Research article

The impact of corporate tax outcomes on forced CEO turnover

  • Received: 21 March 2022 Revised: 14 June 2022 Accepted: 20 June 2022 Published: 18 July 2022
  • JEL Codes: M40, H25

  • As market competition has increased in recent years, CEO turnover has become more frequent. The tax avoidance activities maximize after-tax profits. After the CEO turnover, the company's strategy needs to be repositioned. Therefore, this paper analyzes the impact of corporate tax avoidance on CEO turnover. This paper selects the Chinese A-share market from 2010 to 2019. It combines theoretical analysis and empirical research to explore the impact of corporate tax avoidance on CEO turnover and further analyzes the relationship under different ownerships. This paper finds a negative relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover. Listed companies with lower tax rates increase social concern, leading to public doubts and inspections by tax authorities, which further damage the company's reputation. CEO turnover is the quick and easy way to respond to public accusations. This paper also finds that state-owned enterprises (SOEs) undertake more social responsibilities than non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs). The main contributions of this paper are as follows: From the theoretical perspective, this paper conducts systematic research on corporate tax avoidance and CEO turnover and analyzes the relationship under different ownerships. In practice, this paper puts forward relevant policy recommendations for the long-term development of enterprises and social responsibilities.

    Citation: Xue Chang. The impact of corporate tax outcomes on forced CEO turnover[J]. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 218-236. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022013

    Related Papers:

    [1] Shan Huang, Khor Teik Huat, Zifei Zhou . The studies on Chinese traditional culture and corporate environmental responsibility: literature review and its implications. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(1): 1-15. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022001
    [2] Jaroslav Sedláček, Veronika Popelková . Non-financial information and their reporting—evidence of small and medium-sized enterprises and large corporations on the Czech capital market. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 204-216. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020012
    [3] Tsolmon Baatarzorig, Nyambaatar Batbayar, Ragchaasuren Galindev, Oyunzul Tserendorj . The 2014 Mongolian Social Accounting Matrix. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 138-154. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020008
    [4] Kewei Ma, Guido Ferrari, Zichuan Mi . SAM-based analysis of China’s economic system and measurement of the effects of a VAT rate cut after the tax reform. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 26-52. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020002
    [5] Jamel Eddine Mkadmi . Impact of Islamic and conventional corporate governance mechanisms on ethical performance of Islamic banks: evidence from Malaysia. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 174-187. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020010
    [6] Serena Fatica, Wildmer Daniel Gregori . Income shifting by multinational enterprises as a source of mismeasurement in aggregate statistics. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(4): 548-563. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024025
    [7] Guillermo Peña . VAT experience as an influence on banking crises. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 53-65. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020003
    [8] Hila Axelrad, Albert Yirmiyahu . Who wants to work and why? workplace practices, job satisfaction and the will to work. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 287-309. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022017
    [9] Dachen Sheng, Opale Guyot . Corporate governance in Chinese manufacturing sector: Ownership structure, monitoring and firms' earning quality. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(4): 421-443. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023024
    [10] Aleksandar Vasilev . A progressive capital income tax — a bad idea, or just a useless idea? Lessons for Bulgaria (1999-2018). National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(4): 402-411. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020024
  • As market competition has increased in recent years, CEO turnover has become more frequent. The tax avoidance activities maximize after-tax profits. After the CEO turnover, the company's strategy needs to be repositioned. Therefore, this paper analyzes the impact of corporate tax avoidance on CEO turnover. This paper selects the Chinese A-share market from 2010 to 2019. It combines theoretical analysis and empirical research to explore the impact of corporate tax avoidance on CEO turnover and further analyzes the relationship under different ownerships. This paper finds a negative relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover. Listed companies with lower tax rates increase social concern, leading to public doubts and inspections by tax authorities, which further damage the company's reputation. CEO turnover is the quick and easy way to respond to public accusations. This paper also finds that state-owned enterprises (SOEs) undertake more social responsibilities than non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs). The main contributions of this paper are as follows: From the theoretical perspective, this paper conducts systematic research on corporate tax avoidance and CEO turnover and analyzes the relationship under different ownerships. In practice, this paper puts forward relevant policy recommendations for the long-term development of enterprises and social responsibilities.



    Chief Executive Officer (CEO) turnover is essential in corporate governance (Clayton et al., 2005). Dismissing the CEO can effectively rebuild the company's reputation and restores the shareholders' confidence (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). This study investigates the relationship between tax issues and forced CEO turnover using linear probability models. This paper finds a negative relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover. This paper also finds that state-owned enterprises undertake more social responsibilities than non-state-owned enterprises.

    Our research expands the research perspective by investigating the impact of tax outcomes on forced CEO turnover from different theories, which helps to understand corporate tax avoidance from a complete perspective and enriches the existing literature. Firstly, this paper documents the important relationship between tax outcomes and forced CEO turnover. Many researchers question the role of CEOs in tax planning because they are not tax experts and do not know the details of tax strategy. This paper studies the role of the CEO in corporate tax planning. Secondly, this paper provides a new perspective on forced CEO turnover. CEO turnover is a hot issue in the current research, but the existing studies focus on the impact of corporate performance on CEO turnover. Few studies analyze the relationship between tax avoidance and forced CEO turnover. Thirdly, this paper enriches the existing literature on tax avoidance. Many researchers have investigated the reasons and impacts of tax avoidance since the literature published by Hanlon and Heitzman (2010). However, few of them analyze tax avoidance from corporate social responsibility theory. This paper also analyzes the relationship under different ownerships, which provides a new perspective on corporate tax avoidance and CEO turnover.

    In recent years, many researchers have paid attention to tax avoidance. Graham et al. (2012) reviewed the literature of the three top accounting journals (Accounting Review, Journal of Accounting and Economics, and Journal of Accounting Research) and finds an upward trend in tax avoidance literature. Much literature has analyzed the tax avoidance motivations and consequences (Dharmapala and Desai, 2007). This paper defines tax avoidance broadly as covering any matter that reduces the company's tax payment compared to pre-tax income (Dyreng et al., 2008). This paper does not measure tax aggressiveness, tax risk, tax evasion, or tax shelters. Previous studies have shown substantial variation in effective tax rates. Many factors affect tax strategies, such as board composition, company structure, and management compensation. Among many factors, the influence of executives is the most important. Kim et al. (2011) finds that managers can manipulate income and hide negative information through complex tax techniques. Slemrod (2004) finds that if the marginal benefits of tax avoidance are more significant than the marginal costs, managers will take all measures to reduce the tax expenses. Companies that use after-tax incentive compensation have lower effective tax rates than companies that use pre-tax performance incentive compensation (Gaertner, 2014; Powers et al., 2016). Tax avoidance can affect the cost of equity, enterprises value, investors' attitude, management reputation, leverage, and so on.

    CEO turnover can be used to change enterprise strategy as the CEO is the decision-maker and implementer of enterprise strategy. CEO turnover has become a core issue in strategy, organization, finance, and leadership in recent years. According to the previous literature, the main factors that affect CEO turnover are company performance, industry competitiveness, board composition, insider ownership, and so on. CEO turnover is an important part of corporate governance. Board has the responsibility to replace the inappropriate CEOs if they cannot meet the requirements of shareholders (Weisbach, 1988). Douglas and Hou (2011) proposes that corporate fraud in non-SOEs is more likely to change the CEO in China compared with state-owned companies. Fee et al. (2013) shows that effectively distinguishing between forced and non-forced CEO turnover can reduce bias in the test, which can robustly analyze the relationship between tax and CEO turnover. Because forcing the CEO to leave is a deliberate action taken by the board, the company plans to change direction, strategy, and leadership. In developed countries, CEO turnover has been widely analyzed. However, the determinants of CEO turnover remain unclear in countries with weak legal systems and underdeveloped financial systems. It is rare to explore the impact of the tax rate on forced CEO turnover in China. Our research also complements the existing literature on CEO turnover.

    Although the CEO is not a tax expert and cannot directly influence the company's tax policies, the CEO is the ultimate decision-maker, whose position is higher than that of the tax director and CFO (Cazier et al., 2014). CEOs significantly impact effective tax rates more than CFOs (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006; Feldstein, 1999). The CEO can use "tone at the top" to indirectly influence the tax policies (Mason and Hambrick, 1984). They hold that the decision-making is affected by the CEO's characteristics, and has been confirmed by many studies (Chyz, 2013; Maydew et al., 2010; Olsen and Stekelberg, 2015; Wilson and Rego, 2012). They believe that the CEO significantly impacts corporate tax rates (Maydew et al., 2010). CEOs can adjust the company's annual budget to avoid taxes. Hiring or dismissing a tax director is part of the CEO's tax planning. The CEO can also instruct the CFO or tax directors to avoid tax by changing the compensation plan. Therefore, the CEO has the intention and ability to influence the company's tax strategy. Chyz et al. (2014) finds a positive relationship between tax avoidance and CEO overconfidence. Koester et al. (2016) finds that executives with more resources are more effective in participating in tax avoidance activities. Gaertner and Chyz (2018) analyses CEO turnover in the United States from 1993 to 2006. They find a relationship between the tax rates and forced CEO turnover. When the tax rate deviates from the industry average, the CEO is more likely to be replaced.

    A company needs to gain legitimacy within society. Corporate attitudes towards corporate social responsibility, considerations of legitimacy, and more fundamental ethical issues affect the tax position of companies (Avi-Yonah, 2008).

    Tax expenses are a primary way for companies to make social contributions (Lanis et al., 2018). Tax avoidance contravenes the expected social standards. Therefore, companies hardly ever publicize their tax avoidance practices (Sikka, 2010). Stakeholders regard tax avoidance as contradictory to their expectations of proper firm behaviors (Gayle et al., 2008; Lanis & Richardson, 2012, 2014). When a firm engages in tax avoidance, the organizational legitimacy of the firm is questioned by the public (Annuar et al., 2014). The public shame of tax-avoidant companies has been seen as an effective way to limit tax avoidance activities (Holt and Barford, 2013). CEOs safeguard the stakeholders' interests while executing their corporate duties (Freeman et al., 2004). Thus, companies seeking to uphold their legitimacy are expected to be less tax avoidant (Lanis & Richardson, 2012).

    Tax avoidance incurs direct and indirect costs (Badertscher et al., 2013). From the dimension of direct expenses, companies not only need to pay related consulting fees and additional audit fees for tax planning, but they must also pay the punishment for tax avoidance, thereby reducing the company's cash inflow and shareholders' wealth (Slemrod, 2004). From the dimension of indirect costs, tax avoidance is formed through complex transactions, which will exacerbate the information asymmetry between insiders and outsiders. Since external investors cannot identify the actual situation of enterprises, they will demand a higher return. Tax avoidance will also increase the complexity of the operating structure and financial system and facilitate the management's opportunistic behaviors such as profit manipulation (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006; Frank et al., 2009). Companies are subject to more stringent external regulatory risks, such as audit firms, media, government, consumers, etc. (Wilson and Rego, 2012).

    Corporate social responsibilities believe that tax avoidance costs are greater than their benefits (Chen et al., 2010). Reputational costs are a limiting factor in the tax literature, which firms and managers are willing to minimize their effective tax rates (Cheng et al., 2012; Graham et al., 2014; Slemrod and Hanlon, 2009). Slemrod and Hanlon (2009) suggests that when a company is involved in tax shelters, the company's share price declines. Bankman (2004) finds that firms may bear reputational and political costs for being labeled a "poor corporate citizen, " which might adversely affect product market outcomes. Networks and media promote the establishment of a reputation mechanism and enhance the trust and efficiency of the market. Dyreng et al. (2017) find that companies that adopt tax avoidance strategies will harm the market value. The loss caused by reputation is far greater than the penalty imposed by the tax authorities (Karpoff and Lott, 1993).

    From the managers' perspective, they are strongly motivated not to participate in tax avoidance. Because reputation costs and punishment are the main factors, managers are unwilling to reduce effective tax rates (Cheng et al., 2012; Desai & Dharmapala, 2006; Slemrod & Hanlon, 2009). Scholes. et al. (2005) finds that CEOs suffer reputational damage due to tax avoidance (Graham et al., 2014). As the corporation's spokesman, the CEO will likely become the "scapegoat." The company is more willing to change the CEO to improve its corporate image and show the market that it hopes to change its tax strategy.

    As mentioned above, paying taxes is essential for enterprises to undertake social responsibility. Slemrod and Hanlon (2009) find that the company will be labeled as a "poor corporate citizen" when the tax rate is too low, which increases reputation costs. Stakeholders highly appraise companies that have made greater contributions to society. Companies that pay more taxes deliver excellent performance information to the market. In turn, companies will face stricter inspections by the tax authorities, media, and even customers resist, which will affect the company's market value. Based on the above analysis, this paper puts forward the first hypothesis.

    H1A: The possibility of forced CEO turnover increases when the effective tax rates related to peer companies are low.

    According to the principal-agent theory, the goal of the shareholders and managers is inconsistent. Shareholders aim for after-tax profits, and managers avoid risks (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006).

    As a kind of operating cost, tax expenses reduce the net profit and affect the reinvestment and reproduction of the enterprise. Implementing tax avoidance can reduce the tax costs, retain more cash flow, and increase the competitiveness of enterprises (Blouin, 2014). As effective tax rates rise, the board of directors and shareholders tend to doubt the CEO's ability to manage the company's resources. Managers are more actively involved in tax avoidance to reflect their profitability and management level.

    From the perspective of the CEO's interests, tax avoidance occurs in three situations. Firstly, if companies have a cooperating governance mechanism, CEOs can increase profits through tax avoidance to obtain higher compensation. Secondly, if the company lacks adequate supervision and corporate governance mechanisms, it will not be able to coordinate agency problems through equity compensation. When there is no effective restriction and control, the CEO as a "rational person, " has self-interest motivation (Warfield and Cheng, 2005). They can use the tax avoidance transactions to grab private interests (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006). Slemrod (2004) finds that managers pursue retaining more surplus funds through the tax avoidance strategy for enterprise expansion or private interests. There is a complementary relationship between tax avoidance and the CEO's rent-seeking (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006; Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). Executives without adequate supervision will take radical tax avoidance decisions to seek private interest, and rent-seeking behavior will further enhance executives' willingness and ability to implement tax avoidance transactions. The cash flow generated by tax avoidance is a supplement to executive compensation. Desai and Dharmapala (2006) find that if the compensation is increased, the degree of tax avoidance will be reduced. Managers tend to take aggressive tax avoidance if incentive contracts don't work. Laguir et al. (2015) confirm that CEOs with more power will implement more radical tax avoidance strategies and seize more private interests accordingly. Therefore, CEOs are willing and able to manipulate profits by taking tax avoidance activities.

    Compared with corporate misconduct, tax avoidance activity may have little impact on the company's reputation. Unlike accounting fraud, tax avoidance is mostly legal or belongs to the gray area of tax law. The risks involved in tax avoidance may differ from other risks faced by companies (such as liquidity, competition, and continued operation risks). Therefore, the impact of tax avoidance on corporate reputation is not essential. Gallemore et al. (2014) studied the possibility of CEO turnover after tax avoidance participation has been publicly disclosed. They find no evidence of an increase in CEO turnover when the company participates in the tax avoidance, which shows that CEOs do not bear the reputation cost due to the choice of tax avoidance policies.

    From the perspective of reducing agency costs and CEOs' interests, CEOs are more willing to avoid taxes. Failure to participate in tax avoidance may result in the CEO unable to achieve the after-tax profit target and increase the possibility of dismissal. Therefore, this paper put forward the second hypothesis:

    H1B: The possibility of forced CEO turnover increases when the effective tax rates related to peer companies are high.

    From the property rights theory, there are great differences between state-owned and non-state-owned enterprises, which also brings about different effects of tax avoidance on CEO turnover. Shareholders have additional requirements for tax planning in state-owned enterprises.

    SOEs have commercial and public welfare characteristics. The goals of SOEs are not only to increase corporate wealth but also to undertake social responsibilities such as economic development and social stability. To achieve social goals, state-owned enterprises must bear more tax expenses to maintain the strength of the national tax revenue. The ownership and control of SOEs belong to the government. The government directly affects SOEs. The government requires state-owned enterprises to bear more tax expenses through administrative approaches. At the same time, the government controls the assessment, appointment, and removal of CEOs of SOEs. To keep the position or favor the government, CEOs have the incentive to bear more taxes to ensure the stability of fiscal income and increase the reputation value of the enterprise.

    Unlike state-owned enterprises, the goal of non-state-owned enterprises is to maximize the company's value. They have higher incentives for tax avoidance to reduce tax costs, retain more cash flow in the enterprise, and increase shareholders' value. The non-state-owned enterprises bear less social responsibility, and the public is less critical of them in tax avoidance. Therefore, compared with state-owned enterprises, CEOs pay less tax to the government and benefit shareholders, which are less likely to be fired in non-state-owned companies.

    From managers' view, CEOs in state-owned enterprises are often administrative appointments that bear many administrative responsibilities. In contrast, CEOs of non-state-owned enterprises are agents elected by the board of directors. The differences make them have different attitudes towards corporate tax avoidance.

    State-owned enterprises face greater public pressure than non-SOEs when they fail to fulfill their social responsibilities (Kao et al., 2018). Besides, public pressure may bring huge political and reputation costs (Dyreng et al., 2016). When S OEs engage in tax avoidance activities, it not only cannot meet the government's objectives but also damages the public image of state-owned enterprises. Based on the above analysis, this paper puts forward the second hypothesis.

    H2: Compared with non-SOEs, tax avoidance in state-owned enterprises significantly impacts forced CEO turnover.

    Our sample is companies listed on both the Shanghai Stock Exchange (SHSE) and the Shenzhen Stock Exchange (SZSE) from 2010 to 2018. The main reason for the sample period beginning in 2010 is that China implemented the new enterprise income tax law in 2008. Revising the new income tax law has reduced the maximum enterprise income tax rate from 33% to 25%. Therefore, it is expected that the implementation of this policy in 2008 will significantly affect the tax avoidance of enterprises. In addition, the global financial crisis that started in 2008 partially impacted China's economy, leading to the fluctuation of national policy. In short, to avoid the impact of the new income tax law and the global financial crisis, this paper takes 2010 as the starting year of the research sample.

    Next, the samples are screened as follows steps:

    1. Remove the samples whose pre-tax accounting profit is less than or equal to zero.

    2. Remove the abnormal samples whose income tax expense is less than or greater than pre-tax accounting profit.

    3. Delete the abnormal samples whose debt cost is less than or greater than one.

    4. Exclude firms with incomplete information on the key variables.

    5. Delete the listed companies in the financial industry because the accounting standards in the financial industry are different from other industries, and the relevant indicators are not comparable.

    6. Delete companies marked as ST or * ST because of irregularities and negative profits for two or three consecutive years.

    7. Excluding the samples with an abnormal income tax rate (the actual income tax rate is less than 0 and greater than 1).

    The research data comes from the CSMAR database. In addition, all variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. In 2010–2018, there are 11,000 firm-year observations.

    To test whether tax avoidance will affect the probability of forced CEO turnover, this paper uses Linear probability models (LPM) to test the hypothesis (Chang & Wong, 2009):

    ForcedCEOturnoveri,t+1=α+β1taxindicatori,t+β2ControlVariablesi,t+Ij+Tt+εi,t (1)

    This paper estimates the model (1) and gives the results of ETR, CASH_ETR, BTD, and DDBTD, respectively. Control variables can be divided into two aspects. This paper uses (Duality structure and CEO's tenure) variables to control the characteristics of CEOs (Shivdasani and Kang, 1995). This paper controls firm characteristics through capital structure, corporate size, and companies' ownership. This paper also controls for three firm characteristics: capital structure, size, leverage, and the ownership of the largest shareholders (Armstrong et al., 2012). This paper uses the accounting performance indicator (ROA) to measure profitability. The dummy variable (State) indicates whether state or private shareholders control a listed firm. This paper calculates industry-adjusted returns (AR) as the firm's industry-adjusted annual stock return (including dividends) (Hubbard et al., 2017).

    There were 1,701 CEO turnovers during the sample period. In table 1, there are 12 reasons for CEO turnover, which are provided by the CSMAR database. Change of job is taking up the highest part, accounting for 28.81% of the turnover. The second is contract expiration, which represents 27.81%, and the third is personal reasons (12.17%). Only 0.76% falls in the dismissal category. This paper reclassifies reasons for job changes, resignations, personal reasons, and reasons not given (Firth et al., 2006). Other turnovers are normal except if the CEO is less than 60 years old and the stated reason is retirement. This paper classifies this turnover as forced (Huson et al., 2004). Table 2 summarizes the reasons for forced and normal CEOs turnover and the corresponding frequency. By reexamining 958 cases (the combination of job changes, resignations, personal reasons, and reasons not given) through a search for CEO resumes, 432 cases are not forced. Of those, 241 cases remain as board chairman or vice-chairman, and 191 are promoted (186 CEOs were promoted as chairman or vice-chairman; 5 CEOs became government officials). This paper classifies the remaining 526 cases as forced turnover. These included 78 CEOs who accepted new positions ranked lower than the CEO position and 448 cases without any traceable destination information. In conclusion, 1154 normal turnover events accounted for 67.84% of the total and 516 cases of forced turnover (32.16%).

    Table 1.  Reasons for CEO turnover presented in CSMAR database.
    Reasons Freq. Percent
    Change of job 490 28.81%
    Retirement 46 2.70%
    Contract expiration 473 27.81%
    Change in controlling shareholders 3 0.18%
    Resignation 160 9.41%
    Dismissal 13 0.76%
    Health 34 2.00%
    Personal reasons 207 12.17%
    Corporate governance reform 94 5.53%
    Legal disputes 4 0.24%
    Completion of acting duties 76 4.47%
    No reason given 101 5.94%
    Total 1701 100.00%

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 2.  Classification of CEO turnover.
    Reasons for turnover Number of observations Frequency (%)
    1.Normal turnover 1154 67.84%
    Retirement 38 2.23%
    Contract expiration 473 27.81%
    Change in controlling shareholders 3 0.18%
    Health 34 2.00%
    Corporate governance reform 94 5.53%
    Legal disputes 4 0.24%
    Completion of acting duties 76 4.47%
    Important government position taken up 5 0.29%
    Remaining as board chairman or vice chairman 241 14.17%
    Promoted to board chairman or vice chairman 186 10.93%
    2. Forced turnover 547 32.16%
    New position ranked lower than CEO position 78 4.59%
    retirement ageless than 60 8 0.47%
    Dismissed 13 0.76%
    Information unavailable 448 26.34%
    Total number of observations 1701 100.00%

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 3.  Variable definitions.
    Variables Variables Name Definition
    Independent Variables ETR ETR equals tax expenditure to pre-tax income
    CASH_ETR CASH_ETR means cash tax payment to pretax income
    BTD Book-tax difference (BTD) means that the total differences between book and taxable incomes.
    DDBTD DDBTD means a measure of unexplained total book-tax differences
    Dependent Variables TO_FORCE TO_FORCE is a dummy variable that equals 1 if there was a forced turnover and 0 otherwise.
    Control Variables STATE If a firm has a greater percentage of state shares, State takes the value of 1, and 0 otherwise.
    TENURE Tenure indicates that the number of years that a CEO has served in a listed firm.
    SIZE Size means the size of a listed firm, measured as the natural logarithm of the book value of total assets.
    AR Firm's industry-adjusted annual stock return (including dividends)
    DUALITY Duality is used to measure whether the CEO is concurrently as a chairman. It is a dummy variable. The value 1 if the CEO and the Chairman of the Board of Directors are the same person, and 0 otherwise.
    LEV Leverage is defined as total liabilities divided by total assets.
    ROA ROA=after tax profit/ total assets

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Hanlon and Heitzman (2010) find that there are many approaches to measure tax avoidance to ensure the robustness of research conclusions. This paper uses four measures from the balance sheet dimension and cash flow statement dimension: effective tax rate (ETR), cash effective tax rate (CASH_ETR), book-tax difference (BTD), and discretionary book-tax difference (DDBTD). They are the core variables in the study of tax avoidance and have been used in many studies (Li et al., 2019). They conclude that a higher ETR or cash-ETR indicates lower tax aggressiveness, while a higher BTD and DDBTD indicate a higher tax avoidance.

    Effective tax rate (ETR) is the simplest measure used by many scholars (Bertrand and Schoar, 2003; Richardson and Lanis, 2012). The lower ETR reflects the lower tax expenditure caused by tax avoidance (Blaylock et al., 2012).

    ETRit=incometaxexpense/(pretaxincome) (2)

    Our second measure is Cash-ETR which reflects firms' actual cash tax payments for a given level of pre-tax income (Chyz & Gaertner, 2017; Coles & Hoi, 2003; Lanis & Richardson, 2012).

    CASH_ETRit=cashtaxpayment/(pretaxincome) (3)

    Book-tax difference (BTD) refers to the difference between book accounting profit and the taxable income declared to the tax authority, which was proposed by Plesko (2003). The larger the BTD, the greater the difference between the accounting profit and the taxable income (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006).

    TD=(pretaxincometaxableincome)/(totalasset) (4)
    CTaxableincome=(Incometaxexpensedeferredincometaxexpense)/(Nominalincometaxrate) (5)

    Discretionary book-tax difference (DDBTD) are the residuals from the following model (8) (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006). DDBTD can more accurately measure and reflect tax avoidance behavior. DDBTD can be calculated from the model (8). TACCit is total accruals profit scaled by total assets; ui is the average value of the residual for firm i over the sample period; εi,t and is the deviation in year t from firm i's average residual ui. The residual from this regression (DDBTD) can be used as a tax avoidance measure. DDBTD represents the part of the BTD that cannot be explained by accrued profit.

    CTACC=(profitcashflowfromoperatingactivities)/totalasset (6)
    BTDit=αTACCit+ui+εi,t (7)
    DDBTD=ui+εi,t (8)

    Table 4 presents descriptive statistics. The average length of tenure is 5.286 years. Duality is not a common feature of the corporate governance structure in listed companies; only 27.2% of the CEOs also serve as the board's chairman.

    Table 4.  Describe statistics.
    Variables Number Mean Standard Deviation Minimum Median Maximum
    Panel A: Control variables
    STATE 11000 0.338 0.473 0 0 1
    TENURE 11000 5.286 2.837 0 4.984 21.19
    SIZE 11000 22.13 1.254 19.99 21.95 25.74
    AR 11000 0.0630 0.523 −1.437 −0.0210 16.95
    LEV 11000 0.392 0.198 0.0510 0.382 0.818
    ROA 11000 0.0620 0.0380 0.00900 0.0530 0.193
    DUALITY 11000 0.272 0.445 0 0 1
    Panel B: Performance variables
    TO FORCE 11000 0.0270 0.163 0 0 1
    ETR 11000 0.171 0.0710 −0.0110 0.158 0.365
    CASH_ ETR 11000 0.523 0.222 −0.00500 0.503 0.990
    BTD 11000 0.00700 0.0270 −0.0580 0.00300 0.102
    DDBTD 11000 0.00500 0.0270 −0.0660 0.00300 0.0920
    Note: Variable definitions: ETR equals tax expenditure to pre-tax income. CASH_ETR means cash tax payment to pretax income. Book-tax difference (BTD) means that the total differences between book and taxable incomes. DDBTD means a measure of unexplained total book-tax differences. TO_FORCE is a dummy variable that equals 1 if there was a forced turnover and 0 otherwise. STATE presents a firm has a greater percentage of state shares, State takes the value of 1, and 0 otherwise. Tenure indicates that the number of years that a CEO has served in a listed firm. SIZE means the size of a listed firm, measured as the natural logarithm of the book value of total assets. AR presents firm's industry-adjusted annual stock return (including dividends). DUALITY is used to measure whether the CEO is concurrently as a chairman or not. It is a dummy variable. The value of concurrent is 1, otherwise it is 0. LEV is defined as total liabilities divided by total assets. ROA equals after tax profit divided total assets.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The Pearson correlation coefficient between the main variables is shown in Table 5. In the table, "*, **, ***" indicate the significance levels at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively. It can be seen from the table above:

    Table 5.  Pearson correlation coefficients.
    VARIABLES STATE TENURE SIZE AR LEV ROA DUALITY TO FORCE ETR CASH_ETR BTD DDBTD
    STATE 1
    TENURE 0.100*** 1
    SIZE 0.359*** 0.038*** 1
    AR −0.011 0.001 −0.034*** 1
    LEV 0.293*** 0.022** 0.554*** 0.051*** 1
    ROA −0.102*** 0.004 −0.121*** 0.044*** −0.347*** 1
    DUALITY −0.286*** 0.011 −0.193*** 0.021** −0.148*** 0.030*** 1
    TO FORCE 0.049*** −0.118*** 0.056*** −0.002 0.037*** 0.002 −0.025*** 1
    ETR 0.130*** 0.018* 0.200*** −0.022** 0.226*** −0.138*** −0.074*** −0.024** 1
    CASH_ETR 0.103*** 0.041*** 0.129*** −0.046*** 0.220*** −0.285*** −0.066*** −0.039*** 0.295*** 1
    BTD 0.020** −0.002 −0.053*** 0.006 −0.114*** 0.297*** −0.016* 0.043*** −0.496*** −0.286*** 1
    DDBTD 0.030*** −0.008 −0.027*** 0.011 −0.094*** 0.215*** −0.01 0.037*** −0.392*** −0.212*** 0.788*** 1
    Note: This table reports Pearson correlation coefficients for the full sample. Forced CEO Turnover is measured at t+1 period, while all other variables as measured at t. *, **, *** Denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for one-tailed tests examining forced turnover quintiles, and two-tailed otherwise.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    (1) The correlation coefficient between the effective tax rate (ETR) and forced CEO turnover (TO_FORCE) is −0.024, the correlation coefficient between CASH-ETR and TO_FORCE is −0.039, and the correlation coefficient between BTD (DDBTD) and TO_FORCE is 0.043 and 0.037, respectively and significant at the 1% level. The results indicate that the higher the tax rate, the lower level of tax avoidance, and the CEO is unlikely to be fired, which is consistent with hypothesis 1A.

    (2) The correlation coefficient between the STATE and the effective tax rate (ETR) and CASH_ETR is 0.13 and 0.103, respectively, and is significant at 1%. The results indicate that the effective tax rate in state-owned enterprises is higher than that of non-state-owned enterprises, which is consistent with hypothesis 2.

    This paper calculates the variance inflation factors (VIF) for each independent variable to ensure multi-collinearity is not a problem. The VIFs do not exceed 2, suggesting that our models are not prone to multi-collinearity problems. After descriptive statistical analysis and the Pearson correlation coefficient test, we have a preliminary understanding of the relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover. This paper also conducts regression analysis to test the correctness of the hypothesis.

    Table 6 shows the regression results in LPM regression. The regression coefficient between the effective tax rate (ETR) and forced CEO turnover (TO_FORCE) is −0.1298, between CASH_ETR and TO_FORCE, is −0.0367, between BTD (DDBTD) and TO_FORCE, is 0.2422 (0.2357) and significantly above the 1% level. The results indicate that the lower the effective tax rate (cash effective tax rates), the higher the degree of corporate tax avoidance and the higher likely forced CEO turnover, which verifies hypothesis 1A, according to Gaertner (2018), I also conducted the linear Probability Model with year and industry fixed effects, and the result is consistent with hypothesis 1A.

    Table 6.  LPM in full sample.
    TO_FORCE TO_FORCE TO_FORCE TO_FORCE
    FULL SAMPLE −1 −2 −3 −4
    STATE 0.0107 0.0114 0.0115 0.0119
    (0.6448) (0.6878) (0.6882) (0.7132)
    TENURE −0.0176*** −0.0176*** −0.0176*** −0.0177***
    (−6.3830) (−6.3762) (−6.3799) (−6.3921)
    SIZE 0.0210*** 0.0193*** 0.0213*** 0.0214***
    (3.5542) (3.1971) (3.6436) (3.6496)
    AR −0.0016 −0.0018 −0.0012 −0.0012
    (−0.5409) (−0.6053) (−0.3929) (−0.4090)
    LEV −0.0354* −0.0335* −0.0354* −0.0352*
    (−1.7702) (−1.6652) (−1.7835) (−1.7654)
    ROA 0.1383* 0.0718 0.1115 0.1410*
    (1.6946) (0.7943) (1.33) (1.7522)
    DUALITY 0.0277*** 0.0274*** 0.0279*** 0.0279***
    (3.8023) (3.7483) (3.8436) (3.8467
    ETR −0.1298***
    (−3.6580)
    CASH_ETR −0.0367**
    (−2.5172)
    BTD 0.2422***
    (2.6327)
    DDBTD 0.2357**
    (2.4282)
    _cons −0.3411*** −0.3047** −0.3732*** −0.3749***
    (−2.7059) (−2.3459) (−3.0227) (−3.0355)
    Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
    N 10695 10695 10695 10695
    adj. R2 0.022 0.022 0.022 0.022
    F 10.8687 10.7843 10.9043 10.7655
    Note: This table reports results for our main tests examining the effect of taxes on forced CEO turnover using a Linear Probability Model. Regression coefficients and standard errors are reported side-by-side. Forced CEO Turnover is measured as year t+1, while all other variables as measured at t. *, **, *** Denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for one-tailed tests examining forced turnover quintiles, and two-tailed otherwise.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The empirical test in table 6 confirms the relationship between corporate tax avoidance and forced CEO turnover. In China, state-owned enterprises occupy an essential part of listed companies. It is necessary to distinguish the nature of property rights to explore the difference between SOEs and non-SOEs. Therefore, an empirical test of hypothesis 2 is carried out. Table 7 shows that in state-owned enterprises, the effective tax rate (ETR) and CASH-ETR are negatively correlated with TO_FORCE and are significant at the 1% level, BTD (DDBTD) is significantly positively correlated with TO_FORCE and significant at the 1 % level. Compared with SOEs, table 7 shows that the relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover is not significant in non-state-owned enterprises, which is consistent with Hypothesis 2. Table 7 shows that the lower the effective tax rate of the state-owned enterprise group, the higher the degree of corporate tax avoidance, and the greater the possibility of mandatory CEO turnover.

    Table 7.  Differences between SOEs and non-SOEs.
    VARIABLES ETR CASH_ETR BTD DDBTD
    (1) Estimating using LPM full sample −0.1298*** −0.0367** 0.2422*** 0.2357**
    (−3.6580) (−2.5172) (2.6327) (2.4282)
    (2) Estimating using LPM in SOEs −0.3752*** −0.1615*** 0.8919*** 1.0125***
    (−5.4373) (−5.4374) (4.2166) (4.4485)
    (3) Estimating using LPM in non-SOEs 0.0187 0.0279* −0.0162 −0.0906
    (0.4845) (1.711) (−0.1649) (−0.9075)
    Note: This table reports results for our main tests examining the effect of taxes on forced CEO turnover using a Linear Probability Model in SOEs. Regression coefficients and standard errors are reported side-by-side. Forced CEO Turnover is measured as year t+1, while all other variables as measured at t. *, **, *** Denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for one-tailed tests examining forced turnover quintiles, and two-tailed otherwise.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    In this subsection, this paper performs a series of additional tests to ensure the robustness of our results.

    This paper also conducts a logit model to support hypothesis, which shows in table 8. The result is consistent with the LPM model.

    Table 8.  Changes of tax rates after forced CEO turnover.
    1 2 3 4
    L_ETR L_CASH-ETR L_BTD L_DDBTD
    TO_FORCEi,t 0.0069* 0.0246** −0.0019 −0.0003
    (1.7315) (2.156) (−1.0279) (−0.1805)
    STATE 0.0098 −0.0067 −0.0005 −0.0023
    (0.6486) (−0.1502) (−0.1005) (−0.4048)
    TENURE 0.0019** 0.0045 −0.0004 −0.0004
    (2.1588) (1.635) (−1.0863) (−0.8619)
    SIZE 0.0004 −0.0221* 0.0044*** 0.0031**
    (0.0943) (−1.7563) (2.6232) (2.0427)
    AR 0.0019 0.0221*** 0 −0.0002
    (1.6394) (5.258) (0.0386) (−0.3228)
    LEV 0.0227 0.0973** −0.0173*** −0.0116*
    (1.5997) (2.0645) (−2.6054) (−1.7497)
    ROA −0.0186 −0.8015*** 0.0256 0.0163
    (−0.4072) (−5.2415) (1.0307) (0.6055)
    DUALITY 0.0019 −0.01 −0.0003 −0.0003
    (0.5568) (−0.8947) (−0.2065) (−0.1783)
    _cons 0.1373 0.9372*** −0.0852** −0.0600*
    (1.6327) (3.4538) (−2.3821) (−1.8613)
    Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
    N 4478 4478 4478 4478
    adj. R2 0.008 0.046 0.132 0.099
    F 2.0282 8.3209 24.8909 19.0775
    Note: This table reports ETR, CASH_ETR, BTD and DDBTD for firms experiencing forced turnover. Forced CEO Turnover is measured as year t+1, while all other variables as measured at t. *, **, *** Denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for one-tailed tests examining forced turnover quintiles, and two-tailed otherwise.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    If low taxes played a role in the CEO's firing, we expect these trends to be reversed under new management. There is a positive relationship between ETR (CASH_ETR) and TO_FORCE. The results are shown in Table 9, which shows that tax rates increase following forced turnover.

    Table 9.  Falsification test.
    1 2 3 4
    L_UNFORCED L_UNFORCED L_UNFORCED L_UNFORCED
    STATE −0.0298 −0.0294 −0.0294 −0.0299
    (−0.9138) (−0.9018) (−0.9003) (−0.9137)
    TENURE −0.0345*** −0.0345*** −0.0345*** −0.0345***
    (−9.5848) (−9.5886) (−9.5881) (−9.5822)
    SIZE 0.0406*** 0.0407*** 0.0406*** 0.0408***
    (5.1558) (5.1379) (5.1494) (5.171)
    AR −0.0076* −0.0075* −0.0075* −0.0074*
    (−1.7271) (−1.7070) (−1.7235) (−1.7013)
    LEV −0.0328 −0.0332 −0.0332 −0.0322
    (−1.0483) (−1.0583) (−1.0596) (−1.0295)
    ROA 0.0045 0.0198 0.0215 −0.0121
    (0.0422) (0.1598) (0.1897) (−0.1102)
    DUALITY −0.0656*** −0.0657*** −0.0657*** −0.0655***
    (−5.6541) (−5.6524) (−5.6556) (−5.6363)
    ETR −0.0238
    (−0.4681)
    CASH_ETR 0.0023
    (0.1101)
    BTD −0.029
    (−0.2183)
    DDBTD 0.138
    (0.8947)
    _cons −0.6422*** –0.6509*** −0.6464*** −0.6513***
    (–3.8747) (–3.8599) (−3.9021) (−3.9299)
    Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
    N 10695 10695 10695 10695
    adj. R2 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04
    F 31.8288 31.8529 31.8545 31.8211
    Note: This table reports results for our falsification tests examining the effect of taxes on unforced CEO turnover using a Linear Probability Model. Regression coefficients and standard errors are reported side-by-side. Forced CEO Turnover is measured as year t+1, while all other variables as measured at t. *, **, *** Denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for one-tailed tests examining forced turnover quintiles, and two-tailed otherwise.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    This paper conducts a falsification test to ensure primary results are not spurious or the result of correlated omitted factors generally inherent to CEO turnover. Specifically, we re-estimate our main tests after substituting Unforced CEO Turnover for Forced CEO Turnover. According to table 2, we obtain 1,154 normal CEO turnover cases, which are unlikely to result from organizational stress or crisis that drives board action to deliberately change its leader or firm strategy (Fee et al. 2013). The results of our falsification test (reported in Table 8) support our hypotheses, as UNFORCED CEO turnover is not significantly positively related to tax indicators.

    Therefore, this paper analyzes the impact of corporate tax avoidance on CEO turnover. This paper finds a negative relationship between tax rates and forced CEO turnover. Listed companies with lower tax rates will cause social concern, leading to public doubts and inspections by tax authorities, which will further damage the company's reputation. CEO turnover is the quick and easy way to respond to public accusations. This paper also finds that SOEs undertake more social responsibilities than non-SOEs. The main contributions of this paper are as follows: From the theoretical perspective, this paper conducts systematic research on corporate tax avoidance and CEO turnover and analyzes the relationship under different ownerships. In practice, this paper puts forward relevant policy recommendations for the long-term development of enterprises and social responsibilities.

    All author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Agnes Cheng CS, Huang HH, Li YH, et al. (2012) The Effect of Hedge Fund Activism on Corporate Tax Avoidance. Account Rev 87: 1493–1526. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50195 doi: 10.2308/accr-50195
    [2] Annuar HA, Salihu IA, Obid SNS (2014) Corporate Ownership, Governance and Tax Avoidance: An Interactive Effects. Soc Behav Sci 164: 150–160. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.11.063 doi: 10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.11.063
    [3] Armstrong CS, Blouin JL, Larcker DF (2012) The incentives for tax planning. J Account Econ 53: 391–411. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.04.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.04.001
    [4] Avi-Yonah RS (2008) Corporate Social Responsibility and Strategic Tax Behavior. In: Schön, W., MPI Studies on Intellectual Property, Competition and Tax Law, Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 3: 183–198. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-77276-7_13
    [5] Badertscher BA, Katz SP, Rego SO (2013) The Separation of Ownership and Control and Corporate Tax Avoidance. J Account Econ 56: 228–250. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2013.08.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2013.08.005
    [6] Bankman J (2004) The Tax Shelter Problem. National Tax Journal 57: 925–936.
    [7] Bertrand M, Schoar A (2003) Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies. Quart J Econ 118: 1169–1208. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552775 doi: 10.1162/003355303322552775
    [8] Blaylock B, Shevlin T, Wilson RJ (2012) Tax Avoidance, Large Positive Temporary Book-Tax Differences, and Earnings Persistence. The Accounting Review 87: 91–120. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-10158 doi: 10.2308/accr-10158
    [9] Blouin J (2014) Defining and Measuring Tax Planning Aggressiveness. Natl Tax J 67: 875–900. https://doi.org/10.17310/ntj.2014.4.06 doi: 10.17310/ntj.2014.4.06
    [10] Cazier R, Rego S, Tian X, et al. (2014) The impact of increased disclosure requirements and the standardization of accounting practices on earnings management through the reserve for income taxes. Rev Account Stud 20: 436–469. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-014-9302-y doi: 10.1007/s11142-014-9302-y
    [11] Chen S, Chen X, Cheng Q, et al. (2010) Are family firms more tax aggressive than non-family firms? J Financ Econ 95: 41–61. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2009.02.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2009.02.003
    [12] Chang EC, Wong SML (2009) Governance with multiple objectives: Evidence from top executive turnover in China. J Corp Financ 15: 230–244. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2008.10.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2008.10.003
    [13] Cheng CSA, Huang HH, Li Y, et al. (2012) The Effect of Hedge Fund Activism on Corporate Tax Avoidance. Account Rev 87: 1493–1526. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50195 doi: 10.2308/accr-50195
    [14] Chyz JA (2013) Personally tax aggressive executives and corporate tax sheltering. J Account Econ 56: 311–328. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2013.09.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2013.09.003
    [15] Chyz JA, Gaertner FB (2017) Can Paying "Too Much" or "Too Little" Tax Contribute to Forced CEO Turnover? Account Rev 93: 103–130. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-51767 doi: 10.2308/accr-51767
    [16] Chyz JA, Gaertner FB, Kausar A, et al. (2014) Overconfidence and Corporate Tax Policy. Rev Account Stud 24: 1114–1145. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-019-09494-z doi: 10.1007/s11142-019-09494-z
    [17] Clayton MC, Hartzell JC, Rosenberg J (2005) The impact of CEO turnover on equity volatility. J Bus 78: 1779–1808. https://doi.org/10.1086/431442 doi: 10.1086/431442
    [18] Coles JL, Hoi CK (2003) New Evidence on the Market for Directors: Board Membership and Pennsylvania Senate Bill 1310. J Financ 58: 197–230. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00522 doi: 10.1111/1540-6261.00522
    [19] Desai MA, Dharmapala D (2006) Corporate tax avoidance and high-powered incentives. J Financ Econ 79: 145–179. https://doi.org/:10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.02.002
    [20] Dharmapala D, Desai MA (2007) Taxation and Corporate Governance: An Economic Approach. In: Schön, W., MPI Studies on Intellectual Property, Competition and Tax Law, Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 3: 13–30. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-77276-7_3
    [21] Douglas C, Hou W (2011) Corporate Fraud, CEO Turnover, and State Ownership in China. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1881960 doi: 10.2139/ssrn.1881960
    [22] Dyreng SD, Hanlon M, Maydew EL (2008) Long-Run Corporate Tax Avoidance. Account Rev 83: 61–82.
    [23] Dyreng SD, Hanlon M, Maydew EL, et al. (2017) Changes in corporate effective tax rates over the past 25 years. J Financ Econ 124: 441–463. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2017.04.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2017.04.001
    [24] Dyreng SD, Hoopes JL, Wilde JH (2016) Public Pressure and Corporate Tax Behavior. J Account Res 54: 147–186. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679x.12101 doi: 10.1111/1475-679x.12101
    [25] Fee CE, Hadlock CJ, Pierce JR (2013) Managers with and without Style: Evidence Using Exogenous Variation. Rev Financ Stud 26: 567–601. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhs131 doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhs131
    [26] Feldstein M (1999) Tax Avoidance and the Deadweight Loss of the Income Tax. Rev Econ Stat 81: 674–680.
    [27] Firth M, Fung PMY, Rui OM (2006) Firm Performance, Governance Structure, and Top Management Turnover in a Transitional Economy. J Manage Stud 43: 1289–1330. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6486.2006.00621.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2006.00621.x
    [28] Frank MM, Lynch LJ, Rego SO (2009) Tax Reporting Aggressiveness and Its Relation to Aggressive Financial Reporting. Account Rev 84: 467–496.
    [29] Freeman RE, Wicks AC, Parmar B (2004) Stakeholder Theory and The Corporate Objective Revisited. Organ Sci 15: 364–369. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1040.0066 doi: 10.1287/orsc.1040.0066
    [30] Gaertner FB (2014) CEO After Tax Compensation Incentives and Corporate Tax Avoidance. Contemp Account Res 31: 1077–1102. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12058 doi: 10.1111/1911-3846.12058
    [31] Gaertner FB, Chyz JA (2018) Can Paying "Too Much" or "Too Little" Tax Contribute to Forced CEO Turnover? Account Rev 93: 103–130.
    [32] Gallemore J, Maydew EL, Thornock JR (2014) The Reputational Costs of Tax Avoidance. Contemp Account Res 31: 1103–1133. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12055 doi: 10.1111/1911-3846.12055
    [33] Gayle K, Johnston K, Beatson A (2008) A framework of Corporate Social Responsibility for advertising accountability: The case of Australian government advertising campaign. J Market Commun 14: 155–169. https://doi.org/10.1080/13527260701858539 doi: 10.1080/13527260701858539
    [34] Graham JR, Hanlon M, Shevlin T, et al. (2014) Incentives for Tax Planning and Avoidance: Evidence from the Field. Account Rev 89: 991–1023. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50678 doi: 10.2308/accr-50678
    [35] Graham JR, Raedy JS, Shackelford DA (2012) Research in Accounting for Income Taxes. J Account Econ 53: 412–434. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.11.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.11.006
    [36] Hanlon M, Heitzman S (2010) A review of tax research. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50: 127–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2010.09.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2010.09.002
    [37] Holt G, Barford V (2013) Google, Amazon, Starbucks: The rise of 'tax shaming'. BBC news magazine 21.
    [38] Hubbard TD, Christensen DM, Graffin SD (2017) Higher Highs and Lower Lows: The Role of Corporate Social Responsibility in CEO Dismissal. Strategic Manage J 38: 2255–2265. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2646 doi: 10.1002/smj.2646
    [39] Huson MR, Malatesta PH, Parrino R (2004) Managerial succession and firm performance. J Financ Econ 74: 237–275. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2003.08.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2003.08.002
    [40] Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3: 305–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(76)90026-x doi: 10.1016/0304-405x(76)90026-x
    [41] Joel S, Crocker KJ (2005) Corporate tax evasion with agency costs. J Public Econ 89: 1593–1610. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.08.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.08.003
    [42] Kao EH, Yeh CC, Wang LH, et al. (2018) The relationship between CSR and performance: Evidence in China. Pac-Basin Financ J 51: 155–170. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pacfin.2018.04.006 doi: 10.1016/j.pacfin.2018.04.006
    [43] Karpoff JM, Lott J (1993) The Reputational Penalty Firms Bear from Committing Criminal Fraud. J Law Econ 36: 757–802.
    [44] Kim JB, Li YH, Zhang LD (2011) Corporate tax avoidance and stock price crash risk: Firm-level analysis. J Financ Econ 100: 639–662. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.07.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.07.007
    [45] Koester A, Shevlin T, Wangerin D (2016) The Role of Managerial Ability in Corporate Tax Avoidance. Manage Sci 63: 3147–3529. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2510 doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2016.2510
    [46] Laguir I, Staglianò R, Elbaz J (2015) Does corporate social responsibility affect corporate tax aggressiveness? J Clean Prod 107: 662–675. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.05.059 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.05.059
    [47] Lanis R, Richardson G (2012) Corporate social responsibility and tax aggressiveness: An empirical analysis. J Account Public Pol 31: 86–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jaccpubpol.2011.10.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jaccpubpol.2011.10.006
    [48] Lanis R, Richardson G (2014) Is Corporate Social Responsibility Performance Associated with Tax Avoidance? J Bus Ethics 127: 439–457. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2052-8 doi: 10.1007/s10551-014-2052-8
    [49] Lanis R, Richardson G, Liu C, et al. (2018) The Impact of Corporate Tax Avoidance on Board of Directors and CEO Reputation. J Bus Ethics 160: 463–498. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-018-3949-4 doi: 10.1007/s10551-018-3949-4
    [50] Li WF, Pittman JA, Wang ZT (2019) The Determinants and Consequences of Tax Audits: Some Evidence from China. J Am Tax Assoc 41: 91–122. https://doi.org/10.2308/atax-52136 doi: 10.2308/atax-52136
    [51] Mason P, Hambrick H (1984) The Organization as a Reflection of Its Top Managers. Acad Manage Rev 9: 193–206. https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.1984.4277628 doi: 10.5465/AMR.1984.4277628
    [52] Maydew EL, Hanlon M, Dyreng SD (2010) The Effects of Executives on Corporate Tax Avoidance. Account Rev 85: 1163–1189. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr.2010.85.4.1163 doi: 10.2308/accr.2010.85.4.1163
    [53] Olsen KJ, Stekelberg J (2015) CEO Narcissism and Corporate Tax Sheltering. J Am Stat Assoc 38: 1–22. https://doi.org/10.2308/atax-51251 doi: 10.2308/atax-51251
    [54] Plesko GA (2003) An evaluation of alternative measures of corporate tax rates. Journal of accounting & economics 35: 201–226. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-4101(03)00019-3 doi: 10.1016/S0165-4101(03)00019-3
    [55] Powers K, Robinson JR, Stomberg B (2016) How do CEO incentives affect corporate tax planning and financial reporting of income taxes? Rev Account Stud 21: 672–710. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-016-9350-6 doi: 10.1007/s11142-016-9350-6
    [56] Richardson G, Lanis R (2012) Corporate social responsibility and tax aggressiveness: a test of legitimacy theory. Account Audit Accoun J 26: 75–100. https://doi.org/10.1108/09513571311285621 doi: 10.1108/09513571311285621
    [57] Scholes MS, Wolfson MA, Erickson MM, et al. (2005) Taxes and Business Strategy: A Planning Approach. https://doi.org/10.2469/br.v2.n1.14
    [58] Shivdasani A, Kang JK (1995) Firm performance, corporate governance, and top executive turnover in Japan. Account Audit Accoun 38: 29–58. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(94)00807-D doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(94)00807-D
    [59] Sikka P (2010) Smoke and mirrors: Corporate social responsibility and tax avoidance. Accounting Forum 34: 153–168. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.accfor.2012.09.002 doi: 10.1016/j.accfor.2012.09.002
    [60] Slemrod J (2004) Are corporate tax rates, or countries, converging? J Public Econ 88: 1169–1186. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(03)00061-6 doi: 10.1016/s0047-2727(03)00061-6
    [61] Slemrod J, Hanlon M (2009) What Does Tax Aggressiveness Signal? Evidence from Stock Price Reactions to News about Tax Shelter Involvement. J Public Econ 93: 126–141. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.09.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.09.004
    [62] Warfield TD, Cheng Q (2005) Equity Incentives and Earnings Management. Account Rev 80: 441–476.
    [63] Weisbach MS (1988) Outside directors and CEO turnover. J Financ Econ 20: 431–460. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90053-0 doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(88)90053-0
    [64] Wilson R, Rego SO (2012) Equity Risk Incentives and Corporate Tax Aggressiveness. J Account Res 50: 775–809. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-679X.2012.00438.x doi: 10.1111/j.1475-679X.2012.00438.x
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Yue Liu, Jinzhi Liu, Lichang Zhang, Enterprise financialization and R&D innovation: A case study of listed companies in China, 2023, 31, 2688-1594, 2447, 10.3934/era.2023124
    2. Yanhui Yin, Bowen Yang, Environmental Protection or Development? Multiple Policy Effects Evaluation of the Resource Tax Collection Reform for Iron Ore Enterprises in China, 2023, 20, 1660-4601, 3976, 10.3390/ijerph20053976
    3. Jie Zheng, Yijun Li, Machine learning model of tax arrears prediction based on knowledge graph, 2023, 31, 2688-1594, 4057, 10.3934/era.2023206
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1623) PDF downloads(89) Cited by(3)

Figures and Tables

Tables(9)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog