Research article Special Issues

Quantifying fairness to overcome selfishness: A behavioural model to describe the evolution and stabilization of inter-group bias using the Ultimatum Game

  • Received: 17 December 2018 Accepted: 15 April 2019 Published: 26 April 2019
  • The ability to form groups to overcome problems has been crucial for the evolution of human beings. To favour the formation of cooperating groups, one of the mechanisms developed is the inter-group bias, namely the tendency of individuals to favour members of their group and hinder the external ones. It is the cognitive equivalent of the "green beard effect" in evolutionary biology, introduced by Hamilton and popularized by Dawkins, for which a group can profit of the altruistic behaviour of its members. Here, we use a behavioural model based on the Ultimatum Game, to shed light on how this behaviour cloud has been stabilized in the human population, estimating the magnitude of favouritism needed to overcome selfish individuals. Through both numerical simulations and analytic approaches, we study how a community of collectivist and individualist agents evolves. The key factor is the mechanism for the evolution of the population, i.e., the replacement of the poor-performing individuals. In the case of replacement by the reproduction of existing individuals, we observe a smooth phase transition and no coexistence. If the replacement is random, the transition smooths, and coexistence is possible. We developed analytical approaches for these two cases and performed numerical simulations. Although analytical calculations support the behaviour emerging from simulations, some differences ask for more refined treatments.

    Citation: Andrea Guazzini, Enrico Imbimbo, Federica Stefanelli, Franco Bagnoli, Ezio Venturino. Quantifying fairness to overcome selfishness: A behavioural model to describe the evolution and stabilization of inter-group bias using the Ultimatum Game[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(5): 3718-3733. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019184

    Related Papers:

  • The ability to form groups to overcome problems has been crucial for the evolution of human beings. To favour the formation of cooperating groups, one of the mechanisms developed is the inter-group bias, namely the tendency of individuals to favour members of their group and hinder the external ones. It is the cognitive equivalent of the "green beard effect" in evolutionary biology, introduced by Hamilton and popularized by Dawkins, for which a group can profit of the altruistic behaviour of its members. Here, we use a behavioural model based on the Ultimatum Game, to shed light on how this behaviour cloud has been stabilized in the human population, estimating the magnitude of favouritism needed to overcome selfish individuals. Through both numerical simulations and analytic approaches, we study how a community of collectivist and individualist agents evolves. The key factor is the mechanism for the evolution of the population, i.e., the replacement of the poor-performing individuals. In the case of replacement by the reproduction of existing individuals, we observe a smooth phase transition and no coexistence. If the replacement is random, the transition smooths, and coexistence is possible. We developed analytical approaches for these two cases and performed numerical simulations. Although analytical calculations support the behaviour emerging from simulations, some differences ask for more refined treatments.


    加载中


    [1] D. Balliet, J. Wu and C. K. De Dreu, Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: a meta-analysis, Psychol. Bullet., 140 (2014), 1556.
    [2] M. Hewstone, M. Rubin and H. Willis, Intergroup bias, Annu. Rev. Psychol., 53 (2002), 575–604.
    [3] A. Romano, D. Balliet and J. Wu, Unbounded indirect reciprocity: Is reputation-based cooperation bounded by group membership?, J. Exp. Soc. Psychol., 71 (2017), 59–67.
    [4] M. A. Nowak, Five rules for the evolution of cooperation, Science, 314 (2006), 1560–1563.
    [5] W. D. Hamilton, The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I, J. Theor. Biol., 7 (1964), 1–16.
    [6] W. D. Hamilton, The genetical evolution of social behaviour. II, J. Theor. Biol., 7 (1964), 17–52.
    [7] R. Dawkins, The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1976.
    [8] T. Yamagishi and N. Mifune, Does shared group membership promote altruism? fear, greed, and reputation, Rationality and Society, 20 (2008), 5–30.
    [9] H. Tajfel and J. C. Turner, The social identity theory of intergroup behavior, in Key readings in social psychology. Political psychology: Key readings , ( eds. J. T. Jost & J. Sidanius), New York, NY, USA: Psychology Press, (2004), 276–293.
    [10] M. A. Hogg, The social psychology of group cohesiveness: From attraction to social identity. New York University Press, New York, 1992.
    [11] H. Tajfel, M. G. Billig, R. P. Bundy, et al., Social categorization and intergroup behaviour, Europ. J. Soc. Psychol., 1 (1971), 149–178.
    [12] T. Yamagishi and T. Kiyonari, The group as the container of generalized reciprocity, Soc. Psychol. Quart., 63 (2000), 116–132.
    [13] N. Masuda and H. Ohtsuki, Tag-based indirect reciprocity by incomplete social information, Pro-ceed. Royal Soc. London B Biol. Sci., 274 (2007), 689–695.
    [14] A. G. Sanfey, J. K. Rilling, J. A. Aronson, et al., The neural basis of economic decision-making in the ultimatum game, Science, 300 (2003), 1755–1758.
    [15] E. Fehr and U. Fischbacher, The nature of human altruism, Nature, 425 (2003), 785–791.
    [16] W. Güth and M. G. Kocher, More than thirty years of ultimatum bargaining experiments: Motives, variations, and a survey of the recent literature, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 108 (2014), 396–409.
    [17] W. Güth, R. Schmittberger and B. Schwarze, An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining,J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 3 (1982), 367–388.
    [18] M.A.Nowak, K.M.PageandK.Sigmund, Fairnessversusreasonintheultimatumgame, Science,289 (2000), 1773–1775.
    [19] V. Denes-Raj and S. Epstein, Conflict between intuitive and rational processing: when people behave against their better judgment., J. Person. Soc. Psychol., 66 (1994), 819–829.
    [20] D.Kahneman, Aperspectiveonjudgmentandchoice: mappingboundedrationality., Am.Psychol.,58 (2003),697–720.
    [21] H. Oosterbeek, R. Sloof and G. Van De Kuilen, Cultural differences in ultimatum game experi-ments: Evidence from a meta-analysis, Exp. Econ., 7 (2004), 171–188.
    [22] R. H. Thaler, Anomalies: The ultimatum game, J. Econ. Perspect., 2 (1988), 195–206.
    [23] J. H. Kagel, C. Kim and D. Moser, Fairness in ultimatum games with asymmetric information and asymmetric payoffs, Games Econ. Behav., 13 (1996), 100–110.
    [24] D. G. Rand, C. E. Tarnita, H. Ohtsuki, et al., Evolution of fairness in the one-shot anonymous ultimatum game, Proceed. Nat. Aca. Sci., 110 (2013), 2581–2586.
    [25] C. Feng, Y. J. Luo and F. Krueger, Neural signatures of fairness-related normative decision making in the ultimatum game: A coordinate-based meta-analysis, Human Brain Map., 36 (2015), 591–602.
    [26] S. Debove, N. Baumard and J.-B. André, Models of the evolution of fairness in the ultimatum game: a review and classification, Evol. Human Behav., 37 (2016), 245–254.
    [27] R. Slonim and A. E. Roth, Learning in high stakes ultimatum games: An experiment in the Slovak republic, Econometrica, 66 (1998), 569–596.
    [28] L. A. Cameron, Raising the stakes in the ultimatum game: Experimental evidence from Indonesia,Econ. Inq., 37 (1999), 47–59.
    [29] J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, et al., In search of Homo Economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies, Am. Econ. Rev., 91 (2001), 73–78.
    [30] G. Bornstein and I. Yaniv, Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: are groups more rational players?, Exp. Econ., 1 (1998), 101–108.
    [31] T. Kugler, E. E. Kausel and M. G. Kocher, Are groups more rational than individuals? a review of interactive decision making in groups, Wiley Int. Rev. Cogn. Sci., 3 (2012), 471–482.
    [32] J. H. Kim, The role of identity in intra-and inter-group bargaining in the ultimatum game, Under- gra. Econ. Rev., 4 (2008), Article 6.
    [33] A. Ockenfels and P. Werner, Beliefs and ingroup favoritism, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 108 (2014), 453–462.
    [34] S.-H. Chuah, R. Hoffmann, M. Jones, et al., Do cultures clash? Evidence from cross-national ultimatum game experiments, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 64 (2007), 35–48.
    [35] R. Boarini, J.-F. Laslier and S. Robin, Interpersonal comparisons of utility in bargaining: evidence from a transcontinental ultimatum game, Theory Decis., 67 (2009), 341–373.
    [36] K. N. McLeish and R. J. Oxoby, Social interactions and the salience of social identity, J. Econ. Psychol., 32 (2011), 172–178.
    [37] S. A. Mendoza, S. P. Lane and D. M. Amodio, For members only: ingroup punishment of fairness norm violations in the ultimatum game, Soc. Psychol. Personal. Sci., 5 (2014), 662–670.
    [38] H. Garrett, The competitive exclusion principle, Science, 131 (1960), 1292–1297.
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2019 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3943) PDF downloads(551) Cited by(1)

Article outline

Figures and Tables

Figures(4)  /  Tables(1)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog