Citation: Andrea Guazzini, Enrico Imbimbo, Federica Stefanelli, Franco Bagnoli, Ezio Venturino. Quantifying fairness to overcome selfishness: A behavioural model to describe the evolution and stabilization of inter-group bias using the Ultimatum Game[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(5): 3718-3733. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019184
[1] | D. Balliet, J. Wu and C. K. De Dreu, Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: a meta-analysis, Psychol. Bullet., 140 (2014), 1556. |
[2] | M. Hewstone, M. Rubin and H. Willis, Intergroup bias, Annu. Rev. Psychol., 53 (2002), 575–604. |
[3] | A. Romano, D. Balliet and J. Wu, Unbounded indirect reciprocity: Is reputation-based cooperation bounded by group membership?, J. Exp. Soc. Psychol., 71 (2017), 59–67. |
[4] | M. A. Nowak, Five rules for the evolution of cooperation, Science, 314 (2006), 1560–1563. |
[5] | W. D. Hamilton, The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I, J. Theor. Biol., 7 (1964), 1–16. |
[6] | W. D. Hamilton, The genetical evolution of social behaviour. II, J. Theor. Biol., 7 (1964), 17–52. |
[7] | R. Dawkins, The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1976. |
[8] | T. Yamagishi and N. Mifune, Does shared group membership promote altruism? fear, greed, and reputation, Rationality and Society, 20 (2008), 5–30. |
[9] | H. Tajfel and J. C. Turner, The social identity theory of intergroup behavior, in Key readings in social psychology. Political psychology: Key readings , ( eds. J. T. Jost & J. Sidanius), New York, NY, USA: Psychology Press, (2004), 276–293. |
[10] | M. A. Hogg, The social psychology of group cohesiveness: From attraction to social identity. New York University Press, New York, 1992. |
[11] | H. Tajfel, M. G. Billig, R. P. Bundy, et al., Social categorization and intergroup behaviour, Europ. J. Soc. Psychol., 1 (1971), 149–178. |
[12] | T. Yamagishi and T. Kiyonari, The group as the container of generalized reciprocity, Soc. Psychol. Quart., 63 (2000), 116–132. |
[13] | N. Masuda and H. Ohtsuki, Tag-based indirect reciprocity by incomplete social information, Pro-ceed. Royal Soc. London B Biol. Sci., 274 (2007), 689–695. |
[14] | A. G. Sanfey, J. K. Rilling, J. A. Aronson, et al., The neural basis of economic decision-making in the ultimatum game, Science, 300 (2003), 1755–1758. |
[15] | E. Fehr and U. Fischbacher, The nature of human altruism, Nature, 425 (2003), 785–791. |
[16] | W. Güth and M. G. Kocher, More than thirty years of ultimatum bargaining experiments: Motives, variations, and a survey of the recent literature, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 108 (2014), 396–409. |
[17] | W. Güth, R. Schmittberger and B. Schwarze, An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining,J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 3 (1982), 367–388. |
[18] | M.A.Nowak, K.M.PageandK.Sigmund, Fairnessversusreasonintheultimatumgame, Science,289 (2000), 1773–1775. |
[19] | V. Denes-Raj and S. Epstein, Conflict between intuitive and rational processing: when people behave against their better judgment., J. Person. Soc. Psychol., 66 (1994), 819–829. |
[20] | D.Kahneman, Aperspectiveonjudgmentandchoice: mappingboundedrationality., Am.Psychol.,58 (2003),697–720. |
[21] | H. Oosterbeek, R. Sloof and G. Van De Kuilen, Cultural differences in ultimatum game experi-ments: Evidence from a meta-analysis, Exp. Econ., 7 (2004), 171–188. |
[22] | R. H. Thaler, Anomalies: The ultimatum game, J. Econ. Perspect., 2 (1988), 195–206. |
[23] | J. H. Kagel, C. Kim and D. Moser, Fairness in ultimatum games with asymmetric information and asymmetric payoffs, Games Econ. Behav., 13 (1996), 100–110. |
[24] | D. G. Rand, C. E. Tarnita, H. Ohtsuki, et al., Evolution of fairness in the one-shot anonymous ultimatum game, Proceed. Nat. Aca. Sci., 110 (2013), 2581–2586. |
[25] | C. Feng, Y. J. Luo and F. Krueger, Neural signatures of fairness-related normative decision making in the ultimatum game: A coordinate-based meta-analysis, Human Brain Map., 36 (2015), 591–602. |
[26] | S. Debove, N. Baumard and J.-B. André, Models of the evolution of fairness in the ultimatum game: a review and classification, Evol. Human Behav., 37 (2016), 245–254. |
[27] | R. Slonim and A. E. Roth, Learning in high stakes ultimatum games: An experiment in the Slovak republic, Econometrica, 66 (1998), 569–596. |
[28] | L. A. Cameron, Raising the stakes in the ultimatum game: Experimental evidence from Indonesia,Econ. Inq., 37 (1999), 47–59. |
[29] | J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, et al., In search of Homo Economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies, Am. Econ. Rev., 91 (2001), 73–78. |
[30] | G. Bornstein and I. Yaniv, Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: are groups more rational players?, Exp. Econ., 1 (1998), 101–108. |
[31] | T. Kugler, E. E. Kausel and M. G. Kocher, Are groups more rational than individuals? a review of interactive decision making in groups, Wiley Int. Rev. Cogn. Sci., 3 (2012), 471–482. |
[32] | J. H. Kim, The role of identity in intra-and inter-group bargaining in the ultimatum game, Under- gra. Econ. Rev., 4 (2008), Article 6. |
[33] | A. Ockenfels and P. Werner, Beliefs and ingroup favoritism, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 108 (2014), 453–462. |
[34] | S.-H. Chuah, R. Hoffmann, M. Jones, et al., Do cultures clash? Evidence from cross-national ultimatum game experiments, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 64 (2007), 35–48. |
[35] | R. Boarini, J.-F. Laslier and S. Robin, Interpersonal comparisons of utility in bargaining: evidence from a transcontinental ultimatum game, Theory Decis., 67 (2009), 341–373. |
[36] | K. N. McLeish and R. J. Oxoby, Social interactions and the salience of social identity, J. Econ. Psychol., 32 (2011), 172–178. |
[37] | S. A. Mendoza, S. P. Lane and D. M. Amodio, For members only: ingroup punishment of fairness norm violations in the ultimatum game, Soc. Psychol. Personal. Sci., 5 (2014), 662–670. |
[38] | H. Garrett, The competitive exclusion principle, Science, 131 (1960), 1292–1297. |