Research article

Forecasting the Taylor rule exchange rate model using directional change tests

  • Received: 17 September 2018 Accepted: 21 November 2018 Published: 03 December 2018
  • JEL Codes: C53, E44, F37, F41

  • This study uses the Taylor rule model of exchange rate determination, to analyse how accurately it can predict directional changes in the exchange rate. Using bilateral exchange rate data for the US, UK, Sweden and Australia, we conduct the Pesaran-Timmermann test to determine how accurately this model can forecast changes in direction. The results suggest that although in many studies the standard out-of-sample forecasting ability of this model has been successful, the performance of the change of direction predictions are not consistently accurate over all specifications tested, in which case they may not prove profitable in a trading environment.

    Citation: Rudan Wang, Bruce Morley. Forecasting the Taylor rule exchange rate model using directional change tests[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 931-951. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.931

    Related Papers:

    [1] Sahar Charfi, Farouk Mselmi . Modeling exchange rate volatility: application of GARCH models with a Normal Tempered Stable distribution. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 206-222. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022009
    [2] Lucjan T. Orlowski, Monika Sywak . Wavering interactions between commodity futures prices and us dollar exchange rates. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(2): 221-243. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.2.221
    [3] Yonghong Zhong, Richard I.D. Harris, Shuhong Deng . The spillover effects among offshore and onshore RMB exchange rate markets, RMB Hibor market. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 294-309. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020014
    [4] Akash Deep . Advanced financial market forecasting: integrating Monte Carlo simulations with ensemble Machine Learning models. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 286-314. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024011
    [5] Andres Fernandez, Norman R. Swanson . Further Evidence on the Usefulness of Real-Time Datasets for Economic Forecasting. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(1): 2-25. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.1.2
    [6] Haryo Kuncoro, Fafurida Fafurida, Izaan Azyan Bin Abdul Jamil . Growth volatility in the inflation-targeting regime: Evidence from Indonesia. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 235-254. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024009
    [7] Kai R. Wenger, Christian H. Leschinski, Philipp Sibbertsen . The memory of volatility. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 622-644. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.137
    [8] Diego Ardila, Dorsa Sanadgol, Didier Sornette . Out-of-sample forecasting of housing bubble tipping points. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 904-930. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.904
    [9] Korhan Gokmenoglu, Baris Memduh Eren, Siamand Hesami . Exchange rates and stock markets in emerging economies: new evidence using the Quantile-on-Quantile approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(1): 94-110. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021005
    [10] Ramzi Drissi, Jamel Boukhatem . A nonlinear adjustment in real exchange rates under transaction costs hypothesis in developed and emerging countries. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 220-235. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020010
  • This study uses the Taylor rule model of exchange rate determination, to analyse how accurately it can predict directional changes in the exchange rate. Using bilateral exchange rate data for the US, UK, Sweden and Australia, we conduct the Pesaran-Timmermann test to determine how accurately this model can forecast changes in direction. The results suggest that although in many studies the standard out-of-sample forecasting ability of this model has been successful, the performance of the change of direction predictions are not consistently accurate over all specifications tested, in which case they may not prove profitable in a trading environment.


    1. Introduction

    The ability to forecast directional change in exchange rates is important to asset managers and macroeconomists, with implications regarding the efficient allocation of capital and the ability to predict important economic events. This study aims to estimate the popular Taylor rule models of the exchange rate and apply an alternative measure of forecast performance to the mean square error approach commonly used, in this case forecasts of the direction of change using the Pesaran-Timmermann (1992) test. Although a number of studies have recently found the Taylor rule based model of the exchange rate, initially developed by Engel and West (2006) to be a more successful model at forecasting the exchange rate relative to more standard models, it does not imply that this will also be the case for the directional change forecasts. Unlike earlier studies of the exchange rate which largely failed to outperform the random walk (Meese and Rogoff, 1982), recent studies such as Molodstova and Papell (2009) and Ince (2014) among others have demonstrated that the Taylor rule based model can outperform the random walk in out-of-sample forecasts. This study aims to build on these results by testing whether the model can additionally accurately forecast the direction of change of the exchange rate. Forecasts based on accurately predicting movements in the direction the exchange rate moves could not only be potentially profitable for investors, but can also facilitate greater understanding of exchange rate dynamics for the monetary authorities.

    The use of financial loss functions, such as the Pesaran-Timmermann (PT) test, is particularly relevant when forecasting asset prices, as forecasting the direction in which an asset moves can determine whether the trade is profitable or not, regardless of the performance using the conventional forecast errors. In addition a number of studies such as Leitch and Tanner (1991) have demonstrated that forecasting the direction of change accurately can produce more profits compared to the standard forecasting approaches.

    Forecasts based on directional predictions have been conducted extensively in the literature with differing degrees of success. In general their ability to forecast varies across markets and the modelling approaches used to produce the forecasts, to this extent these results tend to reflect the results from the more conventional forecast error approaches. Studies which have attempted to forecast the direction of change have been conducted for a number of markets and series, including stock prices (Leung et al., 2000; Nyberg, 2011), crude oil prices (Knetsch, 2006), interest rates (Greer, 2003) and GDP (Pons, 2000). There have also been a number of approaches to forecasting the direction of change in exchange rates, including Qi and Wu (2003), although they find that their non-linear approach is not good at forecasting the future exchange rate or its direction. Another approach with exchange rates by Mitchell and Pearce (2007) finds that using forecasts provided by Wall Street Journal Economists can't provide direction of change forecasts that are more accurate than a chance occurrence. The contribution of this study is that it uses a variety of Taylor rule based exchange rate models to forecast directional accuracy, to determine if the recent success from conventional forecasts with these models is also apparent with directional prediction tests.

    Unlike other conventional exchange rate models, the Taylor rule type exchange rate models overcome one of the major shortcomings of traditional exchange rate models which tend to pay too little attention to the market's expectations of future values of the macroeconomic fundamentals (Bacchetta and van Wincoop, 2006; Engel and West, 2005). It reflects how monetary policy is actually conducted or evaluated and offers a different explanation of exchange rate dynamics. In addition we test a number of variations on the conventional Taylor rule model including the addition of asset market effects to the model. The use of the directional accuracy tests is particularly relevant for asset market based models and as far as we know, this is the first time it has been attempted with an exchange rate model which includes asset price measures as explanatory variables.

    The theoretical basis for this study is the linear model of the exchange rate developed by Molodtsova and Papell (2009) among others. In addition, as in Wang et al. (2016), this model can be extended by the inclusion of asset market or wealth effects, including both house and stock prices, to produce a number of different variations on the main model for comparison purposes. The inclusion of asset market measures in the specification is motivated by the increasing importance of capital flows between asset markets, which inevitably influences exchange rates. As Case et al. (2005) suggest, both housing and stock markets have varying degrees of influence on the macro-economy. As with other similar studies using the Taylor rule, the emphasis in this study is on the forecasting performance of this model rather than the estimation of the model1.

    1 Although this is the case in most studies, an exception is Chen et al. (2017), who have used a SVAR and a Taylor rule based model to analyse exchange rate policy, with respect to foreign exchange intervention and capital controls.

    Following the introduction we discuss the Taylor rule exchange rate models used in this study, then outline the Pesaran-Timmermann test. We then analyse the results and finish with some conclusions.


    2. Materials and methods

    The model used for forecasting is an amended Taylor rule model of exchange rate determination, in which the relationship between interest rates and macro fundamentals stems from the central bank's approach to monetary policy2. Monetary based fundamentals are a common approach to modelling the exchange rate (Beckmann et al., 2012), this can involve the monetary model approach as well as a Taylor rule model as is used in this study. According to the Taylor rule, the most basic approach to monetary policy involves setting the interest rate in response to changes in inflation and the output gap. This original specification has been further enhanced by extending the model by incorporating variables representing various asset market or wealth effects on the baseline equation, as used in other studies such as Semmler and Zhang (2007).

    it=πt+δ(πtπt)+γyt+βwt+r (1)

    2 The Taylor rule approach to monetary policy is widely used, including in the countries tested in this study. It allows US variables to be included in all the specifications, in effect acting as a proxy for the impact from the rest of the world, either in a restricted or unrestricted format. However there are many other approaches that could be incorporated into exchange rate modelling such as the issue of global liquidity (Beckmann et al., 2014), current account imbalances (Beckmann et al., 2013) and productivity shocks (Beckmann et al., 2015).

    Where it is the target for the short-term nominal interest rate, πt is the inflation rate, πt is the target level of inflation, yt is the output gap, or percent deviation of actual real GDP from an estimate of its potential level, and r is the equilibrium level of the real interest rate and wt represents the wealth effect.

    Following the approach of Clarida et al. (1998), several modifications which are typically included in the estimation have been included. This includes the real exchange rate in the specification of the foreign country, where it is assumed the central bank targets the level of the exchange rate to ensure long-run PPP holds. Combining the parameters πt and r from equation (1) into one constant term: μ=rδπ, we can derive the following version of the Taylor rule model:

    it=μ+λπt+γyt+βwt+ϕqt (2)

    Where qt is the real exchange rate.

    A lagged interest rate is also incorporated into the Taylor rule to account for the Federal Reserve following the Taylor rule, while responding gradually to changes in the inflation and output gaps. The observable interest rate it follows a partial adjustment to the target rate as follows:

    it=(1ρ)it+ρit1+vt (3)

    Where ρ denotes the extent of interest rate smoothing and vt is the error term also known as the interest rate smoothing shock. Substituting (2) into (3) gives the following equation for the actual short-term interest rate:

    it=(1ρ)(μ+λπt+γyt+βwt+ϕqt)+ρit1+vt (4)

    Taking the U.S. as the benchmark country, equation (4) as the interest rate reaction function for the foreign country, then the monetary policy reaction function for the US would be the same as equation (4) but with ϕ=0.


    2.1. The exchange rate models

    Deriving the Taylor rule based exchange rate model requires generating the implied interest rate differential. Where ~ denotes variables for the foreign country; the interest rate differential is produced by subtracting the Taylor rule equation for the foreign country from that of the domestic country, in this case the US.

    it˜it=ψ+(ψuππtψfπ˜πt)+(ψuyytψfy˜yt)+(ψuwwtψfw˜wt)ψq˜qt+ρuit1ρf˜it1+ηt (5)

    Where u and f are coefficients for the U.S. and the foreign country respectively. ψ is a constant, ψπ=λ(1ρ), ψy=γ(1ρ) and ψw=β(1ρ) for both countries, and ψq=ϕ(1ρ) for the foreign country.

    Finally we assume that the expected rate of exchange rate depreciation is proportional to the interest rate differential:

    E(Δst+1)=β(it˜it) (6)

    Where Δst+1 represents the logarithmic difference of the nominal exchange rate; specified as the price of the home currency in terms of the foreign currency, and E denotes the expectations operator. If we Assume Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP) holds with rational expectations, then β=1, producing the following Taylor rule based exchange rate equation:

    Δst+1=ψ+ψuππtψfπ˜πt+ψuyytψfy˜yt+ψuwwtψfw˜wtψq˜qt+ρuit1ρf˜it1+ηt (7)

    Where st is the natural log of the U.S. nominal exchange rate, defined as the US dollar per unit of foreign currency, meaning a rise in st implies a depreciation of the American dollar. This specification using UIP, follows other similar approaches such as the Dornbusch (1976) overshooting model which provides a link for the monetary policy reaction function to the exchange rate behaviour through UIP. It has also previously been used in other Taylor rule based exchange rate models, such as Jian and Wu (2009) and Molodtsova and Papell (2009).

    The Taylor rule forecasting model has the following form3:

    Δst+1=αm+βmXm,t+ηm,t+1 (8)

    3 The models were also estimated and used for forecasting with lags of the variables included, but this had little effect on the forecasts.

    where Δst+1 is the change in the log of the nominal exchange rate determined as the domestic price of foreign currency. Xm,t is a vector contains different economic variables. A general form of our forecasting model is given by the following equation:

    Δst+1=ααuππt+αfπ˜πtαuyyt+αfy˜ytαuwwt+αfw˜wt+aq˜qtαuiit1+αfi˜it1+ηt (9)

    To produce the forecasts rolling regressions have been conducted with a moving window of 40 quarters (10 years) to produce one quarter ahead forecasts. Covering the time period from 1989Q1 to 2008Q4, forecasts are generated of the exchange rate and this forecast is then compared to the actual data, where the initial estimation period is from1979Q1 to 1988Q4 (except Australia which begins in 1983Q4). Depending on different assumptions regarding the coefficients, including the addition of stock prices and house prices as the wealth effect, there are sixteen models embedded in the above equation, which can be used for forecasting.

    Model 1: asymmetric, with smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X1,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtit1˜it1wt(stock)˜wt(stock)]

    Model 2: asymmetric, with smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X2,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtit1˜it1wt(house)˜wt(house)]

    Model 3: asymmetric, with smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X3,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtit1˜it1wt(s)˜wt(s)]

    Model 4: asymmetric, with smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X4,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtit1˜it1wt(h)˜wt(h)]

    Model 5: Symmetric with smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X5,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytit1˜it1wt(stock)˜wt(stock)]

    Model 6: Symmetric with smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X6,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytit1˜it1wt(house)˜wt(house)]

    Model 7: Symmetric with smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X7,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytit1˜it1wt(s)˜wt(s)]

    Model 8: Symmetric with smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X8,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytit1˜it1wt(h)˜wt(h)]

    Model 9: Asymmetric, no smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X9,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtwt(stock)˜wt(stock)]

    Model 10: Asymmetric, no smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X10,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtwt(house)˜wt(house)]

    Model 11: Asymmetric, no smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X11,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtwt(s)˜wt(s)]

    Model 12: Asymmetric, no smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X12,t[cπt˜πtyt˜yt˜qtwt(h)˜wt(h)]

    Model 13: Symmetric, no smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X13,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytwt(stock)˜wt(stock)]

    Model 14: Symmetric, no smoothing, heterogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X14,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytwt(house)˜wt(house)]

    Model 15: Symmetric, no smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with stock prices

    X15,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytwt(s)˜wt(s)]

    Model 16: Symmetric, no smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with house prices

    X15,t[cπt˜πtyt˜ytwt(house)˜wt(house)]

    2.2. Methodology

    The Pesaran-Timmermann test is a directional prediction test which focuses on correctly forecasting the direction of change in the variables being considered. The null hypothesis is that there is no relationship between actual and predicted directional changes. The procedure is distribution free and based on the proportion of times the direction of change in yt is correctly predicted in the sample, as specified in Pesaran and Timmermann (1992). There are a number of economic theories that suggest predicting directional changes can be effective. As Hong and Chung (2003) point out, one example is the overreaction theory, whereby there are reversals in price movements following an overreaction by the market to a news announcement. With exchange rates the overshooting approach, as developed by Dornbusch (1976) would be an example of when directional change in the exchange rate could potentially be predictable. Similarly with the contagion theory, where adverse movements in one market could cause similar movements in another related market.

    Assuming the following:

    yt: Actual value at time t

    ˆyt: The predictor value of yt based on information available at time t1

    n: Total number of observations in the forecast series

    Set:Yt={1yt>00otherwise,ˆYt={1ˆyt>00otherwiseandZt={1ytˆyt>00otherwise

    Let Py=Pr(yt>0), Pˆy=Pr(ˆyt>0) and ˆP be the proportion of time that the sign of yt is correctly predicted. On the assumption that yt and ˆyt are independently distributed of each other, the number of correct sign predictions has a binominal distribution with n trials and a success probability equal to:

    P=Pr(Zt=1)=Pr(yt˜yt>0)=Pr(yt>0,ˆyt>0)+Pr(yt<0,ˆyt<0)=PyPˆy+(1Py)(1Pˆy)

    Estimating these probabilities with their samples, we have:

    ˆPy=nt=1ytn,ˆPˆy=nt=1ˆytnandˆP=ˆPyˆPˆy+(1ˆPy)(1ˆPˆy)

    Under the null hypothesis that yt and ˆyt are independently distributed, i.e. ˆyt has no power in forecasting yt, the test statistic is:

    PT=ˆPˆP(vˆar(ˆP)vˆar(ˆP))1/2

    Where vˆar(ˆP)=n1ˆP(1ˆP),

    vˆar(ˆP)=n1(2ˆPy1)2ˆPy(1ˆPˆy)+n1(2ˆPˆy1)2ˆPy(1ˆPy)+4n2ˆPyˆPˆy(1ˆPy)(1ˆPˆy)

    Pesaran-Timmermann (1992) have shown that the PT statistics converge to a standard normal distribution. The critical values at 95% and 99% are 1.64 and 2.33 respectively.


    3. Data and Results


    3.1. Data

    The data is all quarterly and consists of the exchange rates returns measured in log-differences, and the standard Taylor rule economic fundamentals for the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden and Australia. Due to data availability, the time period for these countries differs depending on the measure of the wealth effect, which in the case of stock prices representing the wealth effect, the data runs from 1975Q1 to 2008Q4. Whereas when house prices are used, the data runs from 1980Q1 to 2008Q4 (The Australian data is estimated from 1983 quarter 4, reflecting the move to a floating exchange rate in that year). These four countries were selected partly because they have strong housing markets and therefore plentiful housing data and also because the UK, US and Australia have large internationally traded stock markets. As the interest rates approached their zero bounds after the financial crisis, the models are only estimated up to 2008. However a separate set of tests for robustness has been conducted on the shadow interest rate for the UK/US exchange rate to allow a data series to continue past 2008 (until 2015 Q4) and predict exchange rate movements after the financial crisis. The shadow interest rate is estimated and made available by Wu and Xia (2016).

    All variables except interest rates are in logarithms4. The inflation rate is the annual inflation rate calculated using the CPI over the previous 4 quarters and we have used real GDP to measure the level of output. As in other similar studies, the output gap is constructed as the percentage deviation of actual output from a Hodrick Prescott (1997) (HP) generated trend.5 The real foreign/U.S. exchange rate is calculated as the percentage deviation of the nominal exchange rate from a target, which is defined by purchasing power parity (PPP) (i.e., ˜qt=st(ptpt), where pt and pt are natural logarithms for U.S. and foreign price levels, respectively, as measured by respective CPI levels. The money market interest rates are used as a measure of the short-term interest rates. The nominal exchange rate is defined as the U.S. dollar price of foreign currency and is taken as the end-of-month exchange rate.

    4 The data was taken from the International Financial Statistics (IMF), except the exchange rate and main stock market indices which are from Datastream and the house price series from Oxford Economics. Summary statistics of the data are contained in tables A1 to A4 in the appendices and plots in Figure 1.

    Figure 1. Plots of the data.

    5 Quarterly data was used, as the GDP data was not available on a monthly basis.

    Similar studies, such as Molodtsova and Papell (2009) have emphasised the importance of real-time data in the use of Taylor rule-based models for forecasting the exchange rate. Real-time data use vintages of data which are available to researchers at each point in time (i.e., before any revisions to the data are applied). We have followed the approach of Molodtsova and Papell (2009) and used quasi-real time data for the output gap. In this case, current vintage data has been used and the trends at period t were calculated based on observations 1 to t-1.


    4. Discussion


    4.1. Structural breaks

    As Pesaran and Timmermann (2004) and Sinclair et al. (2008) have indicated, the presence of structural breaks can affect forecasts and Beckmann et al. (2011) have emphasised the importance of testing for structural breaks in exchange rate models. To determine if there are structural breaks present and also whether the data is stationary, we have employed the Lee-Strazicich (2003) test for unit roots and structural breaks in the dataset. The Lee-Strazicich (2003) test starts with the assumption that the null hypothesis is a unit root with up to two breaks. Compared to the other ADF-type endogenous break unit root tests, it not only endogenously determines the structural breaks, but the alternative hypothesis also implies the series is trend stationary (Glynn et al., 2007). The ability to permit up to two breaks in the null and two breaks in the level or slope of the alternative make this approach particularly flexible and attractive.

    The results are shown in Table 1. For variables that are expected to grow over time, we allow for a constant and a time trend under the alternative hypothesis. Those series are the stock price and house price. For the exchange rate differences, inflation, interest rate, output gap and real exchange rate, we expect a long-run equilibrium value which does not grow over time and these tests have been specified with a constant but no time trend; Table 1 lists the test results and break points we considered for each of the countries measured at the 95% confidence interval6. In the presence of breaks for these variables, we have re-estimated the models including dummy variables to account for the breaks and ensure the data is stationary.

    Table 1a. One Break Lee Strazicich Test.
    UK Sweden Australian
    variables model t-statistics break date t-statistics break date t-statistics Break date
    Δst+1 A -4.0101* 1980:01 -6.6866* 2001:01 -6.9187* 1985:01
    πt A -5.1396* 1985:02 -6.2031* 1994:03 -5.8468* 2000:01
    yt A -4.1115 1978:04 -6.8584* 2005:02 -5.1151* 1985:02
    ˜qt A -4.0772* 1986:03 -2.9814 1984:04 -3.274** 1985:02
    it1 A -4.5221* 1992:03 -7.1603* 1993:02 -3.5384 1991:01
    wt(house) C -4.8287* 1987:02 -4.8584* 1988:01 -3.9666 1988:01
    wt(stock) C -5.5372* 2002:04 -5.4708* 1982:01 -5.6244* 2005:03
    πt˜πt A -7.5086* 1991:02 -5.8380* 1993:01 -3.7506 2001:02
    yt˜yt A -5.3955* 1983:03 -5.8464* 1992:02 -5.3360* 1982:01
    it1˜it1 A -4.8120* 1992:03 -4.2090* 1993:02 -3.0798 1990:01
    wt˜wt(H) A -5.0372* 2004:01 -4.8003* 1992:01 5.7839* 2005:01
    wt˜wt(S) A -6.9614* 1979:02 -5.6860* 1982:01 -5.0880* 1986:02
    Notes: we only consider breaks if a variable is concluded to be non-stationary in the conventional tests. *, ** denote the unit root is rejected if allowed for 1 structural break at the 5% and 10% significance level.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 1B. One Break Lee Strazicich Test (continued).
    U.S.
    variables model t-statistics break date
    πt A -4.7665* 1982:02
    yt A -5.2147* 2004:03
    it1 A -5.0039* 1980:02
    wt(house) C -6.1388* 2004:02
    wt(stock) C -4.9267* 1982:02
    Notes: *, ** denote the unit root is rejected if allowed for 1 structural break at the 5% and 10% significance level.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    6 We also used the Perron-NG test for a unit root, results available on request. For the real Swedish exchange rate, as it was non-stationary even with two structural breaks, we included it in first-differenced form.

    Most of the break dates can be explained by changes in the exchange rate regime or monetary policies in these countries. For example, For the UK, the first break corresponds with the abandoning of the £M3 target in October 1985. This is part of the MTFS the government announced in March 1980. It was originally aiming to reduce inflation and create conditions for sustainable economic growth. However, with the overshooting of the £M3 target, the UK economy went into a deep recession. The authorities had then successively downgraded its importance and by October 1985, the plan was finally abandoned. The second breaks can be viewed as a result of the UK leaving the ERM7. Sweden has a single break in 1994 Q3, when their economy began recovering after the severe banking crisis in the early 1990s. Australia has a break in 1985 Q2, when Australia adopted a flexible exchange rate. For the US there was a break in 1980 Q2, when the Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve announced a package of measures to strengthen the Dollar.

    7 The European exchange rate mechanism; Within the ERM, Germany was dominant and other countries followed German interest rate policy.


    4.2. Results from the PT test

    Table 2 contains the results over the extended time period using the shadow interest rates and Tables 3 and 4 report the results from our analysis of the predictive power of the exchange rate models for different countries over the standard time period. The column labelled "directional accuracy" shows the percentage of exchange rate changes that were accurately forecast by different models over the one quarter interval. The PT statistics measure the significance in the predictability of the direction of exchange rate changes. Results in general vary with different countries and the different model specifications, in particular whether stock prices or house prices are used as the wealth effect. The standard forecast error tests, using the mean square error (MSE) type statistic have not been included here, as there is a substantial body of literature which has already shown that forecasts from this Taylor rule based model outperform a random walk and the results of conducting the same tests on the models used here mirrored those results8.

    Table 2. Results for the Pesaran-Timmermann (PT) test using USUK with the shadow interest rate.
    Directional Accuracy PT statistic
    Model 1 50.0% -0.1304
    Model 2 42.2% -1.9639
    Model 3 54.7% 0.9757
    Model 4 53.1% 0.6207
    Model 5 54.7% 0.6611
    Model 6 43.8% -1.7218
    Model 7 56.3% 1.2977
    Model 8 53.1% 0.6712
    Model 9 56.3% 1.0973
    Model 10 54.7% 0.7190
    Model 11 60.9% 1.9379*
    Model 12 53.1% 0.6207
    Model 13 62.5% 2.2624*
    Model 14 53.1% 0.4760
    Model 15 64.1% 2.5124*
    Model 16 57.8% 1.5380
    Note: Directional accuracy is the percentage of exchange rate changes that were accurately forecast. * and ** indicates model can correctly forecast the direction of change at the 5% and 1% significance level. The critical values of the PT-test at 95% and 99% are 1.64 and 2.33 respectively.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 3. Non-parametric Statistics for the Pesaran-Timmermann (PT) test.
    UK Sweden Australia
    Directional Accuracy PT statistic Directional Accuracy PT statistic Directional Accuracy PT statistic
    Model 1 58.3% 1.1198 44.4% -1.0934 47.2% -1.1931
    Model 2 58.3% 1.0306 63.9% 1.7889* 55.6% -0.0926
    Model 3 52.8% 0.3912 33.3% -2.1552 47.2% 0.0401
    Model 4 58.3% 1.0725 58.3% 1.1198 47.2% -0.1173
    Model 5 63.9% 1.7889* 44.4% -1.0934 69.4% 2.3371**
    Model 6 61.1% 1.4255 69.4% 2.6186** 55.6% 0.0862
    Model 7 61.1% 1.5597 36.1% -1.7889 52.8% 1.1932
    Model 8 66.7% 2.3047* 63.9% 1.9270* 33.3% -1.8073
    Model 9 55.6% 0.6981 50.0% 0 47.2% -0.1173
    Model 10 58.3% 1.1198 63.8% 1.7889* 63.9% 1.1809
    Model 11 50.0% 0 33.3% -2.2180 50.0% 0.4887
    Model 12 58.3% 1.0725 52.8% 0.3912 44.4% -0.5462
    Model 13 61.1% 1.5597 44.4% -0.6848 61.1% 1.7870*
    Model 14 63.9% 2.0641* 66.7% 2.1704* 58.3% 1.3088
    Model 15 72.2% 3.2660** 33.3% -2.6701 58.3% 1.7371*
    Model 16 63.8% 1.8405* 52.8% 0.4282 30.6% -2.2731
    Note: Directional accuracy is the percentage of exchange rate changes that were accurately forecast. * and ** indicates the model can correctly forecast the direction of change at the 5% and 1% significance level. The critical values of the PT-test at 95% and 99% are 1.64 and 2.33 respectively.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 4. Non-parametric Statistics for the Pesaran-Timmermann (PT) test after incorporating structural breaks.
    UK Sweden Australia
    Directional Accuracy PT statistic Directional Accuracy PT statistic Directional Accuracy PT statistic
    Model 1 47.2% -0.3391 58.3% 1.0725 52.8% 0.2705
    Model 2 63.9% 1.7646* 63.8% 2.0641* 61.1% 0.6375
    Model 3 52.8% 0.3912 33.3% -2.1552 47.2% 0.0401
    Model 4 58.3% 1.0725 58.3% 1.1198 47.2% -0.1173
    Model 5 63.9% 1.7646* 63.9% 1.9270* 69.4% 2.3371**
    Model 6 63.9% 1.7646* 69.4% 2.6186** 58.3% 0.4049
    Model 7 61.1% 1.5597 36.1% -1.7889 52.8% 1.1932
    Model 8 66.7% 2.3047* 63.9% 1.9270* 33.3% -1.8073
    Model 9 47.2% -0.3434 47.2% -0.3525 55.5% 0.8583
    Model 10 58.3% 1.0306 63.8% 1.7889* 50.0% -0.6836
    Model 11 50.0% 0 33.3% -2.2180 50.0% 0.4887
    Model 12 58.3% 1.0725 52.8% 0.3912 44.4% -0.5462
    Model 13 61.1% 1.5597 47.2% -0.3525 61.1% 1.7870*
    Model 14 69.4% 3.0693** 66.7% 2.1704* 55.6% 0.5462
    Model 15 72.2% 3.2660** 33.3% -2.6701 58.3% 1.7371*
    Model 16 63.8% 1.8405* 52.8% 0.4282 30.6% -2.2731
    Note: Directional accuracy is the percentage of exchange rate changes that were accurately forecast. * and ** indicates model can correctly forecast the direction of change at the 5% and 1% significant level. The critical values of the PT-test at 95% and 99% are 1.64 and 2.33 respectively. Dummy variable added for AUS: 85Q2; Dummy variable added for Sweden: 94Q3 and 80Q2; Dummy variable added for UK: 85Q2, 92Q3 and 80Q2.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    8 Results are available on request.

    For the UK and US exchange rates9, the rolling predictions attain the sign of the exchange rate changes correctly in at least 50% of all quarters over the period 2000 to 2008. We have based the selection criteria on the models which perform best simply on the one with the highest percentage of correct predictions. We have in addition provided information on the explanatory power of these models in tables 5 to 7, but as with similar studies we concentrate on the forecast performance rather than the models explanatory powers.

    Table 5. Estimation of Taylor rule exchange rate models for the UK.
    Heterogeneous coefficient Model 1 Model 2 Model 5 Model 6 Model 9 Model 10 Model 13 Model 14
    R-squared 0.262 0.438 0.144 0.193 0.204 0.350 0.087 0.143
    Adj. R-squared 0.168 0.354 0.044 0.081 0.146 0.294 0.029 0.078
    ˆσ 0.047 0.042 0.051 0.050 0.048 0.044 0.051 0.050
    Log likelihood 227.327 209.501 217.459 188.648 224.255 201.063 215.058 185.168
    F-statistic 1.758 5.072* 0.629 0.595 2.787* 4.827* 0.245 3.197*
    Homogenous coefficient Model 3 Model 4 Model 7 Model 8 Model 11 Model 12 Model 15 Model 16
    R-squared 0.142 0.150 0.088 0.049 0.112 0.124 0.058 0.026
    Adj. R-squared 0.109 0.111 0.051 0.015 0.084 0.093 0.037 -0.001
    ˆσ 0.0489 0.049 0.050 0.052 0.049 0.050 0.051 0.052
    Log likelihood 217.252 185.654 213.136 179.223 216.866 183.931 212.933 177.785
    F-statistic 0.142 0.150 0.088 0.049 0.112 0.124 0.058 0.026
    Note: Models are estimated by OLS where standard errors have been Newey-West corrected. Dummies are only included in ones that have structural breaks (i.e. heterogeneous models) ˆσ is the standard error of the regression. F-statistics is the Wald test for coefficient equality restriction. *and **means significance at 5% and 1% significant level, respectively.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 6. Estimation of Taylor rule exchange rate models for the Sweden.
    Heterogeneous coefficient Model 1 Model 2 Model 5 Model 6 Model 9 Model 10 Model 13 Model 14
    R-squared 0.221 0.237 0.221 0.237 0.077 0.144 0.067 0.141
    Adj. R-squared 0.137 0.139 0.144 0.147 0.010 0.071 0.008 0.076
    ˆσ 0.052 0.055 0.052 0.055 0.056 0.057 0.056 0.057
    Log likelihood 215.036 177.938 215.012 177.936 203.584 171.355 202.859 171.121
    F-statistic 0.952 1.355 1.287 1.400 0.732 2.056 1.254 2.171**
    Homogenous coefficient Model 3 Model 4 Model 7 Model 8 Model 11 Model 12 Model 15 Model 16
    R-squared 0.062 0.080 0.043 0.067 0.044 0.048 0.023 0.035
    Adj. R-squared 0.026 0.038 0.013 0.033 0.015 0.014 0.001 0.009
    ˆσ 0.055 0.058 0.056 0.058 0.056 0.059 0.056 0.059
    Log likelihood 200.576 167.184 199.204 166.379 201.249 165.234 199.797 164.443
    F-statistic 0.062 0.080 0.043 0.067 0.044 0.048 0.023 0.035
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 7. Estimation of Taylor rule exchange rate models for the Australia.
    Heterogeneous coefficient Model 1 Model 2 Model 5 Model 6 Model 9 Model 10 Model 13 Model 14
    R-squared 0.112 0.230 0.088 0.146 0.096 0.227 0.076 0.130
    Adj. R-squared 0.048 0.164 0.030 0.082 0.047 0.176 0.032 0.082
    ˆσ 0.0586 0.058 0.059 0.061 0.058 0.057 0.059 0.061
    Log likelihood 195.283 169.545 193.488 163.634 196.059 169.324 194.523 162.569
    F-statistic 1.073 5.423* 1.998** 3.254* 0.353 4.906* 1.735 2.240**
    Homogenous coefficient Model 3 Model 4 Model 7 Model 8 Model 11 Model 12 Model 15 Model 16
    R-squared 0.090 0.039 0.059 0.004 0.089 0.038 0.058 0.004
    Adj. R-squared 0.055 -0.005 0.030 -0.032 0.061 0.004 0.037 -0.022
    ˆσ 0.058 0.064 0.059 0.064 0.058 0.063 0.059 0.064
    Log likelihood 193.664 156.833 191.421 154.782 195.543 156.816 193.320 154.781
    F-statistic 0.090 0.039 0.059 0.004 0.089 0.038 0.058 0.004
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    9 The implied restrictions on the coefficients were tested using Wald tests and models 5 and 13 in the cases of the US/UK exchange rate and Models 9, 10, 13 and 14 in the case of US/Sweden exchange rate the restrictions could not be rejected, so the unrestricted results of these tests have not been reported.

    In table 2 we find that only 3 models predict the directional change when using the shadow interest rate on post-crisis data with model 15 performing best, this is less than the UK/US model for the pre-crisis data suggesting directional change is now less easy to predict in the post-crisis monetary regime for these two countries. In Table 3, again for the UK/US model 15 (symmetric, no smoothing, homogeneous coefficients with stock prices) gives the highest directional prediction accuracy, with 72.2 percent of actual exchange rate changes correctly predicted. The PT test statistics show that only for 5 out of the 14 models, are the predicted changes significantly associated with the actual changes. A common feature shared by the successful results is that they are all symmetric models, without the real exchange rate. For the PT results confirming the directional accuracy, models with significant PT statistics tend to have a higher proportion of successful directional prediction than the others.

    According to the results in Tables 3 and 4, the model which gives the best forecast of directional change for the Sweden/US exchange rate is the symmetric, with smoothing and heterogeneous coefficient model with house prices representing the wealth effect (see Model 6). It gives the highest fraction of successful directional prediction at 66.7% and the PT statistic is well above the 95% critical value for a one sided standard normal test, leading to a strong rejection of the hypothesis that actual and predicted exchange rates are independently distributed. The PT statistics show that 5 models provide evidence of predictive power in exchange rate direction movements. All the best performing Swedish models have house prices representing the wealth effect. Therefore, exchange rate forecasting models incorporating house prices are the most accurate approach to forecasting the direction of exchange rate changes, which reflects the relative importance of housing to the Swedish economy relative to the stock market.

    The difference between the Swedish and the UK/Australian results can be explained by reference to the underlying structure of the Swedish economy. There are several reasons why house prices are more significant than stock prices in explaining the US-Swedish exchange rate. Firstly, Swedish stock market wealth accounts for only a small proportion of the total household financial wealth, as estimated by Chen (2006). This study found that 0.08–0.2% of total financial wealth in Sweden is from the stock market. In contrast, housing wealth takes up a much a larger proportion, again according to Chen (2006), about 50–70% of non-stock wealth originates from housing for the period 1980 to 2004. As housing wealth takes up a large proportion of household asset wealth, changes in house prices will have a more significant impact on consumption and therefore output, as well as a more substantial effect on inflation. Secondly, house prices often indirectly influence consumption through credit loans, as it is often used as collateral. Sweden has a large and liquid housing finance market and its mortgage bond market ranks as the third largest in Europe.

    For the Australian data, the PT test statistics show that only models 5, 13 and 15 have significant statistics and so we reject the null hypothesis for only these three models. Since model 13 is an unrestricted version of model 15, and Model 13 has a higher directional accuracy and PT statistic than model 15, we conclude that symmetric models with heterogenous coefficients and stock prices are better in predicting directional changes for Australia. Table 4 contains the results from including dummy variables in those series where a structural break was found based on the Lee-Stazichich test. Where no structural breaks were found the test statistic is the same as in the previous table. In general there is a slight improvement in the forecasting performance for the UK and Swedish tests in terms of significant forecasts, but no difference for Australia.

    From the above PT test results, we conclude that not all Taylor rule models are effective in predicting the direction of the exchange rate changes. For almost two thirds of the models studied, the direction of exchange rate changes predicted from the Taylor rule models is uncorrelated with the actual directional changes. This mirrors other studies such as Qi and Wu (2003) who found using their model to predict the direction of change of the exchange rate was not successful, although in their case, it also failed to consistently predict the future value of the exchange rate. Among the three countries that have been studied, the PT statistics show that Taylor rule models give the highest predictive power for the UK/US data. Model 15 in general works well for both the UK/US and Australia/US exchange rate predictions. In addition to these forecasts Tables 5, 6 and 7 provide statistical analysis of the estimated models.

    When accounting for the structural breaks in the series by adding dummy variables, there is little evidence that the forecasts have improved substantially. Although there is a slight improvement for the Swedish and UK models, there is no improvement for Australia. Overall there is a lack of significance in most of the results, this could be due to the lack of any predictable overreaction or overshooting in these exchange rates over the recent past. Although it doesn't prove that there is no overshooting, it appears that if there is any it is not predictable using this approach. Similarly with regard to the contagion theory, if there are any adverse movements in the money markets, it doesn't appear to transfer to the foreign exchange markets in a predictable way based on our results.


    5. Conclusion

    Following the success of the Taylor rule model of the exchange rate in out-of-sample forecasting based on the conventional forecast errors measures, we have used the PT test of directional accuracy to determine if this modelling approach produces forecasts that are equally accurate. However the results suggest there is mixed evidence of these models being able to consistently forecast directional change, which is in contrast to other studies using these models with the conventional forecasting approach. This suggests that the ability of a model to forecast future exchange rates doesn't imply it will be able to predict directional change, which can be a more practical way of assessing the profitability of investing in asset markets.

    The main policy implications of these findings relate to both the asset management sector and macroeconomic policy makers. For asset managers being able to predict directional change can be essential for active asset management strategies involving the use of technical trading rules. This in turn is important for the efficient allocation of resources by financial markets. Similarly for macroeconomists attempting to forecast future economic events, these results indicate it is difficult to predict directional changes to the economy, such as following a sudden financial crises.

    However there is evidence that the results are sensitive to the specification of the models used, in particular the measure of wealth used. Some specifications of these models can produce reasonably accurate forecasts and therefore the potential to make a profit by using these forecasts. For instance for Australia and the UK exchange rates, the symmetric model, with no smoothing, homogenous coefficients and stock prices as the wealth effect appears to do better than simple chance, perhaps reflecting the importance of the stock markets in these two countries and the role of capital flows between the UK, Australian and the US asset markets. This suggests that future research could concentrate more on the asset market aspects of these models as well as related issues in terms of global liquidity, current account imbalances and productivity shocks if these forecasts are to be improved.


    Conflict of interest

    The authors declare no conflict of interest in this paper.


    Acknowledgements

    We would like to thank the Editor and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.


    Appendices

    Table A1. UK Summary Statistics.
    UK Δst πt yt wt(s) wt(h) ˜qt it πt˜πt yt˜yt wt˜wt(S) wt˜wt(H) it˜it
    Mean -0.0020 0.0554 0.0014 -0.0007 0.0000 0.5448 7.8901 0.0121 0.0017 0.0000 0.0000 1.5363
    Median 0.0001 0.0355 0.0011 0.0022 -0.0058 0.5429 6.4800 0.0017 0.0019 0.0075 -0.0021 1.3450
    Maximum 0.1499 0.2356 0.0365 0.3119 0.1457 0.8202 17.1300 0.1556 0.0444 0.2094 0.1275 6.9000
    Minimum -0.1626 0.0061 -0.0397 -0.3682 -0.1123 0.1632 0.3100 -0.0266 -0.0424 -0.3730 -0.0743 -6.8600
    Std. Dev. 0.0515 0.0525 0.0142 0.1062 0.0435 0.1174 3.6526 0.0338 0.0164 0.0719 0.0408 2.5450
    Skewness -0.2441 1.5869 0.0770 -0.6472 1.0424 -0.2988 0.5610 2.2832 0.0011 -0.8096 0.6467 -0.2014
    Kurtosis 3.4479 4.8300 3.3284 4.6535 5.1522 3.5694 2.2842 8.6585 3.1107 8.1023 3.7967 3.7781
    Jarque-Bera 2.4872 76.0590 0.7452 24.9882 43.3969 3.8611 10.0363 299.5962 0.0695 162.3822 11.1519 4.3498
    Probability 0.2883 0.0000 0.6889 0.0000 0.0000 0.1451 0.0066 0.0000 0.9659 0.0000 0.0038 0.1136
    Observations 136 136 136 136 116 136 136 136 136 136 116 136
    Note: The descriptive statistics are the log form of the USD/UK exchange rate change, inflation, output gap, stock price index, house price index, real USD/UK exchange rate, interest rate, inflation difference, output gap difference, stock price difference, house price difference and interest rate difference between the US and UK, respectively. All statistics are constructed from quarterly observations running from 1975 to 2008 with definitions listed above. All differentials are measured as the US minus the foreign data.
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table A2. Swedish Summary Statistics.
    Sweden Δst πt yt wt(s) wt(h) ˜qt it πt˜πt yt˜yt wt˜wt(s) wt˜wt(h) it˜it
    Mean 0.0043 0.0498 0.0007 -0.0002 0.0000 1.8920 8.0796 0.0064 0.0010 0.0004 0.0000 1.7257
    Median 0.0022 0.0413 -0.0015 -0.0180 -0.0035 1.9678 8.2550 0.0027 -0.0018 0.0092 -0.0005 1.8650
    Maximum 0.2490 0.1375 0.0491 0.6046 0.1300 2.4230 35.7800 0.0633 0.0560 0.4044 0.1318 32.5200
    Minimum -0.1055 -0.0112 -0.0420 -0.4976 -0.0898 1.1252 1.6200 -0.0427 -0.0361 -0.4953 -0.0839 -4.4000
    Std. Dev. 0.0562 0.0391 0.0162 0.1999 0.0436 0.3349 4.5750 0.0259 0.0188 0.1593 0.0446 3.9932
    Skewness 1.2818 0.4132 0.2540 0.2179 0.6526 -0.7995 1.6046 0.3224 0.6230 -0.0914 0.6087 3.4469
    Kurtosis 6.3521 1.9314 3.8248 3.5877 3.8156 2.5857 10.9428 2.1512 3.3564 3.4175 3.6219 27.2233
    Jarque-Bera 100.9125 10.3420 5.3173 3.0336 11.4499 15.4609 415.8643 6.4377 9.5161 1.1767 9.0322 3594.3290
    Observations 136 136 136 136 116 136 136 136 136 136 116 136
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table A3. Australian Summary Statistics.
    Australia Δst πt yt wt(s) wt(h) ˜qt it πt˜πt yt˜yt wt˜wt(s) wt˜wt(h) it˜it
    Mean -0.0051 0.0556 0.0008 -0.0029 0.0000 -0.3016 8.9820 0.0123 0.0011 -0.0023 0.0000 2.6282
    Median 0.0024 0.0457 -0.0004 -0.0056 -0.0075 -0.2749 7.5050 0.0040 -0.0024 -0.0067 -0.0042 2.2800
    Maximum 0.1144 0.1628 0.0488 0.4281 0.1361 -0.0447 18.3600 0.0840 0.0484 0.2754 0.1258 10.5200
    Minimum -0.3592 -0.0045 -0.0356 -0.3826 -0.0997 -0.6883 4.2400 -0.0344 -0.0421 -0.2396 -0.1115 -5.5500
    Std. Dev. 0.0596 0.0378 0.0172 0.1221 0.0422 0.1589 4.1228 0.0286 0.0194 0.0969 0.0467 3.1550
    Skewness -2.2882 0.5642 0.6566 0.4991 0.7792 -0.5996 0.8022 0.7524 0.4066 0.2575 0.1587 0.2839
    Kurtosis 13.0328 2.4558 3.7480 4.5702 4.2203 2.7014 2.4002 2.5980 2.6956 2.9113 3.2920 3.6431
    Jarque-Bera 689.0707 8.8940 12.9435 19.6176 18.9364 8.6541 16.6250 13.7460 4.2716 1.5475 0.8989 4.1699
    Observations 136 136 136 136 116 136 136 136 136 136 116 136
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table A4. U.S. Summary Statistics.
    US πt yt wt(s) wt(h) it
    Mean 0.0434 -0.0003 -0.0007 0.0000 6.3538
    Median 0.0335 -0.0015 -0.0004 -0.0029 5.5600
    Maximum 0.1355 0.0343 0.2216 0.0558 17.7800
    Minimum 0.0124 -0.0457 -0.3279 -0.1150 0.5100
    Std. Dev. 0.0273 0.0127 0.0989 0.0224 3.5188
    Skewness 1.5636 -0.2275 -0.4570 -0.9688 1.0157
    Kurtosis 4.9019 3.5774 3.7532 9.8068 4.2784
    Jarque-Bera 75.9163 3.0623 7.9491 242.0905 32.6464
    Probability 0.0000 0.2163 0.0188 0.0000 0.0000
    Observations 136 136 136 116 136
     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    [1] Bacchetta P, Wincoop E Van (2006) Can information heterogeneity explain the exchange rate determination puzzle? Am Econ Rev 96: 552–576. doi: 10.1257/aer.96.3.552
    [2] Beckmann J, Belke A, Kuehl M (2011) The Stability of the Dollar-Euro Exchange Rate Determination Equation-A Time-varying Coefficient Approach. Rev World Econ 14: 11–40.
    [3] Beckmann J, Belke A, Dobnik R (2012) Cross-section Dependence and the Monetary Exchange Rate Model-A Panel Analysis. N Am Econ Financ 23: 38–53. doi: 10.1016/j.najef.2011.11.003
    [4] Beckmann J, Belke A, Czudaj R (2013) Current Account and Real Effective Dollar Exchang Rates. Kredit und Kapital 46: 213–232.
    [5] Beckmann J, Belke A, Czudaj R (2014) The Importance of Global Shocks for National Policymakers-Rising Challenges for Sustainable Monetary Policies. The World Econ 37: 1101–1127. doi: 10.1111/twec.12127
    [6] Beckmann J, Belke A, Czudaj R (2015) Productivity Shocks and Real Effective Exchange Rates. Rev Dev Econ 19: 502–515. doi: 10.1111/rode.12165
    [7] Case KE, Quigley JM, Shiller RJ (2005) Comparing wealth effects: the stock market versus the housing market. B E J macroecon 5: 1–34.
    [8] Chen J (2006) Re-evaluating the association between housing wealth and aggregate consumption: new evidence from Sweden. J Hous Econ 15: 321–348. doi: 10.1016/j.jhe.2006.10.004
    [9] Chen C, Yao S, Ou J (2017) Exchange rate dynamics in a Taylor rule framework. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 46: 158–173. doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2016.07.008
    [10] Clarida R, Galı́ J, Gertler M (1998) Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence. Eur Econ Rev 42: 1033–1067. doi: 10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00016-6
    [11] Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics. J Polit Econ 82: 1161–1176.
    [12] Engel C, West KW (2006) Taylor Rules and the Deutschmark-Dollar Real Exchange Rate. J Money Credit Bank 38: 1175–1194. doi: 10.1353/mcb.2006.0070
    [13] Glynn J, Perera N, Verma R (2007) Unit Root Tests and Structural Breaks: A Survey with Applications. Revista de Métodos Cuantitativos para la Economía y la Empresa 3: 63–79.
    [14] Greer M (2003) Directional accuracy tests of long-term interest rate forecasts. Int J Forecast 19: 291–298. doi: 10.1016/S0169-2070(01)00141-8
    [15] Hong Y, Chung J (2003) Are the Directions of Stock Price Changes Predictable? Statistical Theory and Evidence. Cornell University.
    [16] Ince O (2014) Forecasting Exchange Rates Out-of-Sample with Panel Methods and Real-Time Data. J Int Money Finan 43: 1–18. doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2013.12.004
    [17] Jian W, Wu J (2009) The Taylor Rule and Interval Forecast for Exchange Rates. FRB International Finance Discussion Paper 963.
    [18] Knetsch T (2007) Forecasting the price of crude oil via convenience yield predictions. J Forecast 26: 527–549. doi: 10.1002/for.1040
    [19] Lee J, Stazicich M (2003) Minimum Lagrange Multiplier unit root tests with 2 structural breaks. Rev Econ Stat 85: 1082–1089. doi: 10.1162/003465303772815961
    [20] Leitch G, Tanner JE (1991) Economic forecast evaluation: profits versus the conventional error measures. Am Econ Rev 81: 580–590.
    [21] Leung M, Daouk H, Chen A (2000) Forecasting stock indices: A comparison of classification and level estimation models. Int J Forecast 16: 173–190. doi: 10.1016/S0169-2070(99)00048-5
    [22] Meese RA, Rogoff K (1983) Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: Do they fit out of sample? J Int Econ 14: 3–24. doi: 10.1016/0022-1996(83)90017-X
    [23] Molodtsova T, Papell DH (2009) Out-of-Sample Exchange Rate Predictability with Taylor Rule Fundamentals. J Int Econ 77: 167–180. doi: 10.1016/j.jinteco.2008.11.001
    [24] Mitchell K, Pearce D (2007) Professional forecasts of interest rates and exchange rates: Evidence from the Wall Street Journal's panel of Economists. J Macroecon 29: 840–854. doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2005.11.004
    [25] Nyberg H (2011) Forecasting the direction of the US stock market with dynamic binary probit models. Int J Forecast 27: 561–578. doi: 10.1016/j.ijforecast.2010.02.008
    [26] Pesaran MH, Timmermann A (1992) A simple nonparametric test of predictive performance. J Bus Econ Stat 10: 461–465.
    [27] Pesaran H, Timmermann A (2004) How Costly Is It to Ignore Breaks when Forecasting the Direction of a Time Series? Int J Forecast 20: 411–425. doi: 10.1016/S0169-2070(03)00068-2
    [28] Pons J (2000) The accuracy of IMF and OECD forecasts for G7 countries. J Forecast 19: 53–63. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1099-131X(200001)19:1<53::AID-FOR736>3.0.CO;2-J
    [29] Qi M, Wu Y (2003) Non-linear prediction of exchange rates with monetary fundamentals. Int J Forecast 10: 623–640.
    [30] Semmler W, Zhang W (2007) Asset price volatility and monetary policy rules: a dynamic model and empirical evidence. Econ Model 24: 411–430. doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2006.10.001
    [31] Simclair T, Stekler H, Kitzinger L (2008) Directional Forecasts of GDP and Inflation: A Joint Evaluation with an Application to Federal Reserve Predictions. Appl Econ 42: 2289–2297.
    [32] Wang R, Morley B, Ordonez J (2016) The Taylor rule wealth effects and the exchange rate. Rev Int Econ 24: 282–301. doi: 10.1111/roie.12213
    [33] Wu J, Xia F (2016) Measuring the Macroeconomic Impact of Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound. J Money Credit Bank 48: 253–291. doi: 10.1111/jmcb.12300
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Liming Chen, Ziqing Du, Zhihao Hu, Impact of economic policy uncertainty on exchange rate volatility of China, 2020, 32, 15446123, 101266, 10.1016/j.frl.2019.08.014
    2. Yorgos D. Marinakis, Reilly White, Steven T. Walsh, Lotka–Volterra signals in ASEAN currency exchange rates, 2020, 545, 03784371, 123743, 10.1016/j.physa.2019.123743
    3. Panpan Wang, Yishi Li, Sixu Wu, Time-varying Effects of U.S. Economic Policy Uncertainty on Exchange Rate Return and Volatility in China, 2022, 58, 1540-496X, 1807, 10.1080/1540496X.2021.1937114
    4. Waqas Shair, Naveed Ahmad, Muhammad Tayyab, Iqra Ishaq, Effect of Economic Policy Uncertainty on Exchange Rate Volatility in Pakistan, 2023, 12, 2409-9368, 33, 10.61506/01.00075
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2018 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4045) PDF downloads(800) Cited by(4)

Article outline

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog