifurcation and eliminate chaos. Here, a small constant is introduced into sales promotion strategy, that is,

    ΔS(t)=S(t+)S(t)=αS(t)+β,   t=nT, (17)

    where β is a small increase in sales at promotion time t=nT. So the following bifurcation control system is obtained.

    {˙S=ρS(t)(1S(t)ργ),   tnT,S(t+)=S(t)+αS(t)+β,  t=nT.    (18)

    Similar to the previous section, we obtain the following map under conditions γ=0.1 and (1exp(ρT))γ=ρ.

    Sk+1=Sk+αSk+β1+10ρ(Sk+αSk+β)=f1(Sk). (19)

    Suppose the positive fixed point of (19) is ˉS0i, the eigenvalue of the fixed point is

    ˉλ0i=1+β+ˉS0+βˉS0α+2αβˉS20αˉS30α2ˉS40(1+βˉS0+αˉS20)2 (20)

    The fixed points of maps (7) and (19) are shown in Figure 9(a) for ρ=1.1, ΔS(t)=αS(t), ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8. Figure 9(b) shows that α1<α3<α4<α2, where λ2(α1))=λ2(α2))=1 and ˉλ02(α3)=ˉλ02(α4)=1. After taking control measures ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8 at t=nρln(1+10ρ), the flip bifurcation is suppressed from α=α1 to α=α3 while the inverse flip bifurcation occurs from α=α1 to α=α3 in advance. So chaos in system (4) with ΔS(t)=αS(t) may be eliminated.

    Figure 9.  For system with ρ=1.1, ΔS(t)=αS(t), ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8, (a) fixed points, (b) eigenvalues of fixed points S02 and ˉS02.

    The effects of bifurcation control on system (4) with ρ=1.1 and ρ=1.26 are shown in Figure 10. Chaos in system (4) with ΔS(t)=αS(t) are controlled into period-2T state for ρ=1.1 (see Figure 10(a)) and into period-T, 2T, 4T states for ρ=1.26 (see Figure 10(b)).

    Figure 10.  Bifurcation diagrams with ΔS(t)=αS(t) and ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8, (a) ρ=1.1, (b) ρ=1.26.

    Figure 11 shows that control measures ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8 are taken at t=nT (n40,T=11.1ln(1+101.1)=2.2590) in system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=10. A chaotic solution slowly evolves into a stable period-2T solution.

    Figure 11.  Control measures ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8 are taken at t=nT (n40,T=2.2590) in system (4) with ρ=1.1 and α=10, (a) time series of Sn, (b) time series of S(t).

    For system (4) with ρ=1.26 and α=25, suppose that control measures ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8 are taken at t=nT (n40,T=11.26ln(1+101.26))=2.0715. A chaotic solution of system (4) slowly evolves into a stable period-T solution (Figure 12).

    Figure 12.  Control measures ΔS(t)=αS(t)+0.8 are taken at t=nT (n40,T=2.0715) in system (4) with ρ=1.26 and α=25, (a) time series of Sn, (b) time series of S(t).

    In the bifurcation diagram Figure 6(d) of system (4) with ρ=1.26, there is a blank area for α(11.42, 18.91). The reason for this phenomenon is that the promotion strategy ΔS(t)=αS(t) makes sales level S(t) greater than the maximum ργ. So the promotion strategy ΔS(t)=αS(t) is ineffective for α(11.42, 18.91). It's seen from Figure 10(b) that the control strategy ΔS(t)=αS(t)+β can not only control chaos, but also control sales level under the maximum value ργ=12.6. The solution from the initial value S(0)=11.61 crosses the maximum line at t=5T under promotion strategy ΔS(t)=αS(t) for α=15 (see Figure 13(a)). Figures 10(b) and 13(b) show that the solution from the same initial value S(0)=11.61 tends a stable period-4T solution and is always less than ργ under the control strategy ΔS(t)=15S(t)+0.8.

    Figure 13.  The solution from the initial value S(0)=11.61 under (a) promotion strategy ΔS(t)=15S(t), (b) control strategy ΔS(t)=15S(t)+0.8.

    In this paper, single parameter sales promotion strategy is introduced into a nonlinear differential advertising model. Theoretical analysis and numerical results show that the system possesses complex dynamic behavior.

    The coexistence of multi periodic solutions, which include unstable and stable period-nT (n = 1, 2, ...) solutions, occurs in the system for parameter α satisfies some conditions. Interestingly, both flip bifurcation and inverse flip bifurcation occur in nonlinear differential advertising model with sales promotion. System (4) enters into chaos from stable state through flip bifurcation and enters into stable state from chaos through inverse flip bifurcation. By suppressing flip bifurcation and promoting inverse flip bifurcation, an effective control strategy is proposed to eliminate chaos. The parameter α plays an important role in the complex dynamics of advertising model. According to theoretical analysis and actual situation, firms determine the value of parameters α to develop sales promotion strategy and avoid disorderly changes in sales volume.

    The purpose of the proposed sales promotion strategy is to improve sales level and maximize firm's profit. The condition to make sales meet given target is obtained. Considering unit profit margin, constant advertising expenditure, and unit promotion cost, the profit function is constructed. The optimal sales promotion strategy is obtained and used to maximize firm's profit.

    This work is jointly supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (11662001), National Science Foundation of Guangxi Province (2018GXNSFAA138177), and the Young and Middle-aged Teachers Ability Promotion Project of Guangxi District (2019KY0228)

    The authors declare there is no conflict of interest.



    [1] G. Luo, Y. Liu, Q. Zeng, Su. Diao, F. Xiong, A dynamic evolution model of human opinion as affected by advertising, Physica A, 414 (2014), 254–262. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2014.07.055 doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2014.07.055
    [2] J. B. Ford, S. Bezbaruah, P. Mukherji, et al., A decade (2008-2019) of advertising research productivity: A bibliometric review, J. Business Res., 136 (2021), 137–163. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2021.07.030 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2021.07.030
    [3] Z. Guo, J. Ma, Dynamics and implications on a cooperative advertising model in the supply chain, Commun Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul., 64 (2018), 198–212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cnsns.2018.04.017 doi: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2018.04.017
    [4] X. Chen, Y. Zhu, L. Sheng, Optimal control for uncertain stochastic dynamic systems with jump and application to an advertising model, Appl. Math. Comput., 407 (2021), 126337. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2021.126337 doi: 10.1016/j.amc.2021.126337
    [5] R. Y. Chenavaz, G. Feichtinger, R. F. Hartl, P. M. Kort, Modeling the impact of product quality on dynamic pricing and advertising policies, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 284 (2020), 990–1001. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.01.035 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2020.01.035
    [6] L. Leong, T. Hew, K. B. Ooi, Y. K. Dwivedi, Predicting trust in online advertising with an SEM-artificial neural network approach, Expert Syst. Appl., 162 (2020), 113849. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eswa.2020.113849 doi: 10.1016/j.eswa.2020.113849
    [7] L. Weng, Z. Huang, J. Bao, A model of tourism advertising effects, Tour. Manag., 85 (2021), 104278. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104278 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104278
    [8] Q. Wang, J. Wen, P. Zhang, Oscillation analysis of advertising capital model: Analytical and numerical studies, Appl. Math. Comput., 354 (2019), 365–376. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2019.02.029 doi: 10.1016/j.amc.2019.02.029
    [9] M. Nerlove, K. J. Arrow, Optimal advertising policy under dynamic conditions, Economica, 39 (1962), 129–142. https://doi.org/10.2307/2551549 doi: 10.2307/2551549
    [10] M. L. Vidale, H. B. Wolfe, An operations research study of sales response to advertising, Oper. Res., 5 (1957), 370–381. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.5.3.370 doi: 10.1287/opre.5.3.370
    [11] X. Qiu, G. Zhu, Y. Ding, K. Li, Successive lag synchronization on complex dynamical networks via delay-dependent impulsive control, Physica A, 531 (2019), 121753.
    [12] N. Bandyopadhyay, B. Sivakumaran, S. Patro, R. S. Kumar, Immediate or delayed! Whether various types of consumer sales promotions drive impulse buying?: An empirical investigation, J. Retail. Consum. Serv., 61 (2021), 102532. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2019.121753 doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2019.121753
    [13] R. McColl, R. Macgilchrist, S. Rafiq, Estimating cannibalizing effects of sales promotions: The impact of price cuts and store type, J. Retail. Consum. Serv., 53 (2020), 101982. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2019.101982 doi: 10.1016/j.jretconser.2019.101982
    [14] E. Crespo-Almendros, S. Del Barrio-García, Online airline ticket purchasing: Influence of online sales promotion type and Internet experience, J. Air Transp. Manag., 53 (2016), 23–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jairtraman.2016.01.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jairtraman.2016.01.004
    [15] H. Jiang, Z. Feng, G. Jiang, Dynamics of an advertising competition model with sales promotion, Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul., 42 (2017), 37–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cnsns.2016.05.007 doi: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2016.05.007
    [16] F. M. Bass, A new product growth model for consumer durables, Manage. Sci., 15 (1969), 215–227. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.15.5.215 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.15.5.215
    [17] J. Guckenheimer, P. Holmes, Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical Systems, and Bifurcations of Vector Fields, New York: Springer-Verlag, 1983. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-1140-2
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Jiarui Chen, Aimin Tang, Guanfeng Zhou, Ling Lin, Guirong Jiang, Walking dynamics for an ascending stair biped robot with telescopic legs and impulse thrust, 2022, 30, 2688-1594, 4108, 10.3934/era.2022208
    2. Pradeep Kumar, Kuldeep Chaudhary, Vijay Kumar, Sudipa Chauhan, Impact of Goodwill on Consumer Buying through Advertising in a Segmented Market: An Optimal Control Theoretic Approach, 2023, 12, 2075-1680, 223, 10.3390/axioms12020223
    3. Haihu Wang, Qishao Wang, Wei Dong, Chuanming Liu, Wenqing Hong, Yuanni Gong, Qingyun Wang, Kechao Wang, M. Vijayalakshmi, 2023, Bifurcation and chaotic for an asymmetric kneed passive dynamic walker, 9781510671867, 120, 10.1117/12.3011214
    4. You Li, Yueming Xiao, Dynamic analysis of differential advertising model based on single parameter sales promotion strategy, 2025, 2025, 2731-4235, 10.1186/s13662-025-03864-5
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2230) PDF downloads(89) Cited by(4)

Figures and Tables

Figures(13)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog