Research article

The impact of saving rate on economic growth in Asian countries

  • Received: 30 September 2022 Revised: 05 December 2022 Accepted: 08 December 2022 Published: 19 December 2022
  • JEL Codes: O47, E21, R11

  • The success of East Asian countries in economic growth since the 1960s and the rapid development of China's economy in the past four decades have caused debates on whether these countries have found a new path of development and the role of government in economic growth. The present study investigates whether orthodox growth theories can explain East Asian growth by examining the impact of saving rates on economic growth in Asian countries. Using panel data analysis based on a dataset of 46 Asian countries and regions during the period 1969–2021, we find that gross domestic saving rate, GDP per capita, and urban population growth rate all significantly impact the annual GDP growth rates of Asian countries. The positive effect of the gross saving rate is very significant in the period 1960–1990 but insignificant in 1991–2021, while the positive impact of the urban population growth rate is more significant in the period 1991–2021 than in 1960–1990, and GDP per capita has a very significant negative effect during both 1960–1990 and 1991–2021. We further find that the saving rate has a very significant positive impact on economic growth in East and South Asian countries during 1960–2021. GDP per capita has a significant negative impact in East, South, Southeast, and West Asian countries; the urban population growth has a significant positive impact on GDP growth in East and West Asian countries during 1960–2021. The saving rate has a very significant positive impact on GDP growth in high-income countries, a significant positive impact in upper-middle-income countries, and an insignificant impact in lower-middle-income countries. Our present results show that a high saving rate is one of the critical factors for rapid economic growth in developing countries. Urban population growth and GDP per capita also have significant impacts on economic growth.

    Citation: Mei Liu, Qing-Ping Ma. The impact of saving rate on economic growth in Asian countries[J]. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(4): 412-427. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022023

    Related Papers:

  • The success of East Asian countries in economic growth since the 1960s and the rapid development of China's economy in the past four decades have caused debates on whether these countries have found a new path of development and the role of government in economic growth. The present study investigates whether orthodox growth theories can explain East Asian growth by examining the impact of saving rates on economic growth in Asian countries. Using panel data analysis based on a dataset of 46 Asian countries and regions during the period 1969–2021, we find that gross domestic saving rate, GDP per capita, and urban population growth rate all significantly impact the annual GDP growth rates of Asian countries. The positive effect of the gross saving rate is very significant in the period 1960–1990 but insignificant in 1991–2021, while the positive impact of the urban population growth rate is more significant in the period 1991–2021 than in 1960–1990, and GDP per capita has a very significant negative effect during both 1960–1990 and 1991–2021. We further find that the saving rate has a very significant positive impact on economic growth in East and South Asian countries during 1960–2021. GDP per capita has a significant negative impact in East, South, Southeast, and West Asian countries; the urban population growth has a significant positive impact on GDP growth in East and West Asian countries during 1960–2021. The saving rate has a very significant positive impact on GDP growth in high-income countries, a significant positive impact in upper-middle-income countries, and an insignificant impact in lower-middle-income countries. Our present results show that a high saving rate is one of the critical factors for rapid economic growth in developing countries. Urban population growth and GDP per capita also have significant impacts on economic growth.



    加载中


    [1] Aghion P, Comin D, Howitt P, et al. (2016) When does domestic savings matter for economic growth? IMF Econ Rev 64: 381–407. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2015.41 doi: 10.1057/imfer.2015.41
    [2] Agrawal P (2001) The relation between savings and growth: cointegration and causality evidence from Asia. Appl Econ 33: 499–513. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840122210 doi: 10.1080/00036840122210
    [3] Ahluwalia MS (2002) Economic reforms in India since 1991: Has gradualism worked? J Econ Perspect 16: 67–88. https://doi.org/10.1257/089533002760278721 doi: 10.1257/089533002760278721
    [4] Arestis P, Glickman M (2002) Financial crisis in Southeast Asia: dispelling illusion the Minskyan way. Camb J Econ 26: 237–260. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/26.2.237 doi: 10.1093/cje/26.2.237
    [5] Bertinelli L, Black D (2004) Urbanization and growth. J Urban Econ 56: 80–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2004.03.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jue.2004.03.003
    [6] Bloom DE, Canning D, Fink G (2008) Urbanization and the Wealth of Nations. Science 319: 772–775. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1153057 doi: 10.1126/science.1153057
    [7] Campbell JY (1987) Does Saving Anticipate Declining Labor Income? An Alternative Test of the Permanent Income Hypothesis. Econometrica 55: 1249–1273. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1805 doi: 10.3386/w1805
    [8] Carroll CD, Summers LH (1991) Consumption growth parallels income growth: Some new evidence. In: Bernheim, B.D., Shoven, J.B., National saving and economic performance, Chicago: Chicago University Press, 305–348. https://doi.org/10.3386/w3090
    [9] Carroll CD, Weil DN (1994) Saving and growth: a reinterpretation. Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy 40: 133–192. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(94)90006-X
    [10] Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Rev Econ Stud 32: 233–240. https://doi.org/10.2307/2295827 doi: 10.2307/2295827
    [11] Chow GC (1997) Challenges of China's economic system for economic theory. Am Econ Rev 87: 321–327.
    [12] Chow GC, Li KW (2002) China's economic growth: 1952–2010. Econ Dev Cult Change 51: 247–256. https://doi.org/10.1086/344158 doi: 10.1086/344158
    [13] Deaton AS, Paxson C (1994) Saving, growth, and aging in Taiwan. In: Wise, D.A., Studies in the Economics of Aging, University of Chicago Press, 331–362.
    [14] Domar ED (1946) Capital expansion, rate of growth, and employment. Econometrica 14: 137–147. https://doi.org/10.2307/1905364 doi: 10.2307/1905364
    [15] Friedman M (1957) A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9780691188485
    [16] Halper S (2010) The Beijing consensus: how China's authoritarian model will dominate the twenty-first century: ReadHowYouWant. com.
    [17] Harrod RF (1939) An essay in dynamic theory. The Economic Journal 49: 14–33.
    [18] Huang Y (2008) Capitalism with Chinese characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [19] Huang Y (2010) Debating China's economic growth: The Beijing consensus or the Washington consensus. Acad Manag Perspect 24: 31–47.
    [20] Jangili R (2011) Causal relationship between saving, investment and economic growth for India—what does the relation imply? Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/40002/1/MPRA_paper_40002.pdf.
    [21] Koopmans TC (1969) Objectives, constraints, and outcomes in optimal growth models, In: Fox K. A., Sengupta, J., Narasimham, G.V.L., Economic Models, Estimation and Risk Programming: Essays in Honor of Gerhard Tintner, Heidelberg: Springer, 110–132. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-46198-9_7
    [22] Krugman P (1994) The myth of Asia's miracle. Foreign Aff 73: 62–78.
    [23] Levine R, Renelt D (1992) A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. Am Econ Rev 82: 942–963.
    [24] Lewis WA (1954) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. Manch Sch 22: 139–191. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.tb00021.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.tb00021.x
    [25] Lin Y (2016) It is not feasible to copy the western mainstream economic theory. QiuShi 20: 57–59.
    [26] Ma QP (2017) Contribution of interest rate control to China's economic development. J Chinese Econ Bus Stud 15: 325–352. https://doi.org/10.1080/14765284.2017.1342057 doi: 10.1080/14765284.2017.1342057
    [27] Ma QP (2019) What drives China's economy: economic, socio-political, historical and cultural factors. London: Routledge.
    [28] Ma QP (2020) The China Miracle in a technological and socio-political framework—The role of institutions. J Chinese Econ Bus Stud 18: 253–272. https://doi.org/10.1080/14765284.2020.1823146 doi: 10.1080/14765284.2020.1823146
    [29] Mason A (1988) Saving, economic growth, and demographic change. Popul Dev Rev 14: 113–144. https://doi.org/10.2307/1972502 doi: 10.2307/1972502
    [30] Modigliani F (1970) The life cycle hypothesis of saving and intercountry differences in the saving ratio, In: Eltis, W.A., Scott, M.F.G., Wolfe, J.N., Induction, Growth, and Trade, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 197–225
    [31] Modigliani F, Brumberg R (1954) Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of cross-section data. In: Kurihara, K.K., Post-Keynesian Economics, New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, 388–436.
    [32] Nguyen HM, Nguyen LD (2018) The relationship between urbanization and economic growth: An empirical study on ASEAN countries. Int J Soc Econ 45: 316–339. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSE-12-2016-0358 doi: 10.1108/IJSE-12-2016-0358
    [33] Ortmann S (2013) The "Beijing consensus" and the "Singapore model": unmasking the myth of an alternative authoritarian state-capitalist model, In: Li, J., Wang, L., China's Economic Dynamics: A Beijing Consensus in the Making? Routledge, 97–120.
    [34] Pomfret R (2012) Central Asia after two decades of independence, In: Roland, G., Economies in Transition, Springer, 400–429.
    [35] Ramo JC (2004) The Beijing Consensus. London: Foreign Policy Centre.
    [36] Ramsey FP (1928) A Mathematical Theory of Saving. Econ J 38: 543–559. https://doi.org/10.2307/2224098 doi: 10.2307/2224098
    [37] Singh T (2010) Does domestic saving cause economic growth? A time-series evidence from India. J Policy Model 32: 231–253. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2009.08.008 doi: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2009.08.008
    [38] Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70: 65–94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513 doi: 10.2307/1884513
    [39] Spechler MC (2008) The economies of Central Asia: A survey. Comp Econ Stud 50: 30–52.
    [40] Swan TW (1956) Economic growth and capital accumulation. Econ Rec 32: 334–361. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.1956.tb00434.x doi: 10.1111/j.1475-4932.1956.tb00434.x
    [41] Wang Y, Yao Y (2003) Source of China's Economic Growth, 1952—1999: Incorporating Human Capital Accumulation. China Econ Rev 14: 32–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1043-951X(02)00084-6 doi: 10.1016/S1043-951X(02)00084-6
    [42] Williamson J (2000) What should the World Bank think about the Washington Consensus? World Bank Res Obs 15: 251–264.
    [43] Woo WT (1999) The real reasons for China's growth. China J 41: 115–137. https://doi.org/10.2307/2667589 doi: 10.2307/2667589
    [44] World Bank (2022) World Development Indicators.
    [45] Zhang W (2006) The allure of the Chinese model. International Herald Tribune.
  • NAR-04-04-023-s001.pdf
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3949) PDF downloads(256) Cited by(4)

Article outline

Figures and Tables

Tables(7)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog