Research article

Wavelet-based systematic risk estimation: application on GCC stock markets: the Saudi Arabia case

  • Correction on: Quantitative Finance and Economics 7: 117-118.
  • Received: 02 June 2020 Accepted: 01 September 2020 Published: 07 September 2020
  • JEL Codes: G11, C02, C22

  • Systematic risk estimation is widely applied by investors and managers in order to predict risks in the market. One of the most applied measures of risk is the so-called Capital Asset Pricing Model, shortly CAPM. It has been studied empirically focusing on the impact of return interval on the betas. This paper lies in this topic and attempts to estimate the CAPM at different time scales for GCC markets by adapting a wavelet method to examine the relationship between the return of the stock and its systematic risk at different time scales. The main novelty is by applying non-uniform intervals of time. Differently from existing literature, we use random ones. The proposed procedure is acted empirically on a sample corresponding to Saudi Tadawul market as the most important GCC representative market actively traded over the period January 01, 2013 to September 20, 2018, which is characterized by many political, economic and financial movements such as Qatar embargo, Yemen war, NEOM project, 2030 KSA vision and the Arab spring effects. The findings in the present work may be good basis for understanding current and future GCC markets situation and may be thus a basis for investors' decisions in such markets.

    Citation: Anouar Ben Mabrouk. Wavelet-based systematic risk estimation: application on GCC stock markets: the Saudi Arabia case[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(4): 542-595. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020026

    Related Papers:

    [1] Lei Mao, Yan Zhang . Robust optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance and investment problem with p-thinning dependent risks under CEV model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(1): 134-162. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021007
    [2] Sang Phu Nguyen, Toan Luu Duc Huynh . Portfolio optimization from a Copulas-GJR-GARCH-EVT-CVAR model: Empirical evidence from ASEAN stock indexes. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(3): 562-585. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.3.562
    [3] Keyue Yan, Ying Li . Machine learning-based analysis of volatility quantitative investment strategies for American financial stocks. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 364-386. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024014
    [4] James P. Gander . Market Value Volatility and the Volume of Traded Stock for U.S. Industrial Corporations. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(4): 403-410. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.4.403
    [5] Yuhang Zheng, Siming Liu . A Dynamic Analysis of the Business Cycle Model with a Fixed-time Delay. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(2): 174-185. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.2.174
    [6] Muath Asmar, Susanne Trimbath . Regulatory reform and trade settlement failures in USA equity markets: Does regulatory reform matter?. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(4): 537-552. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022023
    [7] Lucia Morales, Daniel Rajmil . Investing in virtue and frowning at vice? Lessons from the global economic and financial crisis. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(1): 1-18. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023001
    [8] Nereida Polovina, Ken Peasnell . The effects of different modes of foreign bank entry in the Turkish banking sector during the 2007–2009 Global financial crisis. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(1): 19-49. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023002
    [9] Anna Timonina-Farkas . COVID-19: data-driven dynamic asset allocation in times of pandemic. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(2): 198-227. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021009
    [10] Andrea Ferrario, Massimo Guidolin, Manuela Pedio . Comparing in- and out-of-sample approaches to variance decomposition-based estimates of network connectedness an application to the Italian banking system. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 661-701. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.661
  • Systematic risk estimation is widely applied by investors and managers in order to predict risks in the market. One of the most applied measures of risk is the so-called Capital Asset Pricing Model, shortly CAPM. It has been studied empirically focusing on the impact of return interval on the betas. This paper lies in this topic and attempts to estimate the CAPM at different time scales for GCC markets by adapting a wavelet method to examine the relationship between the return of the stock and its systematic risk at different time scales. The main novelty is by applying non-uniform intervals of time. Differently from existing literature, we use random ones. The proposed procedure is acted empirically on a sample corresponding to Saudi Tadawul market as the most important GCC representative market actively traded over the period January 01, 2013 to September 20, 2018, which is characterized by many political, economic and financial movements such as Qatar embargo, Yemen war, NEOM project, 2030 KSA vision and the Arab spring effects. The findings in the present work may be good basis for understanding current and future GCC markets situation and may be thus a basis for investors' decisions in such markets.



    1. Introduction

    Investment is an important means of earning profit for insurance companies, reinsurance is in use for controlling insurers' risk exposure. Recently, it became a hot point in optimization and control fields to consider reinsurance and investment synthetically under risk models. There are two main models of reinsurance-investment problem, that is, maximizing the insurer's expected utility of terminal wealth and minimizing the probability of ruin under reinsurance-investment strategies, and each model is based on the quantitative description for insurer's surplus processes. From the known literature, we see that two major types of mathematical model for the surplus of the insurance company are usually exploited, which are the Cramer-Lundberg model and the diffusion model, the former is the so called classical risk process, and the later is an approximation to the former which is feasible as one deals with large insurance portfolios, where an individual claim is relatively small compared to the size of the surplus.

    In our paper, the continuous-time mean-variance reinsurance-investment problem is to be considered, where multiple risky assets for investment exist in the market and diffusion model is exploited to describe the risk process of the insurance company. Under diffusion model of the risk process, related reinsurance-investment problems have attracted a great deal of interest. Promislow et al. (2005) studied the optimal reinsurance-investment strategy to minimize the probability of ruin for insurance companies. Taksar et al. (2003) also obtained the optimal reinsurance-investment strategy to minimize the probability of ruin for insurance companies under diffusion model of surplus process. By solving the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations, Cao et al. (2009) obtained the optimal reinsurance-investment strategies for maximizing the utility of terminal wealth with exponential and power utility functions. Luo et al. (2008) studied the similar problem as Cao et al. (2009) in Black-Scholes market subject to some investment constraints. All of the literature (Browne, 1995; Promislow et al., 2005; Taksar et al., 2003; Cao et al., 2009; Luo et al., 2008) researched their optimization problems in Black-Scholes market with single risky asset. Bai et al. (2008) considered the reinsurance-investment problem in Black-Scholes market with multiple risky assets and no-shorting constraint. Zhang et al. (2009) studied the optimal reinsurance-investment problem of maximizing the expected exponential utility of terminal wealth and solve it by using the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation. It is noted that the transaction costs when investing in the risky assets and conditional Value-at-Risk to control the whole risk have been considered.

    For the sack of practical need in management, mean-variance portfolio selection model initiated by Markowitz has attracted much attention all the time. There has been few literature up to now which devoted themselves to studying the continuous-time mean-variance reinsurance-investment problem, however, the continuous-time mean-variance portfolio selection problem was researched by Zhou et al. (2000)with the help of stochastic linear-quadratic method. As the subsequent paper, Lim et al. (2002) pointed out: there are many advantages of using the framework of stochastic linear-quadratic control to study dynamic mean-variance problems, meanwhile it was recognized that the solution to the problem could also have been obtained via dynamic programming and the associated Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation when the market coefficients are assumed to be deterministic. It is observed that, when the market coefficients are assumed to be deterministic, the Lagrange method can be applied to solving the continuous-time mean-variance portfolio selection problems, which was expounded in Chow (1997) in a general way and was applied to investment decisions and pricing of contingent claims in Chow (1996) and Chow (1999), respectively. The Lagrange method is more popular than other dynamic optimization methods. For our continuous-time mean-variance reinsurance-investment problem with deterministic market coefficients, the Lagrange method is also a simple one to obtain our results, which is the main reason for this research. It should be recognized that the Lagrange method is limited to complex circumstances such as random market coefficients, which induces more complex backward stochastic differential equation for solving the process of the Lagrange multiplier. For more details on the subject, we refer to the recent work such as Chen et al. (2013), Shen et al. (2015), and so on.

    This paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we state the mean-variance optimization problem. In Section 3, we use the Lagrange method to analysis the mean-variance problem, necessary and sufficient conditions for the problem are discussed, the optimal strategy and its effective frontier in explicit forms are obtained. In Section 4, we show a numerical example.


    2. Problem Formulation

    Throughout this paper we denote by M the transpose of any matrix or vector M=(mij), ||M||=i,jm2ij its norm, Rm the mdimensional real space, 1 the vector with unit entries, [0,T] the finite horizon of investment and Et the expectation at time t[0,T].

    Market uncertainty is modeled by a filtered complete probability space (Ω,F,P,{Ft}t[0,T]). Assume that the filtration {Ft}t[0,T] is generated by an (m+1)-dimensional standard Brownian motion {(W0t,W1t,,Wmt):t[0,T]} for a positive integer m. F0={Φ,Ω}, FT=F.

    We recall that the space LF,2([0,T];Rm) of mean square integrable functions u(t,x) from R×Ω to Rm possesses a natural Hilbert space structure, inducing the norm

    ||u||F,2=(E0T0||u(t,X)||2dt)12<+.

    Following the framework of Promislow and Young (2005), we model the insurer's claim process C according to a Brownian motion with drift as follows:

    dC(t)=adtbdW0t, (1)

    where a and b are positive constants. Assume that the premium be paid continuously at the constant rate c0=(1+θ)a with safety loading θ>0, and that the insurer purchase the proportional reinsurance to reduce the underlying risk. Let q(t) represent the proportion reinsured at time t. Similar to the premium paid to the insurer, the reinsurance premium is paid continuously at the constant rate c1=(1+η)aq with safety loading η>θ>0. Based on Eq. (1), the surplus process R(t) is given by the dynamics

    dR(t)=c0dt(1q(t))dC(t)c1dt=(θηq(t))adt+b(1q(t))dW0t. (2)

    In addition to reinsurance, the insurer is allowed to invest its surplus in a financial market in which (m+1) assets are traded continuously over [0,T] in a self-financing fashion (i.e., there is no consumption nor income). The 0th asset is a bond whose price S0(t) is subject to the following deterministic ordinary differential equation:

    dS0(t)=r(t)S0(t)dt,S0(0)=1, (3)

    where r(t)C([0,T];R+) is the interest rate of the risk-free asset. The remaining m assets are risky and their price processes S1(t),S2(t),,Sm(t) satisfy the following stochastic differential equations:

    dSi(t)=μi(t)Si(t)dt+σi(t)Si(t)dWt,Si(0)=si>0,i=1,2,,m, (4)

    where μi(t) and σi(t)=[σi1(t),,σim(t)] are the appreciation rate and dispersion (or volatility) rate of the ith asset, respectively, and W=(W1t,,Wmt). We assume that μi(t) and σi(t) are scalar-valued deterministic bounded functions. Denoting

    σ(t)=[σ1(t)σm(t)]Rm×m, (5)

    we assume throughout that σ(t) is uniformly nondegenerate: that is, there exists δ>0 such that

    σ(t)σ(t)δI,t[0,T]. (6)

    A strategy s is described by a stochastic process (q(t),π(t)), where π(t) :=(π1(t),π2(t),,πm(t)), πi(t) is the dollar amount invested in asset i(i=1,2,,m) at time t.

    Let X(t) denote the resulting surplus process after incorporating strategy s into (2). The dynamics of X(t) can be represented as follows.

    dX(t)=[r(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t)]dt+b(1q(t))dW0t+π(t)σ(t)dWt, (7)

    where τ(t)=(μ1(t)r(t),,μm(t)r(t)), X(0)=x0.

    The admissible strategy set with initial wealth x0 is defined as

    A(x0):={s=(q(t),π(t))|q(t),π(t)satisfies(2.7)}

    The objective of the insurer is to determine an optimal strategy sA(x0) such that the variance of the terminal wealth, Var[X(T)], is minimized, subject to that the expected terminal wealth, E0[X(T)], takes a given level K>x0exp(T0r(t)dt). This can be expressed as the optimization problem:

    {minsA(x0)Var[X(T)]=E0[X2(T)K],s.t.E0[X(T)]=K. (8)

    We introduce a Lagrange multiplier 2ξR and after rearranging terms arrive at the new cost function,

    E0[(X(T)2K)2+2ξ(X(T)K)]=E0[X(T)(Kξ)]2ξ2.

    Letting γ=Kξ leads to the following optimal stochastic control problem,

    maxsA(x0){(Kγ)2E0[X(T)2γ]2}. (9)

    Remark 2.1. The link between problem (8) and (9) is provided by the Lagrange duality theorem, see e.g. Luenberger (1968)

    minsA(x0)Var[X(T)]=maxγRmaxsA(x0){(Kγ)2E0[X(T)2γ]2}.

    3. Mean-Variance Analysis by the Lagrange Method

    For the first step, we consider problem (9) for a fixed γ. Follow the Lagrange method introduced by Chow (1997), recognizing dX(t)=X(t+dt)X(t), and let dt be a very small time interval. The Lagrange expression for the optimization problem (9) beginning from t=0 is

    L=(Kγ)2Et[X(T)2γ]2
    T0Etλ(t+dt)[X(t+dt)X(t)(r(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t))dt
    b(1q(t))dW0tπ(t)σ(t)dWt]. (10)

    For simplicity, denote by

    f(X(t),q(t),π1(t),,πm(t))=r(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t),
    R(q(t))=b(1q(t)).

    The Lagrange expression (10) can be rewritten as follows.

    L=(Kγ)2Et[X(T)2γ]2
    T0Etλ(t+dt)[X(t+dt)fdtR(q)dW0tπ(t)σ(t)dWt]. (11)

    Remark 3.1: By theorem 4.2 of Yong and Zhou(1999), problem (9) with dynamic constraint (7) admits a pathwise unique admissible strategy in A(x0), which implies, for a given γR, maximization of the cost function L in (11) is uniquely solvable, henceforth, the Lagrange multiplier λ=λ(t,X(t)) can be uniquely determined.


    3.1. Necessary conditions

    Let the function λ be in the form λ=λ(t,X(t)), applying Ito's differentiation rule to evaluate dλ yields

    dλ=[λt+λXf+122λX2(R2(q)+||π(t)σ(t)||2)]dt
    +λXR(q)dW0t+λXπ(t)σ(t)dWt. (12)

    Differentiating (11) with respect to X(T), we have

    λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ. (13)

    Differentiating (11) with respect to q(t) gives

    Lq=fqEtλ(t+dt)dt+EtdW0tRqλ(t+dt)
    =fq(λdt+Etdλdt)+EtdW0tRqλ(t+dt)
    =[fqλ(t)+RqλXR(q)]dt+o(dt)
    =[aηλ(t)bR(q)λX]dt+o(dt)=0.

    Hence

    aηλ(t)+bR(q)λX=0. (14)

    Differentiating (11) with respect to π(t) yields

    Lπ=[λ(t)τ(t)+λXσ(t)σ(t)π(t)]dt+o(dt)=0.

    Hence

    λ(t)τ(t)+λXσ(t)σ(t)π(t)=0. (15)

    Noting the term λ(t)[X(t)] in the integrand of (11), differentiating (11) with respect to X(t)(0t<T) gives

    LX=λ(t)+Etλ(t+dt)+fXEtλ(t+dt)dt
    =λ(t)+Et(λ(t)+dλ(t))+fXEt(λ(t)+dλ(t))dt
    =[λt+λXf+fXλ(t)+122λX2(R2(q)+||π(t)σ(t)||2)]dt+o(dt)
    =0.

    Hence

    λt+λXf+fXλ(t)+122λX2(R2(q)+||π(t)σ(t)||2)=0. (16)

    Now we state the necessary conditions for the optimization problem (9) as follows.

    Proposition 3.1. Let s=(q(t),π(t)) be the optimal reinsurance-investment strategy for the optimization problem (9), then the equations (12)-(16) hold.


    3.2. Sufficient conditions

    First, we give the explicit expression of the wealth process X(t). Let

    Y(t)=X(t)exp(t0r(s)ds),

    which yields

    dY(t)=exp(t0r(s)ds)[dX(t)r(t)X(t)dt],

    In view of (7), we have

    dY(t)=exp(t0r(s)ds)[((θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t))dt+R(q)dW0t+π(t)σ(t)dWt],

    and thus

    Y(t)Y(0)=t0exp(s0r(u)du)[((θηq(s))a+τ(s)π(s))ds+R(q)dW0s+π(s)σ(s)dWs].

    So, we have

    X(t)=x0exp(t0r(s)ds)+t0exp(tsr(u)du)[(θηq(s))a+τ(s)π(s))ds.
    +R(q)dW0s+π(s)σ(s)dW. (17)

    In view of (17), it is not difficulty to find that both Et[X(T)2/q2] and Et[X(T)2/πi2] are positive, which guarantees that the necessary conditions stated in proposition 3.1 are also sufficient conditions for the optimization problem (9) according to Chow (1997).


    3.3. Optimal reinsurance-investment strategy

    Noting that f=r(t)X(t)(θηq(t))a+(θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t), from (3.7) and (3.4), we have

    {λt+[r(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+τ(t)π(t)]λX    12[R2(q)+||π(t)σ(t)||2]2λX2+r(t)λ(t)=0,λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ. (18)

    According to Remark 3.1, problem (18) has an unique solution λ(t,X(t)). So, in view of (14) and (15), the components of admissible strategy, q(t) and π(t), are uniquely determined. For purpose of getting the unique solution of (18), we start by finding q(t) and π(t) in linear feedback form as follows.

    q(t)=ϕ1(t)X(t)+φ1(t),π(t)=ϕ2(t)X(t)+φ2(t), (19)

    where ϕ1,φ1C1[0,T;R] and ϕ2,φ2C1[0,T;Rm] are deterministic functions to be determined.

    From (14) and (19), remarking that R(q)=b(1q(t)), we have

    aηλ(t)+b2(1ϕ1(t)X(t)φ1(t))λX=0. (20)

    Differentiating (20) with respect to X(t) arrives at

    (aηb2ϕ1(t))λX+bR(q)2λX2=0.

    Hence

    R2(q)2λX2=(ϕ1(t)aη/b2)bR(q)2λX2=aη(ϕ1(t)aη/b2)λ, (21)

    where (14) is incorporated in the second equality in (21).

    From (15) and (19), we have

    λ(t)τ(t)+λXσ(t)σ(t)(ϕ2(t)X(t)+φ2(t))=0. (22)

    Differentiating (22) with respect to X(t) arrives at

    λX(τ(t)+σ(t)σ(t)ϕ2(t))+2λX2σ(t)σ(t)π(t)=0. (23)

    Hence

    ||π(t)σ(t)||22λX2=λXπ(t)(τ(t)+σ(t)σ(t)ϕ2(t)).
    =λXτ(t)π(t)+λ(t)ϕ2(t)τ(t), (24)

    where (15) is incorporated in the second equality in (23). Substituting from (21) and (24) into (18) gives

    {λt+[r(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+12τ(t)π(t)]λX    +12[2r(t)aη(ϕ1(t)aη/b2)+ϕ2(t)τ(t)]λ=0,λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ. (25)

    Characteristic equation of the first order partial differential equation in (25) is

    dt1=dXr(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+12τ(t)π(t)
    =dλ12(2r(t)aη(ϕ1(t)aη/b2)+ϕ2(t)τ(t))

    In view of

    dt1=dXr(t)X(t)+(θηq(t))a+12τ(t)π(t)

    we obtain a first integration as follows.

    C1=X(t)exp(t0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s)ds)
    Tt(aθaηφ1(u)+12τ(u)ϕ2(u))×exp(u0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s)ds)du,

    where C1 is constant. In view of

    dt1=dλ12(2r(t)aη(ϕ1(t)aη/b2)+ϕ2(t)τ(t)),

    we get another first integration:

    C2=λ(t)+12Tt[2r(s)aη(ϕ1(s)aη/b2)+ϕ2(s)τ(s)]ds,

    where C2 is constant. It is obvious that both the first integrations obtained above are mutual independent. Invoking the boundary condition in (25), that is, λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ, relationship between C1 and C2 is

    C2=2exp(T0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s))ds)C1+2γ

    so we get the solution of (25) as following.

    λ(t)+12Tt[2r(s)aη(ϕ1(s)aη/b2)+ϕ2(s)τ(s)]ds
    =2exp(T0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s))ds)
    ×[X(t)exp(t0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s)ds)
    Tt(aθaηφ1(u)+12τ(u)φ2(u))
    ×exp(u0(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)φ2(s))du]+2γ. (26)

    From (26), we see that

    {λX=2exp(Tt(r(s)aηϕ1(s)+12τ(s)ϕ2(s)ds)0,2λX2=0. (27)

    By (21) and the second equation in (27), we get ϕ1(t)=aη/b2. By (23) and (27), we get ϕ2(t)=(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t). Substituting from the results of ϕ1(t) and ϕ2(t) into (27) shows

    λX=2exp(Tt(r(s)a2η2b212||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds):=H(t). (28)

    Substituting from the results of ϕ1(t) and ϕ2(t) into (26) gives

    λ(t)=H(t)X(t)+h(t), (29)

    where

    h(t)=2Tt(aθaηφ1(u)+12τ(u)φ2(u))
    ×exp(Tu(r(s)a2η2b212||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)du
    12Tt[2r(s)||σ1(s)τ(s)||2]ds+2γ.

    Then h(T)=2γ, and

    dhdt=[(aθaηφ1(t)+12τ(t)φ2(t))]H(t)
    +12[2r(s)||σ1(t)τ(t)||2], (30)

    where H(t) is given by (28).

    By (22), (29) and ϕ2(t)=(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t), we have

    H(t)φ2(t)=h(t)(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t). (31)

    By (20), (29) and ϕ1(t)=aη/b2, we have

    H(t)φ1(t)=aηb2h(t)+H(t). (32)

    Substituting from (31) and (32) into (30) gives

    dhdt=(a2η2b2+12||σ1(t)τ(t)||2)h(t)+aθH(t)+12[2r(t)||σ1(t)τ(t)||2].

    Remarking that h(T)=2γ, we have

    h(t)=2γexp(a2η2b2(Tt)+12Tt||σ1(s)τ(s)||2ds)
    Ttexp(a2η2b2(ut)+12ut||σ1(s)τ(s)||2ds)
    ×[aθH(u)+(r(u)12||σ1(u)τ(u)||2]du. (33)

    From (31) and (32), we have

    φ2(t)=h(t)H(t)(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t),φ1(t)=aηb2h(t)H(t)+1,

    so we have

    {q(t)=ϕ1(t)X(t)+φ1(t)=aηb(X(t)+h(t)H(t))+1;π(t)=ϕ2(t)X(t)+φ2(t)=(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t)(X(t)+h(t)H(t)), (34)

    and

    λ(t)=H(t)X(t)+h(t), (35)

    where H(t) and h(t) are given by (28) and (33), respectively. We state one of our main results as follows.

    Proposition 3.2. Let τ(t)=(μ1(t)r(t),,μm(t)r(t)), and γR be given. The optimal reinsurance-investment strategy for problem (2.9) are given by (34), and the Lagrange multiplier λ(t,X(t)) is a linear function of X(t) which is given by (35).


    3.4. The effective frontier

    From (35), we have

    λt=dHdtX(t)+dhdt,λX=H(t),2λX2=0.

    From equations (12) and (13), we have the backward stochastic differential equation (BSDE, for short) with terminal value for the Lagrange multiplier λ.

    {dλ=[dHdtX(t)+dhdt+H(t)f]dt+H(t)R(q)dW0t+H(t)π(t)σ(t)dWt,λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ. (36)

    From (18) we have dHdtX(t)+dhdt+H(t)f=λr(t). Substituting from (34) into (36), one obtains

    {dλ=λ[r(t)dt+aηbdW0t+(σ1(t)τ(t))dWt],λ(T)=2X(T)+2γ. (37)

    BSDE (37) has the following solution.

    λ=2(X(T)γ)exp[Tt(r(s)l(s)2)ds]
    ×exp[aηb(W0TW0t)+Tt(σ1(s)τ(s))dWs], (38)

    where l=a2η2/b2+||σ1τ||2. By λ obtained in (38), we then have

    λ(0,X(0))=H(0)X(0)+h(0)
    =2(X(T)γ)exp[T0(r(t)l(t)2)dt]×exp[aηbW0T+T0(σ1(t)τ(t))dWt].

    Hence

    X(T)=12(H(0)x0+h(0))exp(T0(r(t)l(t)2)dt)
    ×exp(aηbW0TT0(σ1(t)τ(t))dWt)+γ,

    which implies

    E0[X(T)]=12(H(0)x0+h(0))exp(T0(r(t)l(t))dt)+γ.

    From (28) and (33), we have

    H(0)=2exp(T0(r(s)a2η2b212||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds),

    and

    h(0)=2γexp(a2η2b2T+12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)h(0),

    where

    h(0)=T0exp(a2η2b2u+12u0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2ds)
    ×[aθH(u)+(r(u)12||σ1(u)τ(u)||2)]du.

    Denoting by A=H(0)x0h(0), we have

    E0[X(T)]=12Aexp(T0(r(t)l(t))dt)
    +γ[1exp(T0(r(s)2l(s))ds12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]. (39)

    Furthermore, we have

    X2(T)=14(H(0)x0+h(0))2exp(T0(2r(t)l(t))dt)
    ×exp(2aηbW0T2T0(σ1(t)τ(t))dWt)+γ2
    γ(H(0)x0+h(0))exp(T0(r(t)l(t)2)dt)
    ×exp(aηbW0TT0(σ1(t)τ(t))dWt),

    which yields

    E0[X2(T)]=14A2exp(T0(2r(t)3l(t))dt)
    +A[exp(T0(2r(s)4l(s))ds12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)exp(T0(r(s)l(s))ds)]γ
    +[1+exp(T0(2r(s)5l(s))dsT0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]
    2exp(T0(r(s)2l(s))ds12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)γ2. (40)

    Using (39) and (40) we can thus give an explicit expression for the optimal cost in problem (8), as a one parameter family in γ

    (Kγ)2E0[X(T)γ]2=K22γK+2γE0[X(T)]E0[X2(T)]=K214A2exp(T0(2r(t)3l(t))dt)  [2K+Aexp(T0(2r(s)4l(s))ds12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]γ  [exp(T0(2r(s)5l(s))dsT0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)1]γ2.

    Assume that

    T0(5l(s)2r(s))dsT0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds
    =T0[4||σ1(s)τ(s)||22r(s)]ds+5a2η2T/b2:=ρ>0 (41)

    hold, using remark 2.1, we see that the minimum Var[X(T)] is achieved for

    γ=K+A2exp(T0(2r(s)4l(s))ds12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2ds)eρ1 (42)

    and

    minsA(x0)Var[X(T)]=eρeρ1[K+A2exp(T0l(s)ds+12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]2. (43)

    Now we state the conclusion of the effective frontier of our mean-variance problem as follows.

    Proposition 3.3. Let K=E0[X(T)], τ(t)=(μ1(t)r(t),,μm(t)r(t)), l(t)=a2η2/b2+||σ1(t)τ(t)||2, A=H(0)x0h(0). Assume that (41) hold. The effective frontier of the mean-variance reinsurance-investment strategy for problem (8) is given by

    Var[X(T)]=eρeρ1[K+A2exp(T0l(s)ds+12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]2. (44)

    4. Numerical Example

    Let x0=1, r(t)=0.06, m=3, μ1(t)=0.08, μ2(t)=0.10, μ3(t)=0.15, a=1, b=0.5, θ=0.2, η=0.3, and

    σ(t)=(0.200.150.060.100.300.250.400.050.50).

    Then

    σ1(t)=(2.8701.3570.9481.9712.1570.7652.1740.8701.304),τ(t)=(0.02,0.04,0.09),

    and

    ||σ1(t)τ(t)||2=0.022865,(σ(t)σ(t))1=(16.84801.53454.04781.53457.25101.80214.04781.80213.1843).

    Hence l(t)=a2η2/b2+||σ1(t)τ(t)||2=0.382865. In view of (28) and (33), and let e2.718, direct calculation gives h(t)/H(t)=0.07320.9268×1.9794Tt. According to proposition 3.2, the mean-variance optimal reinsurance-investment strategy are given by (34), that is,

    {q(t)=aηb2(X(t)+h(t)H(t))+1=1+1.2(X(t)+0.07320.9268×1.9794Tt)    =1.0878+1.2X(t)1.1122×1.9794Tt;π(t)=(σ(t)σ(t))1τ(t)(X(t)+h(t)H(t))    =(0.63990.09720.2955)(X(t)++0.07320.9268×1.9794Tt)    =(0.04680.00710.0216)(0.63990.09720.2955)X(t)+(0.59310.09010.2739)×1.9794Tt,

    Remark that

    ρ=T0[4||σ1(s)τ(s)||22r(s)]ds+5a2η2T/b2=1.77146T>0, A=H(0)x0h(0)=0.13082.5858×1.3653T+0.4550×1.4498T. In view of (44), the effective frontier of the mean-variance reinsurance-investment strategy is given by

    Var[X(T)]=eρeρ1[K+A2exp(T0l(s)ds+12T0||σ1(s)τ(s)||2)ds)]2
    =5.8784T5.8784T1(0.0654×1.4498T+0.2775×2.1019T1.2929×1.0619T+E0[X(T)])2.

    Furthermore, let T=1, we have

    Var[X(1)]=1.2050(0.6948+E0[X(1)])2.

    Acknowledgments

    This work is supported by the Foundation of Guangzhou Academy of International Finance (No: 16GFR01A04, 16GFR01A07).


    Conflict of Interest

    All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.




    [1] Aktan B, Ozturk M, Rhaeim N, et al. (2009) Wavelet-Based Systematic Risk Estimation An Application on Istanbul Stock Exchange. Int Res J Financ Econ 23: 34-45.
    [2] Arfaoui S, Rezgui I, Mabrouk AB (2017) Wavelet Analysis On The Sphere, Spheroidal Wavelets, Degryuter, Degruyter, 2017, ISBN 978-3-11-048188-4.
    [3] Arfaoui S, Mabrouk AB, Cattani C (2020) New type of Gegenbauer-Hermite monogenic polynomials and associated Clifford wavelets. J Math Imaging Vision 62: 73-97.
    [4] Arfaoui S, Mabrouk AB, Cattani C (2020) New type of Gegenbauer-Jacobi-Hermite monogenic polynomials and associated continuous Clifford wavelet transform. Acta Applicandea Math. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10440-020-00322-0.
    [5] Aydogan K (1989) Portfolio Theory, Capital Market Board of Turkey Research Report: Ankara.
    [6] Banz RW (1981) The relationship between return and market value of common stock. J Financ Econ 9: 3-18.
    [7] Basu S (1977) The relationship between earnings' yield, market value and return for NYSE common stocks-further evidence. J Financ 32: 663-681.
    [8] Mabrouk AB, Mohamed MLB, Omrani K (2008) Numerical solutions for PDEs modeling binary alloy-solidification dynamics, In: Proceedings of 2007 International Symposium on Nonlinear Dynamics, J Phys, conference series 96 (2008) 012067.
    [9] Mabrouk AB, Kortass H, Ammou SB (2008) Wavelet Estimators for Long Memory in Stock Markets. Int J Theor Appl Financ 12: 297-317.
    [10] Mabrouk AB, Kahloul I, Hallara SE (2010) Wavelet-Based Prediction for Governance, Diversification and Value Creation Variables. Int Res J Financ Econ 60: 15-28.
    [11] Mabrouk AB, Abdallah NB, Hamrita ME (2011) A wavelet method coupled with quasi self similar stochastic processes for time series approximation. Int J Wavelets Multiresolution Inf Process 9: 685-711.
    [12] Mabrouk AB, Zaafrane O (2013) Wavelet Fuzzy Hybrid Model For Physico Financial Signals. J Appl Stat 40: 1453-1463.
    [13] Mabrouk AB, Rabbouch B, Saadaoui F (2015) A wavelet based methodology for predicting transmembrane segments, In: Poster Session, The International Conference of Engineering Sciences for Biology and Medecine, 1-3 May 2015, Monastir, Tunisie.
    [14] Black F, Jensen MC, Scholes M(1972) The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests, in Jensen MC (ed), Studies in the theory of Capital, New York: Praeger, 1-54.
    [15] Black F (1972) Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing. J Bus 45: 444-455.
    [16] Breeden D (1979) An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities. J Financ Econ 73: 265-296.
    [17] Brennan MJ (1973) Taxes, market valuation and corporate financial policy. Natl tax J 23: 417-427.
    [18] Chae J, Yang C (2008) Which idiosyncratic factors can explain the pricing errors from asset pricing models in the Korean stock market? Asia-Pasific J Financ Stud 37: 297-342.
    [19] Chan LK, Lakonishok J (1993) Are the reports of beta's death premature? J Portf Manage 19: 51-62.
    [20] Cifter A, Ozun A (2007) Multiscale systematic risk: An application on ISE 30, MPRA Paper 2484, University Library of Munich: Germany.
    [21] Cifter A, Ozun A (2008) A signal processing model for time series analysis: The effect of international F/X markets on domestic currencies using wavelet networks. Int Rev Electr Eng 3: 580-591.
    [22] Cohen K, Hawawin G, Mayer S, et al. (1986) The Microstructure of Securities Markets, Prentice-Hall: Sydney.
    [23] Conlon T, Crane M, Ruskin HJ (2008) Wavelet multiscale analysis for hedge funds: Scaling and strategies. Phys A 387: 5197-5204.
    [24] Daubechies I (1992) Ten Lectures on Wavelets, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia.
    [25] Desmoulins-Lebeault F (2003) Distribution of Returns and the CAPM Empirical Problems. Post-Print halshs-00165099, HAL.
    [26] DiSario R, Saroglu H, McCarthy J, et al. (2008) Long memory in the volatility of an emerging equity market: The case of Turkey. Int Mark Inst Money 18: 305-312.
    [27] Fama EF (1970) Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. J Financ 25: 383-417.
    [28] Fama E, French K (1992) The Cross-section of Expected Stock Returns. J Financ 47: 427-465.
    [29] Fama E, French K (1993) Common risk factors in returns on stocks and bonds. J Financ Econ 33: 3-56.
    [30] Fama E, French KR (1996) The CAPM is Wanted, Dead or Alive. J Financ 51: 1947-1958.
    [31] Fama E, French KR (2004) The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence. J Econo Perspect 18: 25-46.
    [32] Fama E, French KR (2006) The Value Premium and the CAPM. J Financ 61: 2163-2185.
    [33] Fama E, MacBeth J (1973) Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests. J Polit Econ 81: 607-636.
    [34] Fernandez V (2006) The CAPM and value at risk at different time-scales. Int Rev Financ Anal 15: 203-219.
    [35] Friend L, Landskroner Y, Losq E (1976) The demand for risky assets and uncertain inflation. J Financ 31: 1287-1297.
    [36] Galagedera DUA (2007) A review of capital asset pricing models. Managerial Financ 33: 821-832.
    [37] Gençay R, Selçuk F, Whitcher B (2002) An Introduction to Wavelets and Other Filtering Methods in Finance and Economics, Academic Press, San Diego.
    [38] Gençay R, Whitcher B, Selçuk F (2003) Systematic Risk and Time Scales. Quant Financ 3: 108-116.
    [39] Gençay R, Whitcher B, Selçuk F (2005) Multiscale systematic risk. J Inte Money Financ 24: 55-70.
    [40] Gibbons MR (1982) Multivariate tests of financial models: A new approach. J Financ Econ 10: 3-27.
    [41] Gursoy CT, Rejepova G (2007) Test of capital asset pricing model in Turkey. J Dogus Univ 8: 47-58.
    [42] Handa P, Kothari SP, Wasley C (1989) The relation between the return interval and beta: Implications for size-effect. J Financ Econ 23: 79-100.
    [43] Handa P, Kothari SP, Wasley C (1993) Sensitivity of multivariate tests of the CAPM to the return measurement interval. J Financ 48: 1543-1551.
    [44] Ho YW, Strange R, Piesse J (2000) CAPM anomalies and the pricing of equity: Evidence from the Hong Kong market. Appl Econ 32: 1629-1636.
    [45] Hubbard BB (1998) The world according to wavelets: The story of a mathematical technique in the making, 2e, Ak Peters Ltd., MA.
    [46] Mahmoud IMM, Ben Mabrouk A, Hashim MHA (2016) Wavelet multifractal models for transmembrane proteins' series. Int J Wavelets Multires Inf Process 14: 36.
    [47] In F, Kim S (2006) The hedge ratio and the empirical relationship between the stock and futures markets: A new approach using wavelet analysis. J Bus 79: 799-820.
    [48] In F, Kim S (2007) A note on the relationship between Fama-French risk factors and innovations of ICAPM state variables. Financ Res Lett 4: 165-171.
    [49] In F, Kim S, Marisetty V, et al. (2008) Analysing the performance of managed funds using the wavelet multiscaling method. Rev Quant Financ Accounting 31: 55-70.
    [50] Karan MB, Karadagli E (2001) Risk return and market equilibrium in Istanbul stock exchange: The test of the capital asset pricing model. J Econ Administrative Sci 19: 165-177.
    [51] Kishor NK, Marfatia HA (2013) The time-varying response of foreign stock markets to US monetary policy surprises: Evidence from the Federal funds futures market. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 24: 1-24.
    [52] Kothari S, Shanken J (1998) On defense of beta, J. Stern, and D. Chew, Jr. (Eds.), The Revolution in Corporate Finance, 3e, Blackwell Publishers Inc., 52-57.
    [53] Levhari D, Levy H (1977) The Capital Asset Pricing Model and the Investment Horizon. Rev Econ Stat 59: 92-104.
    [54] Lévy H (1978) Equilibrium in an imperfect market: a constraint on the number of securities in the portfolio. Am Econ Rev 68: 643-658.
    [55] Lintner J (1965a) Security Prices and Maximal Gaines from Diversification. J Financ 20: 587-615.
    [56] Lintner J (1965b) The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets. Rev Econ Stat 47: 13-37.
    [57] Litzenberger RH, Ramaswamy K (1979) The effect of personal taxes and dividends on capital asset prices: Theory and empirical evidence. J Financ Econ 7: 163-195.
    [58] Magni CA (2007a) Project selection and equivalent CAPM-based investment criteria. Appl Financ Econ Lett 3: 165-168.
    [59] Magni CA (2007b) Project valuation and investment decisions: CAPM versus arbitrage. Appl Financ Econ Lett 3: 137-140.
    [60] Marfatia HA (2014) Impact of uncertainty on high frequency response of the US stock markets to the Fed's policy surprises. Q Rev Econ Financ 54: 382-392.
    [61] Marfatia HA (2015) Monetary policy's time-varying impact on the US bond markets: Role of financial stress and risks. North Am J Econ Financ 34: 103-123.
    [62] Marfatia HA (2017a) A fresh look at integration of risks in the international stock markets: A wavelet approach. Rev Financ Econ 34: 33-49.
    [63] Marfatia HA (2017b) Wavelet Linkages of Global Housing Markets and macroeconomy. Available at SSRN 3169424.
    [64] Marfatia HA (2020) Investors' Risk Perceptions in the US and Global Stock Market Integration. Res Int Bus Financ 52: 101169.
    [65] Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio Selection. J Financ 7: 77-91.
    [66] Merton RC (1973) An Intertermporal Capital Asset Pricing Model. Econometrica: J Econometric Society 41: 867-887.
    [67] Mossin I (1966) Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market. Econometrica: J Econometric Society 34: 768-783.
    [68] Perold A (2004) The Capital Asset Pricing Model. J Econ Perspect 18: 3-24.
    [69] Percival DB, Walden AT (2000) Wavelet methods for time series analysis, Camridge University Press, NY.
    [70] Rhaiem R, Ammou SB, Mabrouk AB (2007a) Estimation of the systematic risk at different time scales: Application to French stock market. Int J Appl Econ Financ 1: 79-87.
    [71] Rhaiem R, Ammou SB, Mabrouk AB (2007b) Wavelet estimation of systematic risk at different time scales, Application to French stock markets. Int J Appl Econ Financ 1: 113-119.
    [72] Roll R (1977) A critique of the asset pricing theory's tests Part I: On past and potential testability of the theory. J Financ Econ 4: 129-176.
    [73] Selcuk F (2005) Wavelets: A new analysis method (in Turkish). Bilkent J 3: 12-14.
    [74] Sharkasi A, Crane M, Ruskin HJ, et al.(2006) The reaction of stock markets to crashes and events: A comparison study between emerging and mature markets using wavelet transforms. Phys A 368: 511-521.
    [75] Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Financ 19: 425-442.
    [76] Sharpe WF (1970a) Computer-Assisted Economics. J Financ Quant Anal, 353-366.
    [77] Sharpe WF (1970b) Stock market price behavior. A discussion. J Financ 25: 418-420.
    [78] Sharpe WF (1970c) Portfolio theory and capital markets, McGraw-Hill College.
    [79] Soltani S (2002) On the use of the wavelet decomposition for time series prediction. Neurocomput 48: 267-277.
    [80] Soltani S, Modarres R, Eslamian SS (2007) The use of time series modeling for the determination of rainfall climates of Iran. Int J Climatol 27: 819-829.
    [81] Vasichek AA, McQuown JA (1972) Le modèle de marché efficace. Analyse financière, 15, 1973, traduit de "The effecient market model". Financ Anal J.
    [82] Xiong X, Zhang X, Zhang W, et al. (2005) Wavelet-based beta estimation of China stock market, In: Proceedings of 4th International Conference on Machine Learning and Cybernetic, Guangzhou. IEEE: 0-7803-9091-1.
    [83] Yamada H (2005) Wavelet-based beta estimation and Japanese industrial stock prices. Appl Econ Lett 12: 85-88.
    [84] Zemni M, Jallouli M, Mabrouk AB, et al. (2019a) Explicit Haar-Schauder multiwavelet filters and algorithms. Part II: Relative entropy-based estimation for optimal modeling of biomedical signals. Int J Wavelets Multiresolution Inf Process 17: 1950038.
    [85] Zemni M, Jallouli M, Mabrouk AB, et al. (2019b) ECG Signal Processing with Haar-Schauder Multiwavelet, In: Proceedings of the 9th International Conference on Information Systems and Technologies—Icist 2019.
  • QFE-04-04-026-s001.pdf
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Yue Liu, Dehao Ruan, Stability of a Class of Impulsive Neutral Stochastic Functional Partial Differential Equations, 2020, 2020, 1026-0226, 1, 10.1155/2020/9051396
    2. Xia Zhao, Mengjie Li, Qinrui Si, Optimal investment-reinsurance strategy with derivatives trading under the joint interests of an insurer and a reinsurer, 2022, 30, 2688-1594, 4619, 10.3934/era.2022234
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2020 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4581) PDF downloads(149) Cited by(11)

Article outline

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog