Research article

An evaluation of quantitative easing effectiveness based on out-of-sample forecasts

  • Received: 23 August 2022 Revised: 17 October 2022 Accepted: 27 October 2022 Published: 04 November 2022
  • JEL Codes: E44, E47, E58

  • A line of defense of quantitative easing (QE) policies has been developed around empirical evidence that time series models do not predict long-term asset prices and yields as well as naive random walk forecasts, implying that predictions of price reversals cannot be profitable and, therefore, that QE effects are not reversed. However, in this work we present evidence that for the Eurozone, Sweden, and the UK, which have pursued QE interventions, a random walk does not beat a Markov switching regimes model in out-of-sample forecasting and, at the same time, the switching process provides additional information regarding the likelihood of price reversals, thus inducing market participants to offset the effects of QE interventions whenever they perceive unconventional monetary policy regimes as temporary.

    Citation: Dimitris G. Kirikos. An evaluation of quantitative easing effectiveness based on out-of-sample forecasts[J]. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(4): 378-389. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022021

    Related Papers:

    [1] Fausto Corradin, Monica Billio, Roberto Casarin . Forecasting Economic Indicators with Robust Factor Models. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(2): 167-190. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022010
    [2] Basma Ben Néfissa, Faouzi Jilani . Impact of the mandatory adoption of IFRS on the quality of financial forecasts. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 95-109. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020006
    [3] Aleksandar Vasilev . A progressive capital income tax — a bad idea, or just a useless idea? Lessons for Bulgaria (1999-2018). National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(4): 402-411. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020024
    [4] Olha Kravchenko, Nadiia Bohomolova, Oksana Karpenko, Maryna Savchenko, Nataliia Bondar . Scenario-based financial planning: the case of Ukrainian railways. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(3): 217-248. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020013
    [5] Serhii Shvets . Public investment as a growth driver for a commodity-exporting economy: Sizing up the fiscal-monetary involvement. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 95-115. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024005
    [6] Menghua Huang, Yingxue Ren, Xu Wang, Xinzhe Li, Li Li . What affects the use of smartphones by the elderly? A hybrid survey from China. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(3): 245-260. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023015
    [7] Goshu Desalegn, Anita Tangl . Forecasting green financial innovation and its implications for financial performance in Ethiopian Financial Institutions: Evidence from ARIMA and ARDL model. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(2): 95-111. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022006
    [8] Evgenii Lukin, Ekaterina Leonidova, Elena Shirokova, Nikita Rumyantsev, Maksim Sidorov . Russian economy under sanctions (Case of the northwest of Russia). National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(2): 145-158. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023009
    [9] Liming Chen, Zhi Zhang, Fangyuan Chen, Na Zhou . A study on the relationship between economic growth and energy consumption under the new normal. National Accounting Review, 2019, 1(1): 28-41. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2019.1.28
    [10] Guido Ferrari, José Mondéjar Jiménez, Yanyun Zhao . The statistical information for tourism economics. The National Accounts perspective. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(2): 204-217. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022012
  • A line of defense of quantitative easing (QE) policies has been developed around empirical evidence that time series models do not predict long-term asset prices and yields as well as naive random walk forecasts, implying that predictions of price reversals cannot be profitable and, therefore, that QE effects are not reversed. However, in this work we present evidence that for the Eurozone, Sweden, and the UK, which have pursued QE interventions, a random walk does not beat a Markov switching regimes model in out-of-sample forecasting and, at the same time, the switching process provides additional information regarding the likelihood of price reversals, thus inducing market participants to offset the effects of QE interventions whenever they perceive unconventional monetary policy regimes as temporary.



    The extensive and rather persistent use of unconventional monetary policies in the aftermath of the great financial crisis of 2008 has now offered adequate data to help us assess the efficacy of new tools that have been employed in a liquidity trap environment with nominal policy rates close to the zero lower bound. The main unconventional tool used in this setting has been the purchase of both long-term public sector assets and corporate bonds, also known as quantitative easing (QE), and the relevant purchases are reflected in increases in central bank assets and the monetary base.

    The case for QE is based on a portfolio balance effect and a signaling effect (Bernanke, 2020). The portfolio balance effect works through the elimination of the duration risk of long-term sovereign bonds, thus inducing market participants to bid up the prices of similar assets, while the signaling effect works through its impact on expected short-term interest rates. The latter results from the commitment to low policy rates inferred from central bank announcements regarding the extent and the time length of asset purchases. Then, an important policy question is whether these effects are lasting or transitory, since both cases are theoretically possible. For example, in the preferred-habitat model of Vayanos and Vila (2009) asset demand shocks generate lasting portfolio effects when investors exhibit preferences for assets with specific maturities. However, in the intertemporal approach of Eggertsson and Woodford (2003) expansions of the monetary base through QE purchases have only a transitory effect on asset yields and aggregate expenditure. In recent research, Cebula and Rossi (2022) showed that QE influences macroeconomic stability conditions and has a considerable impact on the size of discretionary policy multipliers in the context of an IS-LM model. Also, the theoretical importance of QE is verified in Bhattarai and Neely (2022), who suggest that unconventional policies seem appropriate only in exceptional circumstances like liquidity trap conditions.

    On the empirical side, one line of arguments in favor of QE was based on event studies which explored the reaction of asset prices and yields in short periods around QE announcements by central banks. For example, Gagnon et al. (2011) found considerable effects on 10-year T-bonds from the first round of asset purchases by the Fed (QE1), over the period 2008–2010, while the limited reaction of bond yields to subsequent rounds of QE has been attributed to anticipation of new asset purchases which appears to have been taken into account in advance of the respective official QE announcements (e.g., Gagnon, 2018). Also, Cahill et al. (2013) presented evidence that portfolio balance effects operate when there is a discrepancy between the actual and the expected allocation of QE purchases among different assets, leading to substantial changes in relative asset prices, that is, lower prices and higher yields for those assets whose purchase shares turn out to be lower than expected.

    Nevertheless, other studies (e.g., Greenlaw et al., 2018; Wright, 2012) have reported evidence that the effects of QE policies on long-term yields are rather short-lived and smaller than what they initially appeared to be, thus making such interventions less likely to have a substantial impact on aggregate demand. A counterargument to these findings was developed around the claim that if price and yield changes are short-lived then market participants should be able to form profitable strategies by betting on such reversals. In that vein, Neely (2022) found that a vector autoregression does not forecast asset prices out of sample as well as a naive model and, therefore, inferred that there are no exploitable profit opportunities since changes in asset prices and yields after unconventional monetary interventions appear to be persistent.

    Following this line of research, in this work we compare the out-of-sample forecasting performance of a model that accounts for price reversals to that of a naive random walk process. In particular, we use a Markov switching regimes stochastic representation with unobserved states to produce one- to six-month out-of-sample forecasts of long-term (10-year) sovereign bond yields for European areas and countries which have pursued QE policies over the last decade, namely the Eurozone, Sweden, and the UK. We estimate the model on monthly data which cover the period from January 2008 to September 2021, extracted from the OECD statistical database (stats.oecd.org), and the generated forecasts are compared to those of a random walk with drift by means of their root mean squared error (RMSE). We find that the Markov process gives equally good forecasts to those of a naive model, in all cases, and, given the additional information conveyed by the Markov representation regarding the probability of regime shifts, we can infer that there are instances in which agents perceive policy regimes as temporary, thus reversing the impact of QE purchases and limiting the effectiveness of unconventional monetary interventions.

    The choice of a Markov switching regimes process with unobserved states to describe the dynamics of long-term bond yields, under QE interventions, has the advantage that the dates of the switch are not prespecified, but we allow the data to tell us if and when such switches occur. Indeed, the state variable, associated with policy regimes, is considered to be unobserved and governed by a Markov chain which makes it possible to derive the probability that the process is in a particular state at any point in time, using information either up to that date or from the full sample of observations.1

    1The probability of a particular regime, based on information up to a particular date, is known as filter probability, while the probability based on information drawn from the full sample is referred to as smoothed probability.

    Thus, these probabilities reflect the perceptions of market participants regarding the likelihood of policy changes and this information is crucial in forming market stances. In other words, if out-of-sample Markov forecasts are at least as good as naive predictions and the probabilistic inferences about the state of the process imply frequent regime shifts, then agents can use the additional information conveyed by the switching model to try to beat the market, thus offsetting the intended changes in asset prices and yields. Also, another reason for choosing the Markov representation for long-term yields is that it appears to capture the dynamics implied by the observed changes in the monetary base (the instrument of unconventional monetary policy) in countries which actively pursued QE after 2008 (see Kirikos, 2020, 2021).

    The generation of out-of-sample forecasts is discussed in the next section and then, in the third section, we report the RMSEs of forecasts as well as the additional information extracted from the Markov process in terms of probabilistic inferences regarding the state of the process at any time. The final section contains concluding remarks.

    Naive forecasts will be based on a random walk with drift. Specifically, under a random walk with drift, the yield of an asset, say yt, will have the representation:

    yt=d+yt1+εt (1)

    where d is the drift and εt is a white noise error term. Then, the time-t forecast of yt+k will be:

    ˆyt+k|t=yt+kˉd (2)

    where ˆy denotes forecast of y and ˉd=1t1t1i=1(yi+1yi).

    An alternative stochastic representation that allows for yield (and asset price) reversals is the following:

    yt=μzt+yt1+ωt,ωtN(0,σ2zt) (3)

    where ωt is a normally distributed error term, zt is a state variable that cannot be observed and takes on the values 1 or 2, that is, the change in y is expected to be either μ1 or μ2 depending on the state of the process, and the variance differs across regimes. Since the state variable is unobserved, the regime must be inferred probabilistically on the basis of information conveyed by the data, and this requires the specification of a law of motion for zt. The latter will be taken to be an irreducible Markov chain with transition probabilities πij=Pr(zt=j|zt1=i), i=1,2, j=1,2, and stationary probability matrix:

    Π=[π11π12π21π22] (4)

    Estimation of the parameters (μ1, μ2, π11, π22, σ21, σ22) of the Markov switching regimes model through the EM algorithm (see Hamilton, 1990, 1993) requires that the series be stationary, which, as we shall see in a following section, is true for the first differences of sovereign bond yields. Therefore, the process in Equation (3) can be rewritten as:

    Δyt=ytyt1=μzt+ωt (5)

    and the period-t forecast of Δyt+k is:

    Δˆyt+k|t=E(Δyt+k|It)=pΠkμz (6)

    where the information set It includes all data up to time t, p=[Pr(zt=1|It)Pr(zt=2|It)] is the vector of filter inferences about the state of the process at period t, Π is the transition probability matrix, k is the forecast horizon, and μz=[μ1μ2] is the vector of state means.

    Forecasts given by Equation (6) are non-linear since the filter probabilities in the vector p are non-linear functions of the data and so are the Markov model parameters. Also, k-period-ahead forecasts of the level of the series y, as of time t, are taken as:

    ˆyt+k|t=yt+ki=1Δˆyt+i|t (7)

    For all models, out-of-sample forecasts are computed through rolling estimation of the stochastic processes. That is, we start estimation with a sub-sample of size m and compute the k-period-ahead out-of-sample forecast, and then the models are re-estimated using the sub-sample m+1 by adding the next available observation of the series and take a new k-period-ahead forecast. This recursive estimation goes on until the size of the sub-sample becomes Tk, where T is the full sample size, and this procedure generates Tmk+1 out-of-sample forecasts, where m is the initial sub-sample and k is the forecast horizon. Thus, the root mean squared error (RMSE)2 of these forecasts is:

    2It should be noted that the relative forecasting performance of the models, reported in the next section, does not change when the Mean Absolute Error (MAE) of forecasts is used instead of the RMSE.

    RMSE=1Tmk+1Tmkj=0(ˆym+j+k|m+jym+j+k)2 (8)

    Apparently, if the Markov model predicts asset yields out of sample as well as a naive model, that is, the RMSE of its forecasts is not higher than that of simple forecasts, then agents could use the inference on regime switches to bet on asset price reversals, thus rendering the effects of QE short-lived. In other words, a good forecasting performance of the switching regimes process suggests that QE effects are perceived as transitory and, therefore, the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policy is rather limited.

    Monthly data on the yields of 10-year sovereign bonds of Eurozone, Sweden, and UK are drawn from the Main Economic Indicators dataset of the OECD database (stats.oecd.org) and cover the period from January 2008 until September 2021 (165 observations). These countries have been selected because their monetary authorities pursued QE policies in the aftermath of the great financial crisis of 2008, mainly through the purchase of long-term government bonds, and the summary statistics of the yield series (measured in percentages) are given in Table 1 both for the levels and for their first differences (change).

    Table 1.  Summary statistics.
    10-year government bond yield (percentage) Mean Standard Deviation Maximum Minimum Observations
    Level Change Level Change Level Change Level Change Level Change
    Eurozone 2.21 −0.02 1.52 0.19 4.81 0.54 −0.09 −0.59 165 164
    Sweden 1.52 −0.02 1.28 0.16 4.43 0.41 −0.29 −0.67 165 164
    UK 2.16 −0.02 1.24 0.17 5.21 0.36 0.21 −0.63 165 164
    Notes: Monthly data from January 2008 to September 2021, drawn from the OECD statistical database (Main Economic Indicators).

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Since estimation of the Markov process must be based on stationary series, we conducted some preliminary tests regarding the presence of unit roots in long-term government bond yields. The results of the KPSS test (see Kwiatkowski et al., 1992) for testing the null hypothesis that a series is stationary are reported in Table 2 and reveal that the stationarity is rejected for the levels of the series but not for their first differences. Therefore, the following Markov forecasts are based on estimates derived from the differenced series.

    Table 2.  KPSS test of the null hypothesis of stationarity.
    10-year government bond yield (percentage) Levels First differences
    Eurozone 1.506 0.046 *
    Sweden 1.479 0.094 *
    UK 1.437 0.070 *
    Notes: Monthly data. The critical value at the 5% significance level is 0.463 when a trend is not included. A * shows significance of the null.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Initial estimates of the models are based on data up to December 2018 and over periods in which the corresponding central banks pursued QE asset purchases, that is, from January 2015 for the Eurozone (48 observations),3 January 2012 for Sweden (84 observations), and March 2009 for the UK (118 observations). Out-of-sample forecasts from 1 to 6 months ahead are computed through rolling estimation over the post-sample period so that the final forecast, for all forecast horizons, corresponds to September 2021.4 The RMSE of forecasts for the post-sample period January 2019 to September 2021 are given in Table 3.

    3In fact, the European Central Bank began QE operations in 2014, but a formal decision was announced in early 2015.

    4Thus, when the post-sample period is January 2019 to September 2021, there are 33 one-month, 32 two-month, 31 three-month, 30 four-month, 29 five-month, and 28 six-month out-of-sample forecasts.

    Table 3.  RMSE of out-of-sample forecasts of 10-year sovereign bond yields. Post-sample period January 2019 to September 2021.
    Country Model Forecast horizon (months)
    1 2 3 4 5 6
    Eurozone RW 0.1318 0.2273 0.2998 0.3553 0.4075 0.4590
    Markov 0.1309 0.2257 0.2978 0.3532 0.4053 0.4566
    Sweden RW 0.1001 0.1646 0.2186 0.2622 0.2972 0.3198
    Markov 0.0966 0.1597 0.2117 0.2531 0.2855 0.3044
    UK RW 0.1111 0.1872 0.2527 0.3060 0.3488 0.3828
    Markov 0.1056 0.1802 0.2449 0.2998 0.3440 0.3759
    Notes: RW denotes a random walk with drift, and Markov denotes the Markov switching regimes process. Initial sub-samples: January 2015 to December 2018 for the Eurozone, January 2012 to December 2018 for Sweden, and March 2009 to December 2018 for the UK.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    To compare the models more easily, in terms of their forecasting performance, we depict the RMSEs of different processes in the following graphs (Figure 1a1c) for the post-sample period from January 2019 until September 2021. Apparently, the graphs reveal that, in all cases considered, naive forecasts are not better than Markov forecasts, and this makes the Markov switching process more useful since it provides additional information regarding the likelihood of a regime change. That is, if there are regime shifts and agents can predict them, then they can form short-run profitable strategies by betting on yield and price reversals that offset the effects of central bank intervention through quantitative easing. These actions, whenever possible, reduce the effectiveness of QE policies making it only temporary.

    Figure 1.  RMSE of out-of-sample forecasts of 10-year sovereign bond yields. Post-sample: January 2019 to September 2021.

    However, before we conclude on the advantages of the switching regimes process in forecasting bond yields out of sample, we must test the presence of Markovian dynamics, and this can be carried out by means of Wald tests of the presence of different regimes and different means across them. More specifically, the existence of different states can be tested through the null hypothesis Ho: π11=1π22, which implies that going to a particular state does not depend on the previous state, that is, the Markov property does not hold. In addition, if the Markov property is verified, a similar test of the null hypothesis Ho: μ1=μ2 can tell us whether the expected change in yields is different across regimes. Thus, if these null hypotheses are not rejected, then there is no superiority in the Markov process relative to a naive model and, therefore, QE could have long-term effects on the grounds of yield unpredictability. To conduct the tests, we estimated the Markov process via the EM algorithm, over the full period of QE interventions of each central bank, and the parameter estimates are reported in Table 4.

    Table 4.  Estimates of Markov switching parameters for 10-year sovereign bond yields.
    parameter Eurozone sample 1/2014 – 9/2021 Sweden sample 1/2012 – 9/2021 UK sample 3/2009 – 9/2021
    μ1 0.061 (0.054) 0.064 (0.041) 0.087 (0.052)
    μ2 −0.121 (0.019) −0.113 (0.024) −0.102 (0.038)
    σ21 0.024 (0.006) 0.014 (0.005) 0.013 (0.004)
    σ22 0.007 (0.002) 0.007 (0.002) 0.014 (0.003)
    π11 0.782 (0.185) 0.800 (0.149) 0.757 (0.148)
    π22 0.793 (0.105) 0.725 (0.090) 0.793 (0.100)
    Note: Numbers in parentheses below the estimated parameters are standard errors.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The Wald test statistics of the null hypotheses Ho: π11=1π22 and Ho: μ1=μ2 are respectively:

    (ˆπ11+ˆπ221)2var(ˆπ11)+var(ˆπ22)+2cov(ˆπ11,ˆπ22)χ21 (9)
    (ˆμ1ˆμ2)2var(ˆμ1)+var(ˆμ2)2cov(ˆμ1,ˆμ2)χ21 (10)

    where a ^ over a parameter denotes the relevant estimate through the EM algorithm. The values of these statistics and their significance levels are reported in Table 5, for the periods over which each central bank has implemented QE purchases. Obviously, the Markov property is not rejected for the Eurozone, Sweden, and the UK which also appear to have statistically significant differences in the mean yield change across regimes. Thus, for these European areas and countries the predictability of regime shifts and of the ensuing long-term sovereign bond yield changes suggest that the effects of QE interventions are rather transitory.

    Table 5.  Wald tests of Markovian dynamics.
    Period of QE implementation (sample) Ho: π11=1π22 Ho: μ1=μ2
    Eurozone 1/2014 – 9/2021 5.107 (0.024) * 13.443 (0.000) *
    Sweden 1/2012 – 9/2021 7.859 (0.005) * 26.520 (0.000) *
    UK 3/2009 – 9/2021 16.851 (0.000) * 38.426 (0.000) *
    Notes: In the columns of the null hypotheses, the first number is the Wald statistic (χ21) and the number in parenthesis is the corresponding p-value. A * indicates rejection of the null at the 5% significance level, that is, non-rejection of the Markov property.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    An additional advantage of the Markov switching process is that it provides information on agents' perceptions regarding the state of policy regime. This information is derived from the full sample of observations through the so-called smoothed probabilities that the process is in a particular state at time t, that is, the conditional probabilities Pr(zt=i|y1,y2,,yr), where i=1,2 and T is the full sample. These probabilities are easily derived as a by-product of the estimation through the EM algorithm. Thus, assuming that agents perceive a particular regime of yield changes, say regime i, whenever Pr(zt=i|y1,y2,,yr)>1/2, then our estimates show that agents have inferred multiple regime shifts using the largest available set of information.

    Indeed, in the case of the Eurozone, estimation of the Markov process for the period after January 2014 and up to September 2021, over which the European Central Bank pursued expansionary monetary policy and actively engaged in QE policies, the smoothed probability of the state of decreasing bond yields, depicted in Figure 2a along with the yield of euro sovereign bonds, shows that the process captures very well the periods of falling bond yields (i.e. when the smoothed probability is greater than ½) which coincide with periods of QE interventions. At the same time, the estimated smoothed probabilities reveal that agents expected changes in policy as the process appears to have switched between states 10 times, over the period of QE purchases 2014–2021.

    Figure 2.  Smoothed probabilities of decreasing 10-year sovereign bond yields.

    Similarly, estimation of the switching process for Sweden and the UK, using the QE periods January 2012 to September 2021 and March 2009 to September 2021, respectively, produced the smoothed inferences depicted in Figure 2b and 2c. These conditional probabilities show that the model identifies the turning points of Swedish and British long-term bond yield series remarkably well and suggests that agents have not perceived the monetary expansion through QE as permanent since the processes have often switched between increasing and decreasing yield states. Indeed, starting in 2012 the Riksbank has acquired Swedish government bonds totaling SEK 373 billion in September 2021, while the Bank of England has purchased UK government bonds amounting to £875 billion between March 2009 and November 2020. However, these programs have not eliminated interim periods of falling asset prices and rising yields which reverse the effects on long-term interest rates sought by QE policies.

    The claim that QE policies have persistent effects on long-term interest rates, because models that account for asset price reversals do not outperform naive out-of-sample forecasts of bond yields, is not empirically supported for European central banks which have carried out extensive QE interventions. Specifically, using data on 10-year sovereign bond yields, we have obtained evidence that a naive random walk model does not beat a Markov switching regimes process in out-of-sample forecasting and that the Markov representation5 captures accurately the dynamics of the series for the Eurozone, Sweden. and the UK. This implies that interim halts in asset purchases generate regime switches which reverse the effects of QE interventions, thus reducing the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policy. Besides, these results corroborate those of Kirikos(2020, 2021) that QE policies do not have sizable effects on inflation, investment, and broad monetary aggregates in the decade after the 2008 financial crisis.

    5Of course, other specifications, like a state-space representation (see Dimitriou et al., 2021), can be useful in checking the robustness of our results. In any case, similar out-of-sample forecasts under an augmented information set which includes the instrument of QE policy, namely the monetary base, reinforce our current findings (see Kirikos, 2022).

    Of course, our findings should cautiously be interpreted as evidence of limited QE effectiveness and not as an indication of complete policy failure since long-term interest rates have overall declined throughout the period of QE pursuit. However, taking also into account the fall in inflationary expectations over the same period, this evidence has the important implication that QE policy appears to have transitory effects on long-term rates, and this limits its usefulness as a tool of monetary policy outside periods of financial turmoil.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Bernanke BS (2020) The new tools of monetary policy. Am Econ Rev 110: 943–983. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.110.4.943 doi: 10.1257/aer.110.4.943
    [2] Bhattarai S, Neely CJ (2022) An Analysis of the literature on international unconventional monetary policy. J Econ Lit 60: 527–597. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.20201493 doi: 10.1257/jel.20201493
    [3] Cahill ME, D'Amico S, Li C, et al. (2013) Duration risk versus local supply channel in Treasury yields: evidence from the Federal Reserve's asset purchase announcements. Available from: https://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2013/201335/201335pap.pdf.
    [4] Cebula R, Rossi F (2022) Quantitative easing, macroeconomic stability and economic policy effectiveness. J Financ Econ Policy 14: 468-475. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JFEP-06-2021-0149 doi: 10.1108/JFEP-06-2021-0149
    [5] Dimitriou D, Pappas A, Kazanas T, et al. (2021) Do confidence indicators lead Greek economic activity? Bull Appl Econ 8: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.47260/bae/821 doi: 10.47260/bae/821
    [6] Eggertsson GB, Woodford M (2003) The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy. Brookings Pap Econ Ac 2003: 139–211. https://doi.org/10.7916/D8S46PV9 doi: 10.7916/D8S46PV9
    [7] Gagnon JE (2018) QE skeptics overstate their case. Available from: https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/qe-skeptics-overstate-their-case.
    [8] Gagnon JE, Raskin M, Remache J, et al. (2011) The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve's large-scale asset purchases. Int J Cent Bank 7: 3–43.
    [9] Greenlaw D, Hamilton JD, Harris E, et al. (2018) A skeptical view of the impact of the Fed's balance sheet. Available from: http://www.nber.org/papers/w24687.
    [10] Hamilton JD (1990) Analysis of time series subject to changes in regime. J Econom 45: 39–70. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(90)90093-9 doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(90)90093-9
    [11] Hamilton JD (1993) Estimation, inference, and forecasting of time series subject to changes in regime, In: Maddala, G.S., Rao, C.R., Vinod, H.D., Handbook of Statistics 11: 231–260. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-7161(05)80044-6
    [12] Kirikos DG (2020) Quantitative easing impotence in the liquidity trap: further evidence. Econ Anal Policy 68: 151–162. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2020.09.004 doi: 10.1016/j.eap.2020.09.004
    [13] Kirikos DG (2021) Monetary policy effectiveness in the liquidity trap: a switching regimes approach. Rev Keynes Econ 9: 139–155. http://dx.doi.org/10.4337/roke.2021.01.07 doi: 10.4337/roke.2021.01.07
    [14] Kirikos DG (2022) Are quantitative easing effects transitory? Evidence from out-of-sample forecasts. J Financ Econ Policy 14: 811–822. https://doi.org/10.1108/JFEP-04-2022-0099 doi: 10.1108/JFEP-04-2022-0099
    [15] Kwiatkowski D, Phillips PCB, Schmidt P, et al. (1992) Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root. J Econom 54: 159–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(92)90104-Y doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(92)90104-Y
    [16] Neely CJ (2022) How persistent are unconventional monetary policy effects? J Int Money Financ 126: 102653. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102653 doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102653
    [17] Vayanos D, Vila JL (2009) A preferred-habitat model of the term structure of interest rates. Available from: https://www.nber.org/papers/w15487.
    [18] Wright JH (2012) What does monetary policy do to long-term interest rates at the zero lower bound? Econ J 122: 447–466. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02556.x doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02556.x
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Wenhui Feng, Xingfa Zhang, Yanshan Chen, Zefang Song, Linear regression estimation using intraday high frequency data, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 13123, 10.3934/math.2023662
    2. Meng Pang, Zhe Li, A novel profit-based validity index approach for feature selection in credit risk prediction, 2024, 9, 2473-6988, 974, 10.3934/math.2024049
    3. Dimitris G. Kirikos, Quantitative easing effectiveness: Evidence from Euro private assets, 2024, 76, 0307-3378, 354, 10.1111/boer.12427
    4. Wenhui Feng, Yuan Li, Xingfa Zhang, A mixture deep neural network GARCH model for volatility forecasting, 2023, 31, 2688-1594, 3814, 10.3934/era.2023194
    5. Jun Zhao, Peibiao Zhao, Quantile hedging for contingent claims in an uncertain financial environment, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 15651, 10.3934/math.2023799
    6. Jie Zheng, Yijun Li, Machine learning model of tax arrears prediction based on knowledge graph, 2023, 31, 2688-1594, 4057, 10.3934/era.2023206
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1918) PDF downloads(67) Cited by(6)

Figures and Tables

Figures(2)  /  Tables(5)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog